Skip to main content

Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That Bind the (New) Industrial District

  • Conference paper
Complexity and Industrial Clusters

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

Whatever they are exactly, industrial districts are also a worldly success and a conceptual innovation. In Italy, the map of district agglomerations of small and medium-sized firms specializing in particular branches of light industry is no longer limited to the triangle marked by Venice, Florence, and Ancona in the Adriatic Marches. New agglomerations are spreading, as though by contagion, down the shores of the Adriatic and the Mediterranean, now and again obstructed in their march south by the detritus of failed, heavy industrial complexes. Quite apart from this expansion of the districts’ homeland, district-like agglomerations are emerging in some patches of the South of Italy. Looking at the economic map of Europe, the economic agronomist sees a “hot banana” of thriving districts curving from London, through Switzerland and the Southwest of Germany into Northern Italy. In the developing economies districts are identified as a motor of growth in countries as different as Chile, Brazil, and India.

The advance of the industrial district as a concept has at least kept pace with its progress in fact. Discussion of economic growth in both the advanced and developing countries is dominated by what is often called the Washington consensus — concern for opening economies to free trade, getting exchange rates and other prices right, and (lately) building the institutions needed to do this. But insofar as it is not, debate gravitates toward the creation and expansion of “clusters” — the business name for districts. In the European Union in particular fostering clusters is often seen as a way of encouraging economic competitiveness without giving in to US pressure to give markets free reign. In theoretical debates about economic growth and international trade too agglomerations, often explicitly identified with districts, have come to play a central role (although, as we shall see, with surprisingly subversive effects).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Adler, P. S., Goldoftas, B., et al. (1999), “Flexibility vs. Efficiency? A Case Study of Model Changeovers in the Toyota Production System”, Organization Science, 10, pp. 43–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnard, C. I. (1947), The Functions of the Executive, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beardsell, M. and Henderson, V. (1999), “Spatial Evolution of the Computer Industry in the USA”, European Economic Review, 43, pp. 431–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becattini, G. (1990), “The Marshallian Industrial District as a Socio-Economic Notion”, in: Industrial Districts and Inter-Firm Cooperation in Italy, Pyke, F., Becattini, G. and Sengenberger, W.(eds), Geneva, International Institute for Labour Studies, pp. 37–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brusco, S. (1989), Piccole imprese e distretti industrials, una raccolta di saggi, Torino, Rosenberg & Sellier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., Hagstrom, P. et al. (eds) (1998), The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, Organization and Regions, Oxford, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm”, Economica, 4, pp. 397–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dei Ottati, G. (1996), “The Remarkable Resilience of the Industrial Districts of Tuscany”, in: Cossentino, F., Pyke, F. and Sengenberger, W.(eds), Local and Regional Response to Global Pressure: The Case of Italy and Its Industrial Districts, Geneva, International Institute for Labour Studies, pp. 37–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dodds, P., Sabel, C. F. and Watts, D. (forthcoming), Searching for Searchers: Organizational Robustness and Innovation in Highly Complex Solution Spaces.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G. and Puga, D. (1999), Diversity and Specialisation in Cities: Why, Where and When Does It Matter?, CEPR (Center for Economic and Policy Research) Discussion Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G. and Puga, D. (2001), Nursery Cities: Urban Diversity, Process Innovation, and theLife-cycle of Products, CEPR Discussion Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M. P. and Audretsch, D. B. (1999), “Innovation in Cities: Science-Based Diversity, Specialization and Localized Competition”, European Economic Review, 43, pp. 409–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M., Krugman, P., et al. (1999), “On the Evolution of Hierarchical Urban Systems”, European Economic Review, 43, pp. 209–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M. and Thisse, J. F. (2000), “The Formation of Economic Agglomerations: Old Problems and New Perspectives”, Economics of Cities, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galison, P. (1997), Image and Logic: A Material Culture of Microphysics, Chicago and London, University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, B., Kelley, M. et al. (1996), “Specialization Versus Diversity in Local Economies: The Implications for Innovative Private-Sector Behavior”, Cityscape 2, pp. 61–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helper, S., MacDuffie, J. P. and Sabel, C. (2000), “Pragmatic Collaborations: Advancing Knowledge while Controlling Opportunism”, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, pp. 443–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. and Krugman, P. (1985), Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the World Economy, Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huriot, J. M. and Thisse, J. F. (eds) (2000), Economics of Cities, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1973), “The Strength of Weak Ties”, American Journal of Sociology 78 (May), pp. 1360–1380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (2001), “A Theoretical Agenda for Economic Sociology”, forthcoming in: Economic Sociology at the Millenium, Guillen, M. F., Collins, R., England, P. and Meyer, M. (eds), New York, Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelley, M. and Helper, S. (1997), “Firm Size and Capabilities, Regional Agglomeration, and the Adoption of New Technology”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacDuffie, J. P. (1997), “The Road to Root Cause: Shop-Floor Problem-Solving at Three Auto Assembly Plants”, Management Science, 43, pp. 479–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacDuffie, J. P. and Helper, S. (1999), “Creating Lean Suppliers: Diffusing Lean Production Through the Supply Chain”, Remade in America: Transplanting and Transforming Japanese Production Systems, Liker, J., Adler, P. and Fruin, M. (eds), New York, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monteverde, K. and Teece, D. J. (1982), “Supplier Switching Costs and Vertical Integration in the Automobile Industry”, Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (1), pp. 206–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connell, L. G. (2001), Breaking the Bounds of Peripher ality: Irish Business in an Era of Multilevel Participative Internationalisation, Ph.D. thesis, University College Dublin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I. P. and Puga, D. (1997), Agglomeration in the Global Economy: A Survey of the “New Economic Geography”, CEP Discussion Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piore, M. J. and Sabel, C. F. (1984), The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity, New York, Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puga, D. (2001), European Regional Policies in Light of Recent Location Theories, CEPR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raymond, R. (n.d.), http://www.tuxedo.org/~esr/writings/.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C. F. (1994), “Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development”, Handbook of Economic Sociology, Smelser, N. and Swedberg, R. (eds), Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press, pp. 137–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C. F. and Zeitlin, J. (eds) (1997), Worlds of Possibility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1926), Theorie der Wirtschlaftlichen Entwicklung: Eine Untersuchung Über Unternehmergewinn, Kapital, Kredit, Zins und Den Konjunkturzyklus, München und Leipzig, Duncker und Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Signorini, L. F. (ed.) (2000), Lo Sviluppo Locale: Un’indagine della Banca d’Italia sui distretti industriali, Roma, Meridiana Libri.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. (1998), “Design Issues for Innovative Firms: Bureaucracy, Incentives and Industrial Structure”, The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, Organization and Regions, Oxford, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel, E. (1988), “Sticky Information and the Locus of Problem Solving: Implications for Innovation”, in: The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, Organization and Regions, Chandler, A. D. Jr., Hagstrom, P. and Solvell, O. (eds), Oxford, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weick, K. E. (1995), Sensemaking in Organizations, Thousand Oaks, Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitford, J. (2001), The Decline of a Model? Challenge and Response in the Italian Industrial Districts, Economy and Society, 30, issue 1, February 2001, pp. 38–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, S. G. (2000), “Organizing for Continuous Improvement: Evolutionary Theory Meets the Quality Revolution”, in: The Quality Movement & Organization Theory, Cole, R. E. and Scott, W. R. (eds), Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage Publications, pp. 49–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts, D. (1999), Small Worlds: The Dynamics of Networks between Order and Randomness, Princeton, Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2002 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg

About this paper

Cite this paper

Sabel, C.F. (2002). Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That Bind the (New) Industrial District. In: Curzio, A.Q., Fortis, M. (eds) Complexity and Industrial Clusters. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-50007-7_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-50007-7_7

  • Publisher Name: Physica-Verlag HD

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-7908-1471-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-50007-7

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics