Skip to main content

Oil Futures Market: A Dynamic Model of Hedging and Speculation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Interrelationship Between Financial and Energy Markets

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Energy ((LNEN,volume 54))

Abstract

This paper develops a non linear model for oil futures prices which accounts for pressures due to hedging and speculative activities. The corresponding spot market is assumed to maintain a long term equilibrium relationship with the futures prices in line with the presence of an arbitrage led time varying basis. The model combines an error correction relationship for the cash returns and a non linear parameterization of the corresponding futures returns with a bivariate CCC-TGARCH representation of the conditional variances. The dynamic interaction between spot and futures returns in the oil market has been investigated over the 1990–2010 time period. We have found clear evidence of the activity of hedgers and speculators on the futures markets and the role of the latter is far from negligible. Finally, in order to capture the consequences of the growing impact of financial flows on commodity market pricing, a two-state regime switching model for futures returns has been implemented. The empirical findings indicate that hedging and speculative behavior change across the two regimes, which we associate with low and high return volatility, according to a distinctive pattern.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Fagan and Gencay (2008) find that hedgers and speculators are often counterparties, since they tend to take opposing positions. Their respective long positions exhibit a strong negative correlation.

  2. 2.

    The hedge ratio is also defined as the ratio between the number of futures and cash contracts.

  3. 3.

    On this point see Figuerola-Ferretti and Gonzalo (2010). They successfully apply a VECM approach to cash and futures commodity returns where cash prices adjust to futures prices, in line with the Garbade and Silber (1983) framework of price discovery.

  4. 4.

    The futures contract expires on the third business day prior to the 25th calendar day of the month preceding the delivery month. If the 25th calendar day of the month is a non-business day, trading ceases on the third business day prior to the business day preceding the 25th calendar day.

  5. 5.

    The unit root test statistics are not reported due to lack of space.

  6. 6.

    The t-ratios reported in the tables are based on the robust quasi-maximum likelihood estimation procedure of Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) since the J.B. test statistics reject the null of normality of the standardized residuals.

  7. 7.

    See Chang (1985) and Bessembinder (1992).

  8. 8.

    For a definition of this measure, see Achen (1982, pp. 72–73).

  9. 9.

    CCC-TGARCH estimates

    OLS estimates

    Naive

    Optimal hedge ratio β*

    St. dev. of the optimal hedge portfolio

    Optimal hedge ratio β*

    St. dev. of the optimal hedge portfolio

    St. dev. of the naive portfolio

    0.75

    0.016309

    0.70

    0.016416

    0.018018

  10. 10.

    In order to eliminate the potential errors-in-variables distortions due to the use of a two-step procedure, we follow Pagan (1984). We replace the conditional variances by the fitted value of a regression of the futures (cash) return conditional variance on a constant, on its own lagged values (up to two lags), on the lagged values (up to two lags) of the conditional variance of the cash (futures) returns and on the one period lagged cash rate of return. The estimated coefficients are consistent, whereas the corresponding standard errors may underestimate their true values. However, this potential bias does not affect the SPEC index, which is consistent.

  11. 11.

    The average expected duration of being in state 1 is computed according to Hamilton (1989) as \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{\infty } {ip_{11}^{i - 1} \left( {1 - p_{11} } \right) = \left( {1 - p_{11} } \right)^{ - 1} = \left( {p_{12} } \right)^{ - 1} } \). If we posit that regime 1 (2) at time t holds if the probability of being in state 1 based on data through t is larger (smaller) than 0.5, the oil market is in the low volatility regime 1 for 4,777 days and in the high volatility regime 2 for 466 days.

  12. 12.

    We detect therefore an overall increase in the share of agents that follow a speculative rationale and a corresponding decrease in the number of standard risk minimizing investors.

  13. 13.

    According to the standard ADF unit root tests the time t regime 1 probability time series is I(0). The correlation coefficients between the regime 1 probability and the daily oil futures’ rate of return and standard deviation are, respectively, 0.035 (2.52) and −0.756 (−83.68), where the t-ratios are in parentheses. Regime 1 is to be associated with both low futures return variability and, to a lesser extent, with positive futures price rates of change (i.e. possibly with a bullish market), and regime 2 with high return variability and negative futures price rates of change (i.e. with a bearish market).

References

  • Achen C (1982) Interpreting and using regression. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks

    Google Scholar 

  • Ai C, Chatrath A, Song F (2006) On the comovement of commodity prices. Am J Agric Econ 88:574–588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alizadeh A, Nomikos N (2004) A Markov regime switching approach for hedging stock indices. J Futures Markets 24:649–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessembinder H (1992) Systematic risk, hedging pressure and risk premiums in futures markets. Rev Finan Stud 5:637–667

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev T, Wooldridge JM (1992) Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation and inference in dynamic models with time-varying covariances. Econometr Rev 11:143–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cashin P, McDermott CJ, Scott A (1999) The myth of comoving commodity prices. IMF working paper 169

    Google Scholar 

  • Cecchetti SG, Cumby RE, Figlewski S (1988) Estimation of the optimal futures hedge. Rev Econ Stat 70:623–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan W, Young D (2006) Jumping hedges: an examination of movements in copper spot and futures markets. J Futures Markets 26:169–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang B (1985) Returns to speculators and the theory of normal backwardation. J Finan 4:193–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle RF, Ng VK (1993) Measuring and testing the impact of news on volatility. J Finan 48:1749–1778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagan S, Gencay R (2008) Liquidity-induced dynamics in futures markets. MPRA working paper 6677 January

    Google Scholar 

  • Figlewski S (1984) Hedging performance and basis risk in stock index futures. J Finan 39:657–669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Figuerola-Ferretti I, Gonzalo J (2010) Modelling and measuring price discovery in commodity markets. J Econometr 158:95–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garbade KD, Silber WL (1983) Price movements and price discovery in futures and cash markets. Rev Econ Stat 65:289–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JD (1989) A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57:357–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JD (1994) Time series analysis. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Irwin SH, Sanders DR, Merrin RP (2009) Devil or angel? The role of speculation in the recent commodity price boom (and bust). J Agric Appl Econ 41:377–391

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson LL (1960) The theory of hedging and speculation in commodity futures. Rev Econ Stud 27:139–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolb RW, Okunev J (1992) An empirical evaluation of the extended Mean-Gini coefficient for futures hedging. J Futures Markets 12:177–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroner KF, Sultan J (1993) Time-varying distribution and dynamic hedging with foreign currency futures. J Finan Quant Anal 28:535–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee TH, Yoder J (2007) Optimal hedging with a regime-switching time-varying correlation Garch model. J Futures Markets 27:495–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Pen Y, Sévi B (2010) Revisiting the excess co-movements of commodity prices in a data-rich environment. Memo Université de Nantes, Nantes

    Google Scholar 

  • Lescaroux F (2009) On the excess co-movement of commodity prices—a note about the role of fundamental factors in short-run dynamics. Energy Policy 37:3906–3913

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lien D, Tse YK (2000) Hedging downside risk with future contracts. Appl Finan Econ 10:163–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnon RL (1967) Futures markets, buffer stocks and income stability for primary producers. J Polit Econ 73:844–861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagan A (1984) Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated regressors. Int Econ Rev 25:221–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Pyndick RS, Rotemberg JJ (1990) The excess co-movement of commodity prices. Econ J 100:1173–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarno L, Valente G (2000) The cost of carry model and regime shifts in stock index futures markets: an empirical investigation. J Futures Markets 20:603–624

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein JL (1961) The simultaneous determination of spot and futures prices. Am Econ Rev 51:1012–1025

    Google Scholar 

  • Stulz RM (1996) Rethinking risk management. J Appl Corp Finan 9:8–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tokic D (2011) Rational destabilizing speculation, positive feedback trading, and the oil bubble of 2008. Energy Policy 39:2051–2061

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward RW, Fletcher LB (1971) From hedging to pure speculation: a micro model of futures and cash market positions. Am J Agric Econ 53:71–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giulio Cifarelli .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Cifarelli, G., Paladino, G. (2014). Oil Futures Market: A Dynamic Model of Hedging and Speculation. In: Ramos, S., Veiga, H. (eds) The Interrelationship Between Financial and Energy Markets. Lecture Notes in Energy, vol 54. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-55382-0_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-55382-0_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-55381-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-55382-0

  • eBook Packages: EnergyEnergy (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics