Skip to main content

The Local Bifurcation of Ramsey Equilibrium

  • Chapter
Optimization and Chaos

Part of the book series: Studies in Economic Theory ((ECON.THEORY,volume 11))

  • 317 Accesses

Abstract

The hypothesis that aggregate fluctuations may represent an endogenous feature of dynamic competitive economies with incomplete markets has been advanced in several papers.1 The role of incomplete markets seems essential for the appearance of cycles in one sector models.2 Becker and Foias (1987) and Woodford (1988a) have pointed out that the elasticity of substitution of the production function plays a fundamental role in the existence of cyclic equilibrium paths. In those papers cycles are generated if the substitutability between capital and labor is not too great. Heterogeneity of households is also a crucial component of their fluctuation theories.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. See Bewley (1986), Becker and Foias (1987), and Woodford (1988a) . Boldrin and Woodford (1990) and Guesnerie and Woodford (1992) survey those equilibrium models.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Dechert (1984) shows that the one sector Ramsey model exhibits a monotonic aggregate capital stock along an optimal program for a wide variety of technologies. Benhabib, Jafarey, and Nishimura (1988) show that standard turnpike properties may be recovered for a class of recursive preferences in Pareto optimal growth with many consumers.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Boyd (1990) and Hernández (1991) for additional research on this model. Bewley (1986) seems the first to draw attention to market incompleteness as a potential source of equilibrium fluctuations.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See Woodford (1988b) for a critique of the closely related cash-in-advance models where laborers choose not to borrow due to high discount rates.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Ramsey equilibrium programs were shown to exist with general utility functions by Becker, Boyd and Foias (1991) .

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Becker and Foia (1987). Henández (1991) recovers this result in the case where all households have a common discount factor.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Becker and Foias (1987) provide an ad hoc construction of an eauilibrium 2-cycle.

    Google Scholar 

  8. This is also the intuition for the 2-cycle example built by Becker and Foias (1987). The intertemporal tolerance for consumption variation and discounting also enter the analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Majumdar and Mitra (Chapter 3) examine changes in the utility and production functions in a one-sector Ramsey model with wealth effects. They demonstrate the possibility of topological chaos for an open set of production and felicity functions that are the economic primitives of the model.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Becker and Foias (1987) give a special version of these condtions for the case of a cycle of period 2.

    Google Scholar 

  11. We have dropped the subscript on δ since the meaning is clear.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See equation (3.1) below for a p</b>recise definition of Φ.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Becker and Foias (1990), Section IV.

    Google Scholar 

  14. If there is only one household, then the model is equivalent to the standard Ramsey optimal growth model with a one sector technology. Optimal capital sequences are always monotonic in that framework.

    Google Scholar 

  15. The intertemporal tolerance is the reciprocal of the Arrow-Pratt measure of absolute risk aversion. This is of course a measure of the degree of concavity of u. Hence the tolerance function also serves the same purpose. The intertemporal elasticity of snbstitution, A(y)/y, is a more commonly used measure of sensitivity to intertemporal consumption variation.

    Google Scholar 

  16. The units of measurement in (3.4A) are output per unit of capital.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Other useful references on center manifold theory may be found in Carr (1981) and Ruelle (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  18. See Becker and Foias (1987) for the underlying intuition.

    Google Scholar 

  19. This should not lead to any confusion since the analysis applies only to the map.

    Google Scholar 

  20. This Taylor series might not converge.

    Google Scholar 

  21. This follows from the Implicit Function theorem.

    Google Scholar 

  22. That is, the fourth derivative is very much larger than 1.

    Google Scholar 

  23. The tangent spaces are given by the space Co2) RR+) of twice continuously differentiable real-valued functions defined on R+ having compact support. This space is a strict inductive limit of Banach spaces. Since this structure does not play any economic role in our analysis we will leave all the functional-geometric details to the mathematically minded reader.

    Google Scholar 

  24. lndeed, ℘k is a submanifold of ℘ of codimension 1, that is defined by one equation. For example, a surface in R3 is a codimension 1 submanifold. Hence, a codimension 1 submanifold in ℘ signifies the submanifold is a “rich” class of functions

    Google Scholar 

  25. Notice that the second inequality in Condition (D) implies (C).

    Google Scholar 

  26. See Aubin (1977, p. 52) for details of this construction.

    Google Scholar 

  27. We retain the use of the notation f’ , f” etc. for the unperturbed production (and income) functions when the meaning is clear.

    Google Scholar 

  28. We note that Berndt (1976) notes the time series estimates of the elasticity of substitution generally provide lower estimates than 1 for that parameter. Indeed, he notes those estimates tend to be centered in the range 0.1 to 0.2.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2000 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Becker, R.A., Foias, C. (2000). The Local Bifurcation of Ramsey Equilibrium. In: Optimization and Chaos. Studies in Economic Theory, vol 11. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-04060-7_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-04060-7_5

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-08636-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-04060-7

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics