Skip to main content

Self-Organizing Financial Stability Map

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Mapping Financial Stability

Part of the book series: Computational Risk Management ((Comp. Risk Mgmt))

  • 955 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter ties together most of the previous parts of this book. Macroprudential oversight and data alike not only motivate, but also provide guidelines for building tools with visual capabilities. Data and dimension reductions, as well as their combinations, provide means for creating visual displays for a wide range of tasks, whereas a qualitative comparison shows that the Self-Organizing Map (SOM) is suitable for the task we have at hand. This chapter unifies the above discussed topics by creating a SOM-based financial stability map, coined the Self-Organizing Financial Stability Map (SOFSM). The task involves five key building blocks: the SOM, crisis dates, vulnerability indicators, a model training framework and a model evaluation framework.

I would very much welcome inspiration from other disciplines: physics, engineering, psychology, biology. Bringing experts from these fields together with economists and central bankers is potentially very creative and valuable. Scientists have developed sophisticated tools for analysing complex dynamic systems in a rigorous way. These models have proved helpful in understanding many important but complex phenomena: epidemics, weather patterns, crowd psychology, magnetic fields.[...] I am hopeful that central banks can also benefit from these insights in developing tools to analyse financial markets and monetary policy transmission.

– Jean-Claude Trichet, President of the ECB, Frankfurt am Main,

18 November 2010

This chapter is partly based upon previous research. Please see the following works for further information: Sarlin and Peltonen (2013) and Sarlin (2013c)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    When the 3-month government bill rate is not available, the spread between interbank and T-bill rates of the closest maturity is used. The equity returns are multiplied by minus one, so that negative returns increase stress, while positive returns are set to 0. When computing realized volatilities for components \(\text {Ind}_{3{-}5}\), average daily absolute changes over a quarter are used.

  2. 2.

    The noise-to-signal ratio is a ratio of the probability of receiving a signal conditional on no crisis occurring to the probability of receiving a signal conditional on a crisis occurring. Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (2000) and El-Shagi et al. (2012) showed that minimizing the noise-to-signal ratio could lead to a relatively high share of missed crisis episodes (i.e., only noise minimization) if crises are rare and the cost of missing a crisis is high. This type of a common corner solution to the optimization problem is mainly due to the fact that the marginal rate of substitution between type I and II errors is unrestricted. Lund-Jensen (2012) concludes the same, and chooses not to use the measure, while Drehmann et al. (2011) choose to minimize the noise-to-signal-ratio subject to at least two thirds of the crises being correctly called. Likewise, Sarlin (2013c) also illustrates such a corner solution.

  3. 3.

    While the seminal loss function by Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (2000) accounts for unconditional probabilities, they do not propose a Usefulness measure for the function. Given their complex definition of loss, deriving the Usefulness would not be an entirely straightforward exercise. Further, the version applied in Bussière and Fratzscher (2008) neither accounts for unconditional probabilities nor distinguishes between losses from correct and wrong calls of crisis.

  4. 4.

    A further discussion on shaping decision-makers’ problems through loss functions, as well as on the relation between statistical and economic value of predictions, can be found in Granger and Pesaran (2000) and Abhyankar et al. (2005).

  5. 5.

    The loss function used by Alessi and Detken (2011) differs from the one introduced here as it assumes equal class size. Their Usefulness measure does, similarly, not account for imbalanced classes, as the loss of disregarding a model depends solely on the preferences. Usefulness measures close to that in Alessi and Detken (2011) have been applied in a large number of works, such as Lo Duca and Peltonen (2013), Sarlin and Marghescu (2011a), El-Shagi et al. (2012), Bisias et al. (2012). Similar loss functions have been applied in Fuertes and Kalotychou (2007), Candelon et al. (2012), Lund-Jensen (2012), Knedlik and Schweinitz (2012).

  6. 6.

    Recall positives \(= TP/(TP+FN)\), Recall negatives \(= TN/(TN+FP)\), Precision positives \(= TP/(TP+FP)\), Precision negatives \(= TN/(TN+FN)\), Accuracy \(= (TP+TN)/(TP+TN+FP+FN)\), TP rate \(= TP / (TP + FN)\), FP rate \(= FP/(FP+TN)\), FN rate \(= FN/(FN+TP)\) and TN rate \(= TN/(FP+TN)\).

  7. 7.

    The BMU is the unit that has the shortest Euclidean distance to a data point. When evaluating an already trained SOM model, all data are projected onto the map using only the indicator vector \(x_{j(in)}\in \mathbb {R}^{14}\). For each data point, probabilities of a crisis in 6, 12, 18 and 24 months are obtained by retrieving the values of C6, C12, C18 and C24 of its BMU (\(m_{b(cl)}\)).

  8. 8.

    The logistic regression proceeds as follows. First, it forms a predictor variable which is a linear combination of the explanatory variables. The values of this predictor variable are transformed into probabilities by a logistic function. This logistic function operates through \(f(z)=\frac{1}{1+e^{-z}}\), where \(z=\beta _{0}+\beta _{1}x_{1}+\beta _{2}x_{2}+\beta _{3}x_{3}+...+\beta _{k}x_{k}\), \(\upbeta _{o}\) is the intercept and \(\upbeta _{1}+\upbeta _{2}+\upbeta _{3}+...\upbeta _{k}\) are the regression coefficients of \(x_{1}+x_{2}+x_{3}+...+x_{k}\), respectively. The value of \(z\) measures the total contribution of all the predictor variables used in the model. It is worth to note that \(f(z)\rightarrow 0\) when \(z\rightarrow -\infty \), and \(f(z)\rightarrow 1\) when \(z\rightarrow \infty \). Moreover, when \(z=0\), then \(f(z)=0.5\). Thereby, a response curve for a logistic regression is S-shaped.

References

  • Abhyankar, A., Sarno, L., & Valente, G. (2005). Exchange rates and fundamentals: Evidence on the economic value of predictability. Journal of International Economics, 66, 325–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alessi, L., & Detken, C. (2011). Quasi real time early warning indicators for costly asset price boom/bust cycles: A role for global liquidity. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(3), 520–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisias, D., Flood, M., Lo, A., & Valavanis, S. (2012). A survey of systemic risk analytics. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 4, 255–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borio, C., Lowe, P., 2002. Asset prices, financial and monetary stability: Exploring the nexus, BIS Working Papers No. 114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio, C., Lowe, P., 2004. Securing sustainable price stability: Should credit come back from the wilderness?, BIS Working Papers No. 157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bussière, M., & Fratzscher, M. (2006). Towards a new early warning system of financial crises. Journal of International Money and Finance, 25(6), 953–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bussière, M., & Fratzscher, M. (2008). Low probability, high impact: Policy making and extreme events. Journal of Policy Modeling, 30, 111–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candelon, B., Dumitrescu, E., & Hurlin, C. (2012). How to evaluate an early-warning system: Toward a unified statistical framework for assessing financial crises forecasting methods. IMF Economic Review, 60(1), 75–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Detragiache, E. (2000). Monitoring banking sector fragility: A multivariate logit. World Bank Economic Review, 14(2), 287–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drehmann, M., Borio, C., & Tsatsaronis, K. (2011). Anchoring countercyclical capital buffers: The role of credit aggregates. International Journal of Central Banking, 7(4), 189–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • El-Shagi, M., Knedlik, T., von Schweinitz, G., 2012. Predicting financial crises: The (statistical) significance of the signals approach, IWH Discussion Papers No. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elkan, C. (2001). The foundations of cost-sensitive learning. Proceedings of the International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI 01) (pp. 973–978). USA: Seattle.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fawcett, T. (2006). ROC graphs with instance-varying costs. Pattern Recognition Letters, 27(8), 882–891.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuertes, A.-M., & Kalotychou, E. (2006). Early warning system for sovereign debt crisis: The role of heterogeneity. Computational Statistics and Data Analysis, 5, 1420–1441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuertes, A.-M., & Kalotychou, E. (2007). Towards the optimal design of an early warning system for sovereign debt crises. International Journal of Forecasting, 23(1), 85–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C., & Pesaran, M. (2000). Economic and statistical measures of forecast accuracy. Journal of Forecasting, 19, 537–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holló, D., Kremer, M., & Lo Duca, M. (2012). CISS - a composite indicator of systemic stress in the financial system. ECB working paper, No. 1426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jordá, O., & Taylor, A. (2011). Performance evaluation of zero net-investment strategies. NBER working paper, No. 17150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaminsky, G., Lizondo, S., & Reinhart, C. (1998). Leading indicators of currency crises. IMF Staff Papers, 45(1), 1–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaski, S., Venna, J., & Kohonen, T. (2001). Coloring that reveals cluster structures in multivariate data. Australian Journal of Intelligent Information Processing Systems, 60, 2–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knedlik, T., & von Schweinitz, G. (2012). Macroeconomic imbalances as indicators for debt crises in europe. Journal of Common Market Studies, 50(5), 726–745.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohonen, T. (2001). Self-organizing maps (3rd ed.). Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lo Duca, M., & Peltonen, T. (2013). Assessing systemic risks and predicting systemic events. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(7), 2183–2195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lund-Jensen, K. (2012). Monitoring systemic risk based on dynamic thresholds. IMF working paper, No. 12/159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarlin, P. (2013). On policymakers’ loss functions and the evaluation of early warning systems. Economics Letters, 119(1), 1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarlin, P., & Marghescu, D. (2011). Neuro-genetic predictions of currency crises. Intelligent Systems in Accounting, Finance and Management, 18(4), 145–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarlin, P., & Peltonen, T. (2013). Mapping the state of financial stability. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 26, 46–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Sarlin .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Sarlin, P. (2014). Self-Organizing Financial Stability Map. In: Mapping Financial Stability. Computational Risk Management. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-54956-4_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-54956-4_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-54955-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-54956-4

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics