Skip to main content

Economic and Procedural Constraints of Compulsory Licences for Medicines

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Compulsory Licensing

Part of the book series: MPI Studies on Intellectual Property and Competition Law ((MSIP,volume 22))

Abstract

The chapter argues that since there is no conclusive evidence for a causal relationship between the issuance of compulsory licences (CL) for medicines and any fall in innovation or foreign direct investment (FDI) inflow, various other factors like predictability and market potential need to be taken into account for understanding the after-effects of a grant of CL. The chapter examines the trends in CLs after the Doha Declaration and carves out a case for adhering to transparent procedures for imparting some predictability to the process in order to mitigate losses from possible repercussions.

Y. Goyal is Associate Professor. Ph.D. Candidate at the University of Hamburg, Germany.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, for e.g., Balasubramaniam (2002).

  2. 2.

    See Cahoy (2008), p. 141.

  3. 3.

    Mazzoleni and Nelson (1998), p. 273, show that conventional thinking among economists, lawyers, and many public officials is heavily weighted towards the proposition that ‘patent rights are conducive to economic progress’.

  4. 4.

    For a very interesting study on this, see Reichman and Lewis (2005).

  5. 5.

    Gilbert and Shapiro (1996), pp. 12753–12754, briefly mention how compulsory licence may reduce efficiency.

  6. 6.

    See, for this study, McFetridge (1998).

  7. 7.

    Ibid, p. 84 (McFetridge reports that with the exception of Merck, 1994, Canadian R&D expenditures as a percentage of worldwide expenditures were less than 2 %; e.g. 1.3 % for Glaxo, 1.0 % for Hoffman LaRoche, 0.7 % for Pfizer, 1.2 % for Sandoz, 1.4 % for Ciba, 1.7 % for Eli Lilly, and 6.1 % for Merck).

  8. 8.

    Moser and Voena (2012), p. 404. They also conclude that this increase of 20 % took 8 to 9 years to set in and remained statistically significant throughout the 1930s (p. 409).

  9. 9.

    Foster and Rosenzweig (1995), p. 1205.

  10. 10.

    Chien (2003), pp. 891–892.

  11. 11.

    See, e.g., Banta (2001), p. 2656; see also Kanth (2003).

  12. 12.

    See, generally, Smith et al. (2009); see also Chaves and Oliveira (2007), pp. 51–54 (focus on Latin American and Caribbean countries).

  13. 13.

    Beall and Kuhn (2012), p. 3. Note that through compulsory licensing, countries can threaten pharmaceutical companies to discipline their pricing behaviour. These disciplining strategies have been discussed (for Thailand and Brazil) in Feldman (2009), pp. 151–155.

  14. 14.

    Ibid, p. 4.

  15. 15.

    Ibid.

  16. 16.

    Ibid.

  17. 17.

    Ibid.

  18. 18.

    Beall and Kuhn (2012), p. 3.

  19. 19.

    For a discussion of Egypt’s CL statute in the copyright context, see International Intellectual Property Alliance 2006: Special 301 Report Egypt.

  20. 20.

    Castellano (2006), p. 289.

  21. 21.

    Bird (2009), p. 212.

  22. 22.

    Ibid, p. 214.

  23. 23.

    Reichman (2009), p. 254.

  24. 24.

    Aziz (2003), p. 22.

  25. 25.

    See “Egypt Pharmaceutical and Healthcare Report Q3 2010,” Business Monitor International, May 2010; available at http://www.researchandmarkets.com/research/d4a32f/egypt_pharmaceutic last accessed on 1 June 2013.

  26. 26.

    Ibid.

  27. 27.

    See, for example, Médecins Sans Frontières Campaign for Access to Essential Medicines, background paper, “Examples of the Importance of India as the ‘Pharmacy for the Developing World’,” available at http://www.doctorswithoutborders.org/news/access/background_paper_indian_generics.pdf last accessed on 1 June 2013.

  28. 28.

    For a detailed treatment of Brazil’s history of use of compulsory licensing in expanding access, see Marques et al. (2005).

  29. 29.

    See ibid, pp. 474–476.

  30. 30.

    See, for e.g., Articles 68 and 71. Article 68 requires that, within 3 years of obtaining a patent, the patent holder must manufacture the subject matter of the patent in Brazil, unless the patent holder can show that local production is not economically feasible or reasonable. Article 71 states that, through an act of the Federal Executive Authorities, a compulsory licence may be granted in cases of “national emergency or public interest”.

  31. 31.

    Bird and Cahoy (2008), p. 313.

  32. 32.

    Passarelli and Terto (2002), p. 42.

  33. 33.

    See chapter “The Use of Compulsory Licences in Latin America” by Carlos M. Correa in this volume.

  34. 34.

    Rich (2001).

  35. 35.

    For details of this case, see Bjornberg (2006).

  36. 36.

    Palermo (2008).

  37. 37.

    van Gelder and Stevens (2010), pp. 5–6.

  38. 38.

    There are certain advantages of government use licences over CLs procedurally under the TRIPS Agreement, the most notable of which is the ability to proceed with the issuance of the government use licence in the absence of failed prior negotiations with the patent holder, and they are thus easier to issue in the face of a medical emergency, for example. At the same time, a government use licence would limit the choice of firms that could import or produce using that licence to government ministries and state-owned enterprises.

  39. 39.

    A rough English translation can be found at http://www.citizen.org/documents/PresidentalDecree20121.pdf last accessed on 1 June 2013.

  40. 40.

    “Indonesia generics: a broad license,” The Economist Intelligence Unit, 17 October 2012.

  41. 41.

    Ibid.

  42. 42.

    Ibid.

  43. 43.

    See original decrees available at http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/c/thailand/thai-cl-kaletra_en.pdf; http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/c/thailand/thaicl4efavirenz.html; http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/c/thailand/thai-cl-clopidogrel_en.pdf last accessed on 1 June 2013.

  44. 44.

    See, for greater detail, the chapter “Compulsory Licences: Law and Practice in Thailand” by Jakkrit Kuanpoth in this volume.

  45. 45.

    Fuller (2007).

  46. 46.

    Lybecker and Fowler (2009), p. 234.

  47. 47.

    Stiglitz (2009), p. 364.

  48. 48.

    Abbott and Reichman (2007), pp. 969–981. Also see, generally, Reichman (2009).

  49. 49.

    Ibid, pp. 973–980.

References

  • Abbott FM, Reichman JH (2007) The Doha Round’s public health legacy: strategies for the production and diffusion of patented medicines under the amended TRIPS provisions. J Int Econ Law 10:921–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aziz S (2003) Linking intellectual property rights in developing countries with research and development, technology transfer, and foreign direct investment policy: a case study of Egypt’s pharmaceutical industry. ILSA J Int Comp Law 10(1)

    Google Scholar 

  • Balasubramaniam K (2002) Access to medicines: patents, prices and public policy – consumer perspectives. In: Drahos P, Mayne R (eds) Global intellectual property rights: knowledge, access and development. Palgrave MacMillan, Hampshire

    Google Scholar 

  • Banta D (2001) Public health triumphs at WTO conference. J Am Med Assoc 286:2655–2656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beall R, Kuhn R (2012) Trends in compulsory licensing of pharmaceuticals since the Doha Declaration: a database analysis. PLoS Med 9(1):e1001154. doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.1001154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird RC (2009) Developing nations and the compulsory license: maximizing access to essential medicines while minimizing investment side effects. J Law Med Ethics 37:209–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird R, Cahoy D (2008) The impact of compulsory licensing on foreign direct investment: a collective bargaining approach. Am Bus Law J 45:283–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjornberg J (2006) Brazil’s recent threat on Abbott’s patent: resolution or retaliation? Northwestern J Int Law Bus 27:199–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Bucknell D (2007) The global IP scorecard for Pharma and Biotech compulsory licences. Mondaq Business Briefing, 22 October. http://www.mondaq.com/australia/article.asp?articleid=53442. Last accessed 20 may 2013

  • Cahoy DR (2008) Confronting Myths and Myopia on the road from Doha. Georgia Law Rev 42:131–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Castellano RA (2006) Note, patent law for new medical uses of known compounds and Pfizer’s Viagra Patent. IDEA 46:283

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaves GC, Oliveira MA (2007) A proposal for measuring the degree of public health-sensitivity of patent legislation in the context of the WTO TRIPS Agreement. Bull World Health Organisation 85:49–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chien CV (2003) Cheap drugs at what price to innovation: does the compulsory licensing of pharmaceuticals hurt innovation? Berkeley Technol Law J 18:853–907

    Google Scholar 

  • David R (2007) Novartis set back in India patent fight over Glivec. Forbes, 7 August. http://www.forbes.com/2007/08/07/novartis-glivec-generics-markets-equity-cx_rd_0807markets02.html. Last accessed 1 June 2013

  • Feldman J (2009) Compulsory licensing: dangers behind current practices. J Int Bus Law 8:137–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisch AM (1994) Compulsory licensing of pharmaceutical patents: an unreasonable solution to an unfortunate problem. Jurimetrics 34:295–315

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster AD, Rosenzweig MR (1995) Learning by doing and learning from others: human capital and technical change in agriculture. J Polit Econ 103:1176–1209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuller T (2007) Thailand takes on drug industry and may be winning. New York Times 11 April. http://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/11/world/asia/11iht-pharma.4.5240049.html?_r=1&pagewanted=1. Last accessed 1 June 2013

  • Gilbert R, Shapiro C (1996) An economic analysis of unilateral refusals to license intellectual property. Proc Acad Sci 93:12749–12755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanth R (2003) WTO drug deal to spark competition. Business Times, 2 September, Singapore

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee S (2011) Compulsory licensing and domestic innovation: evidence from the Trading with the Enemy Act after World War II. Economics Department, Stanford University. http://economics.stanford.edu/files/Lee_HThesis2011.pdf. Accessed 1 June 2013

  • Lee J, Mansfield E (1996) Intellectual property protection and U.S. Foreign Direct Investment. Rev Econ Stat 78:181–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard A (2006) Adventures with Tamiflu. Salon, 7 September. http://www.salon.com/2006/09/06/taiwan_tamiflu/. Last accessed 1 June 2013

  • Lybecker KM, Fowler E (2009) Compulsory licensing in Canada and Thailand: comparing regimes to ensure legitimate use of the WTO rules. J Law Med Ethics 37:222–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marques URQ, Guimarães VS, Sternberg C (2005) Brazil’s AIDS controversy: antiretroviral drugs, breaking patents, and compulsory licensing. Food Drug Law J 60:471–477

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzoleni R, Nelson R (1998) The benefits and costs of strong patent protection: a contribution to the current debate. Res Policy 27:273–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFetridge DG (1998) Intellectual property, technology diffusion, and growth in the Canadian economy. In: Anderson RD, Gallini NT (eds) Competition policy and intellectual property rights in the knowledge based economy. University of Calgary Press, Calgary, pp 64–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Moser P, Voena A (2012) Compulsory licensing: evidence from the trading with the enemy act. Am Econ Rev 102:396–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palermo MP (2008) Brazil may reject Gilead’s AIDS drug patent. Reuters, 10 April. http://www.reuters.com/article/2008/04/10/brazil-aids-gilead-idUSN1034936120080410/. Last accessed 25 May 2013

  • Passarelli C, Terto V (2002) Good medicine: Brazil’s multifront war on AIDS. NACLA Rep Am 35:35

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen M, Rohter L (2011) Maker agrees to cut price of 2 AIDS drugs in Brazil. New York Times, 31 March. http://www.nytimes.com/2001/03/31/world/maker-agrees-to-cut-price-of-2-aids-drugs-in-brazil.html. Last accessed 1 June 2013

  • Reichman JH (2009) Compulsory licensing of patented pharmaceutical inventions: evaluating the options. J Law Med Ethics 37:247–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reichman J, Lewis T (2005) Using liability rules to stimulate local innovation in developing countries: application to traditional knowledge. In: Maskus KE, Reichman J (eds) International public goods and transfer of technology under a globalized intellectual property regime. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 337–366

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rich JL (2001) Roche reaches accord on drug with Brazil. New York Times, 1 September. http://www.nytimes.com/2001/09/01/business/roche-reaches-accord-on-drug-with-brazil.html. Last accessed 30 May 2013

  • Saez C (2010) Ecuador grants first compulsory licence for HIV/AIDS drug. Intellectual Property Watch, 22 April. http://www.ip-watch.org/weblog/2010/04/22/ecuador-grants-first-compulsory-licence-for-hivaids-drug/. Last accessed 1 June 2013

  • Scherer FM (1977) The economic effects of compulsory patent licensing (no. 2). New York University, Graduate School of Business Administration, Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, 1977, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith R, Correa C, Oh C (2009) Trade, TRIPS, and pharmaceuticals. Lancet 373:684–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J (2009) Trade Agreements and health in developing countries. Lancet 373:363–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsai G (2009) Canada’s access to medicines regime: lessons for compulsory licensing schemes under the WTO Doha Declaration. V J Int Law 49:1063–1097

    Google Scholar 

  • van Gelder A, Stevens P (2010) The compulsory license red herring. International Policy Network. http://www.minimalgovernment.net/media/compulsory-201011.pdf. Last accessed 1 June 2013

  • World Development Indicators, World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/BX.KLT.DINV.CD.WD/countries/BR?display=graph

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yugank Goyal .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Goyal, Y. (2015). Economic and Procedural Constraints of Compulsory Licences for Medicines. In: Hilty, R., Liu, KC. (eds) Compulsory Licensing. MPI Studies on Intellectual Property and Competition Law, vol 22. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-54704-1_21

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics