Skip to main content

Using the Entropy Approach to Characterize the Environment as a Supplier of Resources

  • Chapter
Entropy, Environment and Resources
  • 58 Accesses

Abstract

So far the flow of environmental goods (or the negative flow of entropy) from the ecological system into the economic system has not been closely specified. In the following we want to show how the problem of resource scarcity can be specified within the entropy approach. We start by taking note of the fact that the flow of environmental goods, carrying with it a negative flow of entropy into the economic system, contains also the raw materials needed for the manufacturing of the consumption and capital goods in the production sector. The supply of the economic system with raw materials from the environmental sector can therefore only be secured if the ecological system possesses the long-run capability of providing a negative flow of entropy into the economic system. This negative flow of entropy must correspond to the desires of the economic agents.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. In reality a 100% concentration of a mineral which is extracted from an ore is not feasible.

    Google Scholar 

  2. In reality, as a rule, it is hardly feasible that a perfect separation of the desired type of particles is achieved after a few processes. In the enrichment of uranium with the gas centrifugue procedure, for instance, several thousand extraction processes are necessary in order to win fissionable material.

    Google Scholar 

  3. This information is due to Dipl.-Ing. H.P.Lauff, Stahlwerke Peine-Salzgitter A.G., May 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  4. The first postulate describes that there is a linear relationship between the volume of a solid body and its mass (which is given by the specific density). The second postulate is known in gas theory as the Rule of AVOGADRO. According to this rule a given volume of gas always contains the same number of mols regardless of which gas is chosen and provided that conditions are the same.

    Google Scholar 

  5. A similar formula is derived by Chapman and Roberts (1983:91) for metals. The two authors also discuss the difficulties of applying this formula in practice.

    Google Scholar 

  6. This confirms the first derivation of equation (4.10) with regard to the initial concentration. For

    Google Scholar 

  7. We remind the reader that according to our comment on formula (3.8), the correct relationship should be TdS = dU-|∂A| instead of (4.13). |A here is the work which has been performed on the corresponding system. Since we have assumed, however, that the total energy is used to change the order of the system only, |∂A| = 0. We employ this simplified relationship since we are mainly interested in qualitative results.

    Google Scholar 

  8. An empirical illustration of some micro-and macroeconomic aspects of the relationship (4.19) and (4.21) is given by Faber and Wagenhals (1987, Sect. 3), who analyze data of a single copper mine in Chile and the total copper mine production of the United States.

    Google Scholar 

  9. It may be tempting to argue that resources which cannot be substituted are essential, i.e. that F (K, L, R = 0) = 0. As Dasgupta and Heal (1979:196ff.) show, however, this would be a mistake.

    Google Scholar 

  10. In a more detailed investigation — which would, however, considerably complicate our derivations above — this statement only holds if we take into consideration that the resources will be diffusely distributed in the environmental sector after having been used in the economic system. This relationship was already noted above in the context of our second example in Sect. 3.6.

    Google Scholar 

  11. This Section is based on parts of Sect. 3.2 of Faber (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  12. While we have concentrated on exhaustible resources, Murota (1984) has made an attempt to develop a framework for renewable resources, in particular with regard to water and forests.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1995 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Faber, M., Niemes, H., Stephan, G. (1995). Using the Entropy Approach to Characterize the Environment as a Supplier of Resources. In: Entropy, Environment and Resources. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-57832-8_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-57832-8_5

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-58984-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-57832-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics