Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Information Age Economy ((AGEECONOMY))

  • 77 Accesses

Abstract

At the beginning of a scientific treatise a commitment about terms and notions used in the discussion has to be made.26 The definition of information and its properties is one basis of this thesis, therefore, the present chapter treats the basic conceptions of information (Section 2.1) and deepens the properties and effects of information in economic situations. The different possibilities for information acquisition will be discussed (Section 2.2), and the credibility of information sources as well as measures to achieve trust in information sources will be examined from the perspective of principal-agent relationships (Section 2.3). Further, the effects of information on market efficiency will be reviewed briefly (Section 2.4) as well as the circumstances of information as an economic commodity (Section 2.5).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Referneces

  1. Cf. [Esser 77, p. 68 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  2. Cf. [Kampis 92, p.51].

    Google Scholar 

  3. Cf. [Haken 92, p. 155].

    Google Scholar 

  4. See [Hopf 83, p. 6 fp.] and [Bode 97] for a review of different conceptions of information in economics.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Semiotics is the general theory of signs, see [Oeser 92, p. 320], [Lyons 83, p. 25 fp.], [Eco 77].

    Google Scholar 

  6. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 16], [von Weizsäcker 88, p. 168 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  7. Cf. [von Weizsäcker 88, p. 200 fp.]. Semantic information requires a receiver of the information, for whom the information has to be understandable. However, this results in the circumstance that semantic information is measurable only as pragmatic information, cf. [von Weizsäcker 88, p. 168 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  8. Cf. [Shannon 48] and [Shannon 63], [van Lint 80, p. 24fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  9. Cf. [Topsoe 74, p. 5 fp.], [Blahut 87, p. 2 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  10. Cf. [Viterbi 79, p. 11 fp.], [Gallager 86, p. 5].

    Google Scholar 

  11. Cf. [Topsoe 74, p. 5], [Viterbi 79, p. 7 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  12. In statistical physics entropy is defined as the logarithm of the number of accessible states of a macroscopic system for a certain energy times the Boltzmann factor k B , cf. [Reif 85, p. 94 fp.]. The higher the entropy, the more states the system can access for a certain energy, and the more indefiniteness is in the system.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Cf. [Topsoe 74, p. 6].

    Google Scholar 

  14. This definition is referred to as the first main proposition of information theory, cf. [Topsoe 74, p. 25].

    Google Scholar 

  15. In case of two possible outcomes the logarithm to the base 2 has to be taken, cf. [Topsoe 74, p. 26], [Viterbi 79, p. 8].

    Google Scholar 

  16. Cf. [Jürgensen 97].

    Google Scholar 

  17. Cf. [Topsoe 74, p. 67 fp.], [Viterbi 79, p. 3 fp.], [Gallager 86, p. 5 fp.], [Blahut 87, p. 8 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  18. Cf. [Schneider 94].

    Google Scholar 

  19. Cf. [von Weizsäcker 88, p. 200].

    Google Scholar 

  20. Cf. [Viterbi 79, p. 12 fp.], [Gallager 86, p. 4 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  21. Semantic understanding is usually connected with written or spoken human languages, cf. [Anderson 89, p. 322 fp.], but ‘understanding’ is not restricted to the exchange of information between humans. In biological systems we can find an extensive exchange of information, that requires semantic understanding, for example, in the reproduction process, cf. [Csânyi 92].

    Google Scholar 

  22. Cf. [Rich 83, p. 304].

    Google Scholar 

  23. Haken interprets information as a property emergent in complex systems, and applies the theory of dynamic systems to formalize this conception, cf. [Haken 92, p. 153].

    Google Scholar 

  24. Cf. [Haken 88, p. 16 fp.], [Haken 92, p. 162].

    Google Scholar 

  25. Cf. [Scheck 90, p. 274 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  26. Cf. [Scheck 90, p. 292 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  27. On the basis of this model of a dynamic system Haken develops the concept of relative importance of messages to attribute a value to the messages received by the system, cf. [Haken 88, p. 16 fp.], [Haken 92].

    Google Scholar 

  28. For a discussion of the activities and preconditions of information processing within systems see Section 2.1.6 and [Haefner 92b, p. 7 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  29. Cf. [von Weizsäcker 88, p. 201].

    Google Scholar 

  30. Cf. [von Weizsäcker 72] according to [von Weizsäcker 88, p. 201].

    Google Scholar 

  31. Cf. [Lippman 79, p. 1 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  32. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 31].

    Google Scholar 

  33. See the meaning of uncertainty (or entropy) in the definition of information in Section 2.1.1.1.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 31–32].

    Google Scholar 

  35. Cf. [Schneeweiß 66], [Laux 91, p. 32 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  36. Various decision rules, depending on the decision-maker’s risk assessment, can be applied to the choice of an appropriate action, cf. [Laux 91], [Eisenfuhr 94].

    Google Scholar 

  37. Cf. [Laux 91, p. 281].

    Google Scholar 

  38. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 33]

    Google Scholar 

  39. Technological information is usually produced by means of research and development (R&D), which is the basis for an increase in knowledge and a precondition for economic progress, cf. [Hopf 83, p. 74].

    Google Scholar 

  40. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 36 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  41. Cf. Section 2.4.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Commodities are valuable because they possess attributes which consumers desire. The quality of a product can therefore be specified by describing the amount of a desirable attribute it possesses. And a product with multiple attributes determining the quality can be described by a vector of the different product attributes having particular values, cf. [Kihlstrom 74a, p. 415 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  43. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 35].

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Sections 2.3.2 and 2.4.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Cf. [Wittmann 59] according to [Bode 97, p. 454 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  46. Significance of information for the recipient system means that ‘information enables the system to initiate meaningful systematic activities that would not be possible without the information’, cf. [Haefner 92b, p. 5]. Hence, the definition is closely related to the pragmatic conception of information.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Cf. [Kuhlen 95, p. 38].

    Google Scholar 

  48. Translation of [Kuhlen 95, p. 38].

    Google Scholar 

  49. Cf. [Steinmüller 93, p. 263], [Rehäuser 96, p. 5].

    Google Scholar 

  50. Synthesized information refers to internally processed information, cf. [Tuthill 90, p. 5]. For a comprehensive treatment of the concepts of knowledge see [Tuthill 90] as well.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Cf. [Rehäuser 96, p. 2 fp].

    Google Scholar 

  52. Translation of [Kuhlen 95, p. 38].

    Google Scholar 

  53. Cf. [Sydow 96], [Willke 96], [Kuhlen 95, p. 38]. 79 Cf. [Rehäuser 96, p. 7].

    Google Scholar 

  54. Cf. [Kuhlen 95, p. 38].

    Google Scholar 

  55. Cf. [Rehäuser96, p.7].

    Google Scholar 

  56. Cf. [Rehäuser96, p.6].

    Google Scholar 

  57. Cf. Section 2.1.6 and [Kuhlen 95, p. 42–43]. Kuhlen speaks about different information products.

    Google Scholar 

  58. For an overview about methods of knowledge representation see [Tuthill 90, p. 226–245] and [Reimer 97], a comprehensive treatment can be found in [Reichgelt 91].

    Google Scholar 

  59. Cf. [Anderson 89, p. 79 fp., 103 fp., 206 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  60. Cf. [Luger 89, p. 28 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  61. Cf. [Kolodner86, p. 1].

    Google Scholar 

  62. Kreutzer and McKenzie describe knowledge representations as a set of syntactic and semantic conventions ‘to describe things,’ where ‘things’ may be objects, relations, actions, events or processes. This stresses the fact that representation and interpretation are closely intertwined, cf. [Kreutzer 91, p. 198].

    Google Scholar 

  63. For a comprehensive review of semantic networks see [Sowa 90, p. 1011 fp.] and [Mac Randal 88], for their application to language understanding see [Rich 83, p. 295 fp.]. An overview about linguistics from a cognitive science point of view is given in [Anderson 89, p. 281 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  64. For a comprehensive treatment of the organization of knowledge and information see [Rowley 92].

    Google Scholar 

  65. See [Salton 83] for information retrieval (IR).

    Google Scholar 

  66. Cf. [Manecke 97a].

    Google Scholar 

  67. Cf. [Manecke 97a, p. 142–143].

    Google Scholar 

  68. See [Knorz 97] for an overview.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Examples are: manual methods, full-text methods, linguistic methods, retrieval-oriented methods (weighted term schemes, vector models, probabilistic retrieval methods), see [Knorz 97] for details.

    Google Scholar 

  70. Cf. [Rowley 91, p. 170–173].

    Google Scholar 

  71. Cf. [Rowley 91, p. 171], [Knorz 97, p. 138]. A more differentiated method to describe and measure the quality of results obtained from an information retrieval system is described in [Wand 96], see [Jeusfeld 97, p. 493] as well.

    Google Scholar 

  72. Cf. [Rowley 92, p. 3].

    Google Scholar 

  73. Cf. [Knorz 97, p. 122–123].

    Google Scholar 

  74. See, for example, [Alter 96, p. 164], [Reichgelt 91, p. 14].

    Google Scholar 

  75. For references see [Rowley 92, p. 14–15], fox abstracting see [Kuhlen 97].

    Google Scholar 

  76. Cf. [Allen 90] and Section 2.1.1.3.

    Google Scholar 

  77. Examples are given by [Kihlstrom 74a] and [Kihlstrom 74b] who implicitly derive the value of information in markets with uncertain product quality, [MacMinn 80] who examines the value of information in the context of a search model, and [Milgrom 82] who investigates the value of information in a sealed-bid auction.

    Google Scholar 

  78. Cf. [Milgrom 82], [Gilboa 91, p. 444, 456], [Nink 91, p. 62–63].

    Google Scholar 

  79. Cf. [Bamberg 76], [Laux 91, p. 299], [Saliger 93, p. 141].

    Google Scholar 

  80. Cf. [Laux 91, p. 297 fp.], [Saliger 93, p. 141].

    Google Scholar 

  81. The conditional probability is determined by application of Bayes’ theorem, cf. [Härtung 89, p. 102], [Laux 91, p. 285 fp.]: (math)

    Google Scholar 

  82. Cf. [Laux 91, p. 305 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  83. Cf. Sections 2.3.2 and 2.4.

    Google Scholar 

  84. Cf. [Akerlof 70].

    Google Scholar 

  85. In Akerlof s model the seller of a used car is assumed to have private information about the quality of his/her car, and the buyer knows that the seller is so informed. Consequently, the buyer worries that the car is offered because it is a ‘lemon.’ If the buyer can be sure that the seller has no private information, the car would be sold for the expected value. But the seller’s private information lowers the selling price, and therefore is of negative value for the owner. Cf. [Milgrom 82].

    Google Scholar 

  86. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 32–33].

    Google Scholar 

  87. For strategic interdependence see [Rasmusen 89, p. 21] and Section 3.4.

    Google Scholar 

  88. Kamien and Tauman, for example, analyze the dependence of the value of technological information, i.e., cost-reducing innovations, on the number of possessors of the information, cf. [Kamien 86].

    Google Scholar 

  89. Cf. [Salop 77].

    Google Scholar 

  90. Cf. [McKelvey 90].

    Google Scholar 

  91. Cf. Section 2.1.1.3 and [Hirshleifer 73, p. 33].

    Google Scholar 

  92. Cf. [Schwuchow 97, p. 753 fp.], [Reichwald 87].

    Google Scholar 

  93. Cf. [Haken 92, p. 155].

    Google Scholar 

  94. Cf. Section 2.4.

    Google Scholar 

  95. Cf. [Bode 93, p. 37], [Herget 97, p. 782].

    Google Scholar 

  96. Cf. [Bode 97, p. 452].

    Google Scholar 

  97. Cf. [Bode 93, p. 38 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  98. Cf. [Allen 90, p. 271], for the production of information and different sources of information see Section 2.2.

    Google Scholar 

  99. Cf. [Herget 97, p. 782].

    Google Scholar 

  100. Cf. [Allen 90, p. 270].

    Google Scholar 

  101. For commodity aspects of information see Section 2.5.1. Hayek argues that in a decentralized economy all relevant information is effectively disseminated via the price system, cf. [Hayek 45]. See Section 2.4.1 as well.

    Google Scholar 

  102. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 34], [Hopf 83, p. 44 fp.], [Allen 90, p. 270 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  103. Cf. Section 2.5 and [Herget 97, p. 782].

    Google Scholar 

  104. Cf. Section 2.5.1 and [Allen 90, p. 271].

    Google Scholar 

  105. Cf. [Arrow 62], [Williamson 86, p. 161], [Picot 96, p. 109].

    Google Scholar 

  106. This refers to the pragmatic conception of information (Section 2.1.1.3) and the basic model of decision theory (Section 2.1.4). 134 Cf. [Bode 97, p. 453].

    Google Scholar 

  107. In the conception of the basic model of decision theory, however, information can only have a positive value, cf. Section 2.1.4. See Section 2.5. 137 Cf. [Haefner 92b, p. 7].

    Google Scholar 

  108. Cf. [Haefner 92b, p.7].

    Google Scholar 

  109. For a discussion of ‘internal information’ in matter/energy systems see [Lazio 92].

    Google Scholar 

  110. A very general conception conceives all matter/energy structures that perform the quoted functions as information processing systems. These information processing system come along as physical, biological, social, and technical systems, cf. [Haefner 92b].

    Google Scholar 

  111. Cf. [Haefner 92b, p. 8] and [Alter 96, p. 365]. For the application of this conception to information production in economics see [Müller 87].

    Google Scholar 

  112. New information can be produced out of existing information, for example, by rearranging the information or by producing an abstract, cf. [Kuhlen 95, p. 86]. Other forms of manipulating information are: sorting, reformatting, or various types of calculations, cf. [Alter 96, p. 365]. This process, however, does not primarily affect the knowledge represented by the information, the new information is mainly a different representation of the same knowledge, cf. Section 2.1.2.

    Google Scholar 

  113. Cf. [Müller 87, p. 128], [Seng 89, p. 48 fp.], [Corsten 90, p. 159].

    Google Scholar 

  114. The surjective projection r\ is called an information function, cf. [Kiener 90, p. 10].

    Google Scholar 

  115. If this condition does not hold, the information processing system is denoted stochastic, cf. [Kiener 90, p. 10].

    Google Scholar 

  116. Cf. [Ehemann 83] according to [Kiener 90, p. 12], see Section 2.1.4.

    Google Scholar 

  117. Cf. [Marschak 75].

    Google Scholar 

  118. Cf. [Ferstl 93, p. 11 fp.], see [Guntram 85] for a review of the general theory of systems.

    Google Scholar 

  119. Cf. [Ferstl 93, p. 12].

    Google Scholar 

  120. Cf. [Ferstl 93, p. 14], [Guntram 85, p. 302].

    Google Scholar 

  121. Cf. [Mertens 91, p. 10fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  122. Cf. [Scheer 95].

    Google Scholar 

  123. Cf. Section 2.1.1.3.

    Google Scholar 

  124. Cf. [Nelson 70].

    Google Scholar 

  125. Cf. Section 4.2.1.

    Google Scholar 

  126. Cf. [Hirshleifer73, p. 32].

    Google Scholar 

  127. For an economic treatment of R&D activities see, for example, [Kamień 70], [Weitzman 79], [Dasgupta 89].

    Google Scholar 

  128. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 33 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  129. Cf. [Kihlstrom 74a, p. 414] and Section 2.1.4.

    Google Scholar 

  130. Stigler introduced the economics of information, pointing attention to the economics of search processes, see [Stigler 61] and [Gastwirth 76] for an overview.

    Google Scholar 

  131. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 56].

    Google Scholar 

  132. Cf. [McAfee 88] and Section 4.2.2.1.

    Google Scholar 

  133. Cf. Section 2.1.4 and 2.1.5.

    Google Scholar 

  134. In general, the outcome of a decision problem is dependent on the mental resources and the effort spent, cf. [Johnson 85].

    Google Scholar 

  135. Cf. [Dasgupta 89, p. 131].

    Google Scholar 

  136. Cf. [Kihlstrom 74a, p. 421], [Yoon 81].

    Google Scholar 

  137. The dissemination of information about products offered is one important entrepreneurial task, cf. [Kaas 90].

    Google Scholar 

  138. Cf. [Butters 77].

    Google Scholar 

  139. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 36] and Section 2.1.1.3.

    Google Scholar 

  140. Cf. [Kaas 90, p. 541].

    Google Scholar 

  141. Cf. [Bagwell 93, p. 200, 225].

    Google Scholar 

  142. Cf. [Butters 77], [Sass 84, p. 37 fp.], [Guimaraes 95].

    Google Scholar 

  143. Cf. [Bagwell 93, p. 224 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  144. Tellis and Fornell conclude: Tor consumers, advertising cannot be used as a guide to either high or low quality. Though a more heavily advertised brand may be of better quality, the relationship between advertising and quality, albeit positive, is not large enough for advertising to be a good indicator of quality.’ Cf. [Tellis 88, p. 70], [Bagwell 93, p. 203].

    Google Scholar 

  145. Introductory prices above the full-information profit-maximizing price that decline over time as information about the product diffuses are assumed to be a signal of high product quality, cf. [Bagwell 91], [Macho-Stadler 97, p. 212 fp.]. A precondition for prices to signal product quality is a minimum amount of private information a consumer has about the supplier and the products offered prior to the acquisition of price information, cf. [Judd 94]. For a discussion of the concept of signaling in job markets see [Spence 73].

    Google Scholar 

  146. Cf. [Doyle 89].

    Google Scholar 

  147. Cf. [Kihlstrom 74b, p. 99], [Sass 84], [Hänchen 85], [Bagwell 94].

    Google Scholar 

  148. Cf. [Bagwell 93, p. 225]. Akerlof argues in a slightly different way, in his ‘market for lemons’ informed sellers offer cars with a quality below the average quality offered on the market, and thus introduces a negative difference between the true quality level and the one expected by consumers, cf. [Akerlof 70].

    Google Scholar 

  149. Cf. [Stigler 61, p. 216].

    Google Scholar 

  150. Cf. [Kamien 70], [Weitzman 79], [Dasgupta 80].

    Google Scholar 

  151. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 192].

    Google Scholar 

  152. Cf. [Varian93, p. 316 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  153. In an economic relationship one participant has some private information that the other does not have, cf. [Arrow 85, p. 37 fp.], [Rasmusen 89, p. 133 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  154. For an overview of principal-agent theory see [Ross 73], [Jensen 76], [Pratt 85], [Spremann 87], [Spremann 90], [Kiener 90, p. 19 fp.], [Ordelheide 93, p. 1844], [Picot 96, p.47fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  155. Cf. [Pratt 85, p. 1 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  156. Cf. [Arrow 85, p. 37].

    Google Scholar 

  157. Cf. [Pratt 85, p. 17].

    Google Scholar 

  158. Cf. [Arrow 85, p. 37].

    Google Scholar 

  159. Cf. [Pratt 85, p. 3], [Spremann 88, p. 617].

    Google Scholar 

  160. Cf. [Jensen 76, p. 308].

    Google Scholar 

  161. Cf. [Spremann 90, p. 562 fp.], [Arrow 85, p. 38 fjp.].

    Google Scholar 

  162. Cf. [Picot 96, p. 49].

    Google Scholar 

  163. Cf. [Spremann 88, p. 617], [Spremann 90, p. 575].

    Google Scholar 

  164. Cf. [Pratt 85, p. 17].

    Google Scholar 

  165. Cf. [Spremann 88, p. 617], [Picot 96, p. 48].

    Google Scholar 

  166. The term ‘efficient’ refers to informational efficiency, see, for example, Section 2.4.1.

    Google Scholar 

  167. Cf. [Spremann 90, p. 577].

    Google Scholar 

  168. Cf. [Spremann 88, p. 618].

    Google Scholar 

  169. Cf. [Eccles 85, p. 152 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  170. Cf. [Spremann 88, p. 620].

    Google Scholar 

  171. Cf. [Spremann 88, p. 618 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  172. Cf. [Spremann 88, p. 621 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  173. Cf. [Picot 96, p. 49–50].

    Google Scholar 

  174. Cf. [Picot 96, p. 50].

    Google Scholar 

  175. Cf. [Arrow 85, p. 46 fjp.].

    Google Scholar 

  176. Cf. Section 2.2.1 and [Johnson 85].

    Google Scholar 

  177. Cf. [Nelson 70].

    Google Scholar 

  178. Cf. [Kaas 90, p. 543].

    Google Scholar 

  179. These characteristics hold, for example, for services that require a high degree of experience, knowledge and education, cf. [Kaas 90, p. 543].

    Google Scholar 

  180. Cf. [Darby 73, p. 68 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  181. Cf. [Darby 73, p. 69], [Kaas 90, p. 543].

    Google Scholar 

  182. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 54], [Spremann 88], [Rasmusen 89, p. 169].

    Google Scholar 

  183. The role of reputation has been extensively studied in game theory, cf. [Kreps 82], [Sabourian 89], [Holler 93, p. 173 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  184. Cf. [Spremann 88].

    Google Scholar 

  185. Third parties have the opportunity to efficiently perform monitoring and quality assuring tasks because they can concentrate in a special thematic area, become experts in determining the quality of products and services, and spread the costs for information acquisition among a large number of clients. See Section 3.2.3.2.

    Google Scholar 

  186. Licensing is a form of input market regulation that is usually found in the public sector, for example, for physicians or lawyers, cf. [Leland 79], [Shapiro 86].

    Google Scholar 

  187. Cf. [Lizzeri 96].

    Google Scholar 

  188. Examples of third parties that perform monitoring can be found in the literature of financial intermediation, see, for example, [Diamond 84]. See Section 3.2.3.2 as well.

    Google Scholar 

  189. Cf. [McAfee 87, p. 699].

    Google Scholar 

  190. Cf. Section 2.1.1.3.

    Google Scholar 

  191. Cf. [Rothschild 73], [McAfee 87].

    Google Scholar 

  192. Information available on the market is, for example, buyers’ demand and sellers’ supply, cf. [McAfee 87, p. 700]. Under costly information acquisition this information is not acquired by all market participants. A result may be, for example, that agents do not know when and at what prices they can sell or buy, cf. [Ioannides 75, p. 248].

    Google Scholar 

  193. Cf. [Spremann 90] and Section 2.3.2.

    Google Scholar 

  194. Cf. [Hayek 45, p. 525].

    Google Scholar 

  195. Cf. Section 2.1.6. The formation of prices in auctions and bidding is studied in [McAfee 87].

    Google Scholar 

  196. Cf. [Spremann 90, p. 574]. Here, private information of single agents is completely redundant, cf. [Bray 89, p. 263].

    Google Scholar 

  197. In an informationally efficient market there would be no alternative price vector that leaves everyone at least as well off and makes some strictly better off. This can be derived from the definition of Pareto-efficiency, cf. [Varian 93, p. 15, 299 fp.], [Hopf 83, p. 61].

    Google Scholar 

  198. Cf. [Fama 70, p. 383].

    Google Scholar 

  199. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 52]. For a comprehensive treatment of auctions and a review of the related literature see [Stark 79], [Engelbrecht-Wiggans 80], [McAfee 87]. Especially capital markets are assumed to be informationally efficient: ‘at any time prices fully reflect all available information,’ cf. [Fama 70, p. 383].

    Google Scholar 

  200. Cf. Section 2.2.

    Google Scholar 

  201. The optimal amount of information acquisition is given by the condition that the marginal costs of information acquisition equal the marginal returns from the information, see Section 2.2.1, [Hopf 83, p. 56], and Section 4.2.

    Google Scholar 

  202. Cf. [Grossmann 80].

    Google Scholar 

  203. Cf. [Grossmann 80, p. 394], [Hopf 83, p. 42].

    Google Scholar 

  204. Cf. [Grossmann 80, p. 395], [Milgrom 82].

    Google Scholar 

  205. Cf. [Hirshleifer 71, p. 567]. Hirshleifer argues in terms of foreknowledge, which he defines as the ability to successfully predict future states of the environment, cf. [Hirshleifer 71, p. 562].

    Google Scholar 

  206. Cf. [Stigler 62, p. 103].

    Google Scholar 

  207. A review of different models is given in [Rothschild 73].

    Google Scholar 

  208. Roughly speaking, search models usually investigate the aspect of missing information in markets, see for example [Ioannides 75]. Whereas, bargaining models mainly focus the effects of asymmetrically informed market participants, cf. [Chatterjee 83].

    Google Scholar 

  209. Cf. [Salop 77].

    Google Scholar 

  210. The argument was derived by means of a sequential search model, cf. [MacMinn 80].

    Google Scholar 

  211. For a definition of reservation values in sequential search processes see Section4.2.2.1.

    Google Scholar 

  212. Cf. [McAfee 87, p. 711 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  213. Cf. [Milgrom 82], [Engelbrecht-Wiggans 83], [Glosten 85].

    Google Scholar 

  214. Cf. [Akerlof 70].

    Google Scholar 

  215. Cf. [McAfee 87, p. 733]. ‘Information available on the market’ here encloses publicly available information as well as private information.

    Google Scholar 

  216. Cf. [Grossmann 80, p. 394].

    Google Scholar 

  217. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 56]. Costs for information acquisition are part of the transaction costs, cf. Section 3.2.2.2.

    Google Scholar 

  218. Cf. [Pratt 85], [Spremann 87], [Laux 90], and Section 2.3.1.4.

    Google Scholar 

  219. Cf. [Williamson 86], [Simon 91].

    Google Scholar 

  220. Cf. [Malone 87].

    Google Scholar 

  221. See Section 3.4.

    Google Scholar 

  222. Cf. [Hirshleifer 73, p. 32].

    Google Scholar 

  223. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 69].

    Google Scholar 

  224. Cf. Section 2.1.4, [Kihlstrom 74b, p. 100], and [Laux 91, p. 185 fp.] respectively. Menger [Menger 68, p. 7–31] distinguishes between first-order commodities, i.e., commodities that directly satisfy consumer needs and higher-order commodities, i.e., commodities that substitute or improve the consumption of first-order commodities, cf. [Hopf 83, p. 71–72]. Market information can be characterized as a third-order commodity, for it improves the satisfaction of consumers’ needs, cf. [Hopf 83, p. 74].

    Google Scholar 

  225. Cf. [Tietzel 81, p. 210]. Alchian describes property rights as ‘socially recognized rights of action,’ cf. [Alchian 72]. See [Ordelheide 93, p. 1842] for a brief overview about property rights approaches, and [Whinston 97, p. 175–212] for aspects of copyright protection for electronic products.

    Google Scholar 

  226. Cf. [Andel 92, p. 383], [Musgrave 73, p. 52 fp.]. Musgrave characterizes these goods as social goods, cf. [Musgrave 73, p. 51 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  227. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 80 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  228. Cf. Section 2.1.1.3 and Section 2.3.2.

    Google Scholar 

  229. Cf. Figure 5.

    Google Scholar 

  230. Cf. Section 2.4.1.

    Google Scholar 

  231. Cf. [Musgrave 73, p. 58 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  232. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 85].

    Google Scholar 

  233. Cf. [Andel 92, p. 385 fp.], [Musgrave 94, p. 63 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  234. Cf. [Andel 92, p. 385–386].

    Google Scholar 

  235. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 87].

    Google Scholar 

  236. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 93].

    Google Scholar 

  237. Market participants following the decisions of other market participants can utilize the information inherent in the decisions of those agents. In capital markets these effects are known as herd behavior, cf. [Pfister 98, p. 1, 28], [Banerjee 92].

    Google Scholar 

  238. However, in case of technological information the utilization of the information by competitors is to a large extent restricted to the producer through patents, cf. [Hirsh-leifer 73, p. 33].

    Google Scholar 

  239. Cf. [Tietzel 81, p. 211 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  240. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 86], [Musgrave 94, p. 77 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  241. Cf. [Bagnoli 89].

    Google Scholar 

  242. Cf. [Musgrave 73, p. 52].

    Google Scholar 

  243. Hopf puts it: ‘information is a typical lemon good,’ cf. [Hopf 83, p. 76, 92], which indicates a tendency to market failures in markets for information.

    Google Scholar 

  244. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 88].

    Google Scholar 

  245. Cf. [Musgrave 73, p. 80 fp.], [Andel 92, p. 386 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  246. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 89].

    Google Scholar 

  247. Cf. [Kuhlen 95, p. xxiii].

    Google Scholar 

  248. Cf. [Kuhlen 95, p. 3–23].

    Google Scholar 

  249. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 97].

    Google Scholar 

  250. On perfectly competitive markets prices have to be taken as externally given by every market participant, cf. [Varian 93, p. 282].

    Google Scholar 

  251. Cf. [Allen 90, p. 271].

    Google Scholar 

  252. A monopoly or an oligopoly, cf. [Hopf 83, p. 179, 208].

    Google Scholar 

  253. Cf. Section 2.2.3 and Section 2.3.2 respectively.

    Google Scholar 

  254. Cf. Section 2.1.1.2 and 2.1.6.

    Google Scholar 

  255. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 191 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  256. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 208 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  257. Cf. [Knoblich 85, p. 561], [Bessler 85, p. 18–27].

    Google Scholar 

  258. The primary need for information occurs in a different enterprise, which is not the enterprise under consideration here, cf. [Knoblich 85, p. 562].

    Google Scholar 

  259. Cf. [Bessler 85, p. 18–27].

    Google Scholar 

  260. The principle functions: combination of production factors, independence, and making profit are according to Gutenberg the basic aspects that characterize enterprises, cf. [Gutenberg 83, p. 2 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  261. Cf. [Höring 80, p. 914].

    Google Scholar 

  262. Cf. [Knoblich 85, p. 564–565].

    Google Scholar 

  263. For a detailed discussion of information brokers see Section 5.1.4.

    Google Scholar 

  264. Cf. [Bessler 85, p. 173].

    Google Scholar 

  265. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 202 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  266. Cf. [Hopf 83, p. 206], [Varian 95], [Varian 97a], [Varian 97b].

    Google Scholar 

  267. Cf. [Varian 95], [Varian 97b].

    Google Scholar 

  268. Third-degree price discrimination means that different purchasers are charged different prices, but each purchaser pays a constant amount for each unit of the good bought, cf. [Varian 89, p. 600 fp.].

    Google Scholar 

  269. Cf. [Varian 89, p. 599], [Varian 97b].

    Google Scholar 

  270. Perfect price discrimination occurs in a situation in which the seller makes a single take-it-or-leave-it offer to each consumer, cf. [Varian 89, p. 601].

    Google Scholar 

  271. Here, we simply assumed that there are only two groups of consumers, one with a high and another with a low willingness to pay. In real-life settings, however, there is usually a continuum of the willingness to pay, cf. Section 4.3.1.2.

    Google Scholar 

  272. Cf. [Varian 97b].

    Google Scholar 

  273. It is p l < p h and x l < x h.

    Google Scholar 

  274. Cf. [Varian 97b, p. 8].

    Google Scholar 

  275. Cf. [Varian 97b, p. 9].

    Google Scholar 

  276. Cf. Section 2.1.5.

    Google Scholar 

  277. Cf. [Admati 86].

    Google Scholar 

  278. Cf. [Varian 97b, p. 7].

    Google Scholar 

  279. Cf. [Varian 89, p. 626 fp.], [Varian 95], [Bakos 96], [Bakos 97a].

    Google Scholar 

  280. Cf. [Admati 86].

    Google Scholar 

  281. Cf. [Crawford 82], [Admati 86].

    Google Scholar 

  282. Cf. [Admati 90].

    Google Scholar 

  283. Cf. [Bode 97, p. 452] and Section 2.1.5.

    Google Scholar 

  284. Cf. [Schwuchow 97, p. 776].

    Google Scholar 

  285. Cf. [Alter 96, p. 294–295].

    Google Scholar 

  286. Cf. [Zahedi 96, p. 2088], for telecommunication and computer networks see [Alter 96, p. 470–485], [Tanenbaum 96].

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1999 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Rose, F. (1999). Information. In: The Economics, Concept, and Design of Information Intermediaries. Information Age Economy. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-99805-8_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-99805-8_2

  • Publisher Name: Physica-Verlag HD

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-7908-1168-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-99805-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics