Skip to main content

Overuse of Exclusivity in Patent Law

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Liability Rules in Patent Law

Part of the book series: Munich Studies on Innovation and Competition ((MSIC,volume 1))

  • 1069 Accesses

Abstract

Nowadays, the main purpose of a patent law system is predominantly, while balancing private and public interests, to govern economic decisions, to encourage innovation and, in general, to reach economic efficiency. On the one hand, the question is, therefore, whether the current German patent law system (including German and European antitrust laws), as it is currently applied, and the future system under the regulation on the European Patent with Unitary Effect, as it is designed, contain too many exclusive elements to be efficient. On the other hand, because the choice between the two options may not be purely economic, it must also be investigated whether other factors could be taken into account or—more importantly for an analysis that focuses on the economic effects of the patent system—make it necessary to use either exclusive or non-exclusive elements. Two additional perspectives may be relevant: distributional preferences and other justice considerations. Although these two categories and economic efficiency may not be strictly distinguished from each other, the additional perspectives should be understood here as limitations on economic efficiency. Also, due to the present focus on a concrete legal system, at least shortsighted legal reasons (i.e., higher-ranking law and multilateral contracts) may play a role.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1093.

  2. 2.

    Ibid., pp. 1089 et seq.

  3. 3.

    Bell and Parchomovsky (2002), p. 12 et seq.

  4. 4.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), pp. 1115 et seq.

  5. 5.

    Ibid., p. 1090.

  6. 6.

    Ibid.

  7. 7.

    Ibid.

  8. 8.

    Ibid.

  9. 9.

    Ibid., p. 1092.

  10. 10.

    Ibid.

  11. 11.

    Ibid., p. 1093.

  12. 12.

    Ibid., p. 1092.

  13. 13.

    Merges names, therefore, property rules as “absolute permission rules”: cf. Merges (1996), p. 1302, see also Epstein (1997), p. 2091; the terms property rule and exclusive right are used synonymously in the following.

  14. 14.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1092.

  15. 15.

    Ibid.

  16. 16.

    Merges describes the situation under a liability rules as “take now, pay later”: cf. Merges (1996), p. 1302.

  17. 17.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1092.

  18. 18.

    Kaplow and Shavell (1996), p. 756 et seq.; punitive damages are commonly identified as an implementation of a property rule: cf. Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1126; Kaplow and Shavell (1996), p. 724.

  19. 19.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1092.

  20. 20.

    They are relevant, e.g., if a person is incapable of contracting: cf. 104 German Civil Code; another example is that German copyrights shall not be transferable according to Section 29, Subsection 1, German Copyright Act, as a consequence to the monistic theory where proprietary rights and personal rights form a unity: cf. Schulze (2008), p. 1. This theory is not applicable in the field of patent law due to the lower importance of the personal rights component; a patent is negotiable, the personal rights of the inventor not: cf. Mes (2011), § 15, m.n. 3.

  21. 21.

    Cf., inter alia, Bell and Parchomovsky (2002), p. 21; Krier and Schwab (1995), p. 441. Based on a constellation in a nuisance dispute with two parties involved, rule one describes the situation in which the resident is the owner of the entitlement protected by a property rule; rule two in which it is enforced by a liability rule; rule three describes the situation in which the polluter is the owner of the entitlement protected by a property rule; and rule four is in which it is enforced by a liability rule. Cf. Krier and Schwab (1995), p. 444; of course, this categorization is of minor importance in the field of IP because only the inventor may be entitled.

  22. 22.

    Ayres (1998), p. 797; Bell and Parchomovsky (2002), p. 21.

  23. 23.

    Krier and Schwab (1995), p. 471.

  24. 24.

    Ayres (1998).

  25. 25.

    Morris (1993), p. 854 et seq.

  26. 26.

    Levmore (1997), p. 2173.

  27. 27.

    Bell and Parchomovsky (2002), p. 26.

  28. 28.

    Ibid., pp. 26 et seq.

  29. 29.

    Ibid., p. 27.

  30. 30.

    Levmore (1997), p. 2161.

  31. 31.

    Burk argues that they might be worth exploring in the context of IP: Burk (2009), p. 305.

  32. 32.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1093.

  33. 33.

    Calabresi explained this in an article which was published in the context of a 25 year retrospective on property rules, liability rules and inalienability: cf. Calabresi (1997), p. 2202.

  34. 34.

    Cf., inter alia, Kieff (2001), p. 697; Lemley and Weiser (2007), p. 783; Depoorter (2008); Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 408; Crane (2009), p. 253; Burk (2009).

  35. 35.

    Even Calabresi and Melamed indicated this: cf. Calabresi and Melamed (1972), pp. 1128 et seq.

  36. 36.

    Likewise, Lemley and Weiser (2007), p. 786.

  37. 37.

    One could, of course, think about subsidising inventions instead of granting patents. For a comparison between these two possibilities, see, inter alia, Schankerman (1998), p. 95 et seq.

  38. 38.

    A single patent (and therefore also a single entitlement in patent law) can be owned by one individual person or alternatively, by multiple persons, what may be described as a case of collective or joint ownership: Peukert (2010), p. 13.

  39. 39.

    JPO (2009), p. 7.

  40. 40.

    Cf. Rule 29(1), Implementing Regulations to Part I of the Convention.

  41. 41.

    Cf. Article 53(a) EPC.

  42. 42.

    JPO (2009), pp. 7 et seq.

  43. 43.

    United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, 23.07.1998, 149 F.3d 1368—State Street Bank & Trust v. Signature Financial Group.

  44. 44.

    Asendorf and Schmidt (2006), m.n. 4.

  45. 45.

    Wagner (2006), p. 22; see also Riederer (2007), p. 402.

  46. 46.

    About the optimal patent duration, see, inter alia, Scherer (1972); Nordhaus (1972); Gilbert and Shapiro (1990); Denicolò (1996); Christie and Rotstein (2008).

  47. 47.

    The patent term of the European Patent with Unitary Effect is 20 years, Art. 63(1) EPC.

  48. 48.

    JPO (2009), p. 17.

  49. 49.

    Bell and Parchomovsky (2002), p. 6.

  50. 50.

    Bishop (2004), p. 263.

  51. 51.

    JPO (2009), p. 14.

  52. 52.

    Klett et al. (2008), pp. 148 et seq.

  53. 53.

    As it was argued by Peukert who does, however, not follow the framework that is provided here: Peukert (2010), pp. 5 et seq.

  54. 54.

    Issues about the optimal patent breadth are, therefore, not part of the analysis, but see regarding this topic, inter alia, Gilbert and Shapiro (1990); Klemperer (1990); Denicolò (1996).

  55. 55.

    Cf. Section 903 German Civil Code: “The owner of a thing may, to the extent that a statute or third-party rights do not conflict with this, deal with the thing at his discretion and exclude others from every influence.” (Mussett (2013), Section 903).

  56. 56.

    JPO (2009), p. 12.

  57. 57.

    Mussett (2013), Section 1004.

  58. 58.

    Klett et al. (2008), p. 223.

  59. 59.

    Mes (2011), § 139, m.n. 47.

  60. 60.

    Ibid., § 139, m.n. 49 et seq.

  61. 61.

    Gruber (2013), m.n. 34.

  62. 62.

    Calabresi and Melamed: they see the role of criminal law not in the protection of individual rights but rather in the deterrence of “attempts to convert property rules in liability rules”, Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1126.

  63. 63.

    This section is applicable for EPO-Patens with effect for Germany [Article 2(2), EPC] and would also be applicable for European Patents with Unitary Effect: cf. Rogge and Grabinski (2006), m.n. 1.

  64. 64.

    The German Federal Supreme Court has never decided in a case about Section 142 German Patent Act: cf. ibid., m.n. 1.

  65. 65.

    Cf., e.g., Merges (1996), pp. 1293 et seq.; Kieff (2006), pp. 327 and 328 et seq.; Devlin (2009), p. 64 et seq.

  66. 66.

    Such a system will be discussed below under the heading, “Compulsory Patent Buyout” (Sect. B.4) in Chap. 4.

  67. 67.

    Merges (1996), p. 1340; Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 435.

  68. 68.

    Merges (1996), p. 1340; Merges (1999), p. 15.

  69. 69.

    Mechanisms inverse to the first group do not make sense because basically no one besides the owner would have incentives to transform a non-exclusive right to an exclusive one.

  70. 70.

    This will be explained in the following chapters.

  71. 71.

    Fuchs (2007), m.n. 1; de Bronett (2008), m.n. 47 et seq.; Klees (2012), m.n. 49 et seq.

  72. 72.

    Klett et al. (2008), p. 149.

  73. 73.

    Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), p. 840.

  74. 74.

    An unofficial English translation of the GWB is available here: Bundeskartellamt (2011), pp. 790–798.

  75. 75.

    Nägele and Jacobs (2009), p. 1063 et seq.; where these provisions apply is a question which will be addressed in Chap. 4.

  76. 76.

    Rogge (2006b), m.n. 33.

  77. 77.

    Scharen (2006), m.n. 16.

  78. 78.

    For instance, compulsory licensing had a big importance in Canada, certain in the US and also some in the UK; for an overview, see Liu (2008), p. 758 et seq.; regarding other variants of compulsory liability rule regimes further examples are provided below; see especially Sect. B in Chap. 4.

  79. 79.

    Buhrow and Nordemann (2005), p. 409.

  80. 80.

    The German Federal Patent Court was founded in 1961; between 1949 and 1961 the DPA was responsible for the evaluation of applications for compulsory licences.

  81. 81.

    BPatG, GRUR 1994, 98.

  82. 82.

    BGH, GRUR 1996, 190.

  83. 83.

    Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), p. 834.

  84. 84.

    Keukenschrijver (2013a), m.n. 3.

  85. 85.

    Nägele and Jacobs (2009), pp. 1068 et seq.

  86. 86.

    Cf., especially, ECJ, 29.04.2004, C-418/01—IMS Health v. NDC Health; European Commission, 24.03.2004, COMP/C-3/37.792—Microsoft; CFI, 17.09.2007, T-201/04—Microsoft v. European Commission.

  87. 87.

    Buhrow and Nordemann (2005), p. 409; Rogge (2006b), m.n. 4; Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 436.

  88. 88.

    Beier (1999), p. 260, Fn. 27.

  89. 89.

    Hilty made this argument while referring to compulsory licensing for dependent innovations [Article 31 (l) TRIPS]: Hilty (2009a), p. 181.

  90. 90.

    Beier (1999), p. 260; Böttger argues against this thesis by referring to the field of public health and particularly to the situation in developing countries: Böttger (2008), p. 881.

  91. 91.

    The patent buyout mechanism briefly explained below could be categorized as a compulsory liability rule mechanism: see Sect. B.4 in Chap. 4; the use of special liability rule regimes (rather referring to trade secrets) is also suggested by Rai et al. for accelerating drug discovery: Rai et al. (2009), pp. 247 et seqq.; both are not considered in this work due to several reasons and especially because they are not suited for a broad application.

  92. 92.

    Cf. Article 8 Regulation (EU) No. 1257/2012 where the same mechanism is called licence of right.

  93. 93.

    JPO (2009), pp. 20 et seq.

  94. 94.

    Section b.

  95. 95.

    If the patent is not yet granted, there is a liability rule regime. If the patent applicant declares the willingness to license at that stage and the DPMA grants the patent, only the way of liability rule protection changes.

  96. 96.

    Section A in Chap. 3.

  97. 97.

    van Overwalle et al. (2006), p. 144.

  98. 98.

    For an overview of the legal evaluation of cross-licensing agreements according to German law, cf. Wündisch and Bauer (2010), p. 641.

  99. 99.

    Meges calls them private liability rules: Merges (1996), p. 1340; cf. also Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 439.

  100. 100.

    Merges (1996), p. 1340.

  101. 101.

    Ibid, also with reference to Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163, 171 (1931).

  102. 102.

    Verbruggen and Lõrincz (2002), p. 827.

  103. 103.

    Merges (1999), p. 10.

  104. 104.

    Why this can usually not be qualified as a liability rule is explained below, Sect. iv “FRAND-Declaration?”.

  105. 105.

    Merges (1996), p. 1342.

  106. 106.

    Merges (1999), p. 13.

  107. 107.

    Ibid.

  108. 108.

    Ibid., p. 18.

  109. 109.

    Section B in Chap. 3.

  110. 110.

    van Overwalle et al. (2006), p. 145, with reference to Krattiger (2004).

  111. 111.

    There are other ways and variants of categorizing clearinghouses: cf., for instance, Aoki and Schiff (2008), p. 196.

  112. 112.

    van Overwalle et al. (2006), p. 146.

  113. 113.

    Ibid., p. 145, with reference to Krattiger (2004).

  114. 114.

    van Overwalle et al. (2006), p. 145, with reference to Graff and Zilberman (2001); Krattiger (2004).

  115. 115.

    van Overwalle et al. (2006), p. 145, with reference to Merges (1996).

  116. 116.

    van Zimmeren et al. (2006), p. 355.

  117. 117.

    Section C in Chap. 3.

  118. 118.

    Fröhlich (2008), p. 211 et seq.; Maaßen (2009), p. 279796.

  119. 119.

    LG Mannheim, 27.02.2009, 7 O 94/08, Beck Rechtsprechung 2009, 08150.

  120. 120.

    Fröhlich (2008), p. 216.

  121. 121.

    See also Article II, Section 1a, German International Patent Convention Code for patent applications filed with the EPO.

  122. 122.

    This work does not contain any details about the 18 month publication regime, for further information see, inter alia, Webman (1995); Kraßer (1990); Pahlow (2008).

  123. 123.

    JPO (2009), p. 30.

  124. 124.

    BGH, IIC 1990, 241; Neuhaus (1990), pp. 526 and 528; Krieger (2001), p. 966; Keukenschrijver (2013b), m.n. 3.

  125. 125.

    Keukenschrijver (2013b), m.n. 16.

  126. 126.

    The process took place according to (the then existing) Article 23 GG: cf. Zippelius (1991), p. 23.

  127. 127.

    For further information about this topic, see Brändel (1992).

  128. 128.

    Osterrieth (2010), 53; Wirtschaftspatente were, therefore, entitlements protected with a liability rule by default.

  129. 129.

    The possibility that a patent may be revoked is not taken into account.

  130. 130.

    Some variants for definitions are provided below.

  131. 131.

    Bishop (2004), p. 83.

  132. 132.

    Cf., similarly, Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 412.

  133. 133.

    Williamson (1987), p. 19.

  134. 134.

    Ibid., p. 20.

  135. 135.

    Ibid., p. 21.

  136. 136.

    Ibid., pp. 20 et seq.

  137. 137.

    Picot (1982), p. 270.

  138. 138.

    Bishop (2004), p. 198.

  139. 139.

    Ibid., pp. 94 et seq.

  140. 140.

    Bell and Parchomovsky (2002).

  141. 141.

    The analysis is not limited to the area of property and IP law or at least not narrowed to an assumption that property should be protected as an exclusive right because it should be considered a mistake taking into account and comparing only these two fields of law and especially setting tangible property equal with IP without taking the economic differences into account. This is evident when taking a law and economic approach, but cf., for instance, the debate between Epstein and Menell: Menell (2007) and Epstein (2008).

  142. 142.

    Likewise, Heinemann (2008), p. 954.

  143. 143.

    Bishop (2004), p. 196.

  144. 144.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1094, with reference to Coase (1960).

  145. 145.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1096, and, inter alia, Farber (1997), p. 404 et seq.; Fox (2007), p. 387 et seq.; Coase also commented on the criticism regarding unrealistic assumptions later on: Coase (1990), p. 174.

  146. 146.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1093.

  147. 147.

    Ibid., pp. 1125 et seq.

  148. 148.

    Ibid., p. 1110.

  149. 149.

    Arguments which have obviously no relevance at all for the area of IP law are not mentioned, as, for example, the problem of reciprocal takings which may occur with liability rules and only tangible goods: cf. Ayres and Balkin (1996), p. 706.

  150. 150.

    See, inter alia, Kornhauser (1986), p. 712; Coleman and Kraus (1986), p. 1364.

  151. 151.

    The term information/assessment costs, as it is used here, is different from the term transaction costs and can be grouped into the broader category of enforcement costs. Whereas the latter are the parties’ costs for making an economic exchange, the former are costs to determine the compensation at an efficient point. If the parties have to bear the costs for determining a compensation these are, however, again transaction costs. This example also shows that the different cost-categories cannot be strictly distinguished from each other.

  152. 152.

    Polinsky (1980), p. 1111; Krier and Schwab (1995), p. 447; Krauss (1999), pp. 788 et seq.

  153. 153.

    Polinsky (1980), pp. 1111 et seq.

  154. 154.

    Krauss (1999), p. 788.

  155. 155.

    Krier and Schwab (1995), pp. 459 et seq.

  156. 156.

    Krier and Schwab (1995), p. 454; Krauss (1999), p. 789.

  157. 157.

    This idea was already indicated by Calabresi and Melamed: cf. Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1093; however, it seems not being pursued later since they ask “why […] cannot society limit itself to the property rule? To do this it would need only to protect and enforce the initial entitlement from all attacks […].”, ibid., p. 1106.

  158. 158.

    Kaplow and Shavell (1996), pp. 741 et seq.

  159. 159.

    Article 19(4), German Basic Law contains such a guarantee: cf. Remmert (2013), m.n. 6; if there must be more than one instance is object of debate: cf., inter alia, Krugmann (2001), p. 306 et seq.

  160. 160.

    Cf. Section 303 German Criminal Code.

  161. 161.

    Cf. Section 242 German Criminal Code.

  162. 162.

    Kaplow and Shavell (1996), pp. 741 et seq.

  163. 163.

    Ayres and Talley (1995), p. 1037 et seq.

  164. 164.

    Ibid., p. 1033.

  165. 165.

    Ibid., p. 1038.

  166. 166.

    Ayres and Talley (1995), pp. 1032 et seq.; Ayres and Balkin (1996), pp. 706 et seq.

  167. 167.

    Ayres and Talley (1995), pp. 1043 et seq.

  168. 168.

    Kaplow and Shavell made this argument while focussing on situations where negative externalities arise: cf. Kaplow and Shavell (1996), pp. 723 et seq.; this should not be correct in the field of tangible goods because of possible repeated, reciprocal takings and correlated values: cf. ibid., pp. 767 et seq.

  169. 169.

    One should add: … and assessment/enforcement costs are low.

  170. 170.

    Kaplow and Shavell (1995), p. 233; Kaplow and Shavell (1996), pp. 723 et seq.

  171. 171.

    The traditional analysis is based on the standard, but probably wrong assumption, that the value of entitlement does not depend on ownership: Hoffman and Spitzer (1993), p. 98 et seq.; Korobkin (2003), p. 1283.

  172. 172.

    Kahneman et al. (1990), p. 1325; Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 250.

  173. 173.

    Hoffman and Spitzer (1993), p. 65.

  174. 174.

    Rachlinski and Jourden (1998), p. 1553 et seq.; Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 251.

  175. 175.

    Ayres and Talley (1995), pp. 1101 et seq.

  176. 176.

    Rachlinski and Jourdan find evidence for this argument in their behavioural study: cf. Rachlinski and Jourden (1998), p. 1572.

  177. 177.

    Ibid., p. 1574.

  178. 178.

    Epstein (1997), p. 2092.

  179. 179.

    Swope and Schmitt claim to have found empirical evidence for this behaviour in their experiment: Swope and Schmitt (2008), p. 13.

  180. 180.

    Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 247.

  181. 181.

    Haddock et al. (1990), p. 50.

  182. 182.

    Kaplow and Shavell (1995), pp. 228 et seq.

  183. 183.

    Kaplow and Shavell (1995), p. 232; Kaplow and Shavell (1996), pp. 35 et seq.

  184. 184.

    Haddock et al. (1990), p. 16; Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 249.

  185. 185.

    Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 249.

  186. 186.

    Haddock et al. (1990), p. 50.

  187. 187.

    Section B.2.a.

  188. 188.

    Section C.1.a.

  189. 189.

    Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 253.

  190. 190.

    Ibid., pp. 253 et seq.

  191. 191.

    This should especially be the case where no adequate substitutes exist (this argument is, of course, only applicable for tangible goods): cf. ibid.

  192. 192.

    Korobkin (2003), p. 1285.

  193. 193.

    Ibid., p. 1286.

  194. 194.

    Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 222.

  195. 195.

    See, inter alia, Bearden (2001).

  196. 196.

    Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 230.

  197. 197.

    Ibid., p. 232.

  198. 198.

    Kahneman and Tversky (1979), p. 263.

  199. 199.

    Lewinsohn-Zamir (2001), p. 238.

  200. 200.

    Stiglitz and Walsh (2010), p. 550.

  201. 201.

    This can already be seen with the design and application of patent laws, more specifically see, for instance, Machlup (1958), pp. 20 et seq.

  202. 202.

    Lemley (2005), p. 1031.

  203. 203.

    Lehmann (1989), p. 11 et seq.

  204. 204.

    Section 2.c.(2)(b).

  205. 205.

    Tandon (1982), p. 485.

  206. 206.

    Cohen et al. (2000), p. 20.

  207. 207.

    EPO (2007b), p. 95.

  208. 208.

    See Sect. 1.

  209. 209.

    Lemley and Weiser (2007), p. 832, with reference to Epstein (1997), pp. 16 et seq.

  210. 210.

    Elhauge (2008), p. 567; Depoorter (2008), pp. 62 et seq., with reference to Epstein (1997), pp. 16 et seq.

  211. 211.

    Kieff (2001), p. 732.

  212. 212.

    Ibid., pp. 733 and 727 et seq.

  213. 213.

    Ibid., p. 733, with reference to Haddock et al. (1990), pp. 16 et seq.

  214. 214.

    Sect. 2.c.(2)(d).

  215. 215.

    Kieff (2001), p. 732.

  216. 216.

    Kieff (2006), p. 328.

  217. 217.

    Ayres and Klemperer (1999), p. 1027 et seq.

  218. 218.

    Kieff (2001), pp. 734 et seq.

  219. 219.

    Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 417, with reference to Lemley (2005); Crane (2009), p. 271, with reference to Smith (2004), p. 1729.

  220. 220.

    Gilbert and Shapiro (1996), p. 12753.

  221. 221.

    Cugno and Ottoz (2006), p. 17.

  222. 222.

    Section 1.

  223. 223.

    Section 2.c.(2).

  224. 224.

    Merges (1994b), p. 2655; Merges (1996), pp. 1303 et seq.; Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 414.

  225. 225.

    Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 408.

  226. 226.

    Castro Bernieri (2010), p. 258.

  227. 227.

    Merges (1996), p. 1307.

  228. 228.

    von Bassewitz et al. (2004b), pp. 607 and 608.

  229. 229.

    von Bassewitz et al. (2004a), pp. 609 and 610.

  230. 230.

    Section 1.

  231. 231.

    Bessen and Meurer (2008), p. 46.

  232. 232.

    Depoorter (2008), p. 70.

  233. 233.

    Hilty (1990), p. 1.

  234. 234.

    Depoorter (2008), p. 70.

  235. 235.

    Lemley and Weiser (2007), pp. 793 et seq.

  236. 236.

    Ibid., p. 794.

  237. 237.

    Ibid., pp. 794 et seq.

  238. 238.

    Ibid., p. 785.

  239. 239.

    Depoorter (2008), p. 66.

  240. 240.

    Sterk (2008), p. 1285.

  241. 241.

    Castro Bernieri (2010), pp. 241 et seq. and 258.

  242. 242.

    Devlin (2009), pp. 75 and 82 et seq.

  243. 243.

    Gwartney (2009), p. 1406.

  244. 244.

    Lemley and Shapiro (2005), p. 75; Farrell and Shapiro (2008), p. 1347.

  245. 245.

    Heald (2007), p. 460.

  246. 246.

    Ibid.

  247. 247.

    Section 2.c.(1)(d).

  248. 248.

    Section 2.c.(2)(d).

  249. 249.

    Weeds (1999), p. 19.

  250. 250.

    Tandon (1982), p. 484.

  251. 251.

    The definition originates from van Overwalle: van Overwalle (2009), p. 390.

  252. 252.

    Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 414.

  253. 253.

    Frischmann and Lemley (2007), p. 292.

  254. 254.

    Depoorter (2008), p. 66.

  255. 255.

    Liu (2008), p. 757.

  256. 256.

    For an overview with further references, see Fischmann (2010), pp. 185 et seq.

  257. 257.

    Fröhlich (2008), p. 209; Fischmann (2010), p. 186.

  258. 258.

    Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 415.

  259. 259.

    Lemley and Weiser (2007), p. 795.

  260. 260.

    There may not be an infringement, but due to the uncertainty of the boundaries of a patent, the patentee may be successful in asking for licensing fees.

  261. 261.

    Shapiro (2006), p. 27.

  262. 262.

    Klees (2012), p. 90.

  263. 263.

    Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 415.

  264. 264.

    Lemley and Weiser (2007), p. 795.

  265. 265.

    For whatever reason.

  266. 266.

    See, inter alia, Depoorter (2008), pp. 78 et seq.; Schovsbo (2009), pp. 612 et seq.

  267. 267.

    Heller (1998), p. 621.

  268. 268.

    Heller (1998), p. 622; see especially also Hardin (1968), p. 1243.

  269. 269.

    Heller (1998), p. 622; Depoorter (2008), pp. 71 et seq.

  270. 270.

    Heller and Eisenberg (1998), pp. 625 et seq.

  271. 271.

    Buchanan and Yoon (2000), p. 3 et seq.

  272. 272.

    Schulz et al. (2002), p. 158.

  273. 273.

    Shapiro (2001), p. 119.

  274. 274.

    Like it was argued by van Overwalle (2009), p. 387.

  275. 275.

    Schovsbo (2009), pp. 611 et seq.

  276. 276.

    Depoorter (2008), p. 66.

  277. 277.

    Shapiro (2001), p. 119.

  278. 278.

    Schovsbo (2009), p. 612.

  279. 279.

    Lemley and Shapiro (2007), p. 1993.

  280. 280.

    Sections 2.c.(1)(c) and (2)(c).

  281. 281.

    Buccafusco and Sprigman (2010b), p. 39.

  282. 282.

    Depoorter (2008), p. 68.

  283. 283.

    Buccafusco and Sprigman (2010a), p. 34; Buccafusco and Sprigman (2010b), p. 39.

  284. 284.

    Buccafusco and Sprigman (2010a), p. 22.

  285. 285.

    Buccafusco and Sprigman (2010a), pp. 23 et seq.; Buccafusco and Sprigman (2010b), pp. 33 et seq.

  286. 286.

    Merges (1994a), p. 75.

  287. 287.

    Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 417.

  288. 288.

    One should agree with that statement which originates from Kur and Schovsbo (2011), p. 418.

  289. 289.

    McAfee (2002), p. 273.

  290. 290.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), pp. 1098 et seq.

  291. 291.

    Ibid., p. 1104.

  292. 292.

    Ibid., p. 1098.

  293. 293.

    Andel (1984), p. 648.

  294. 294.

    Calabresi and Melamed (1972), pp. 1102 et seq.

  295. 295.

    Polinsky (1980), p. 1111; cf. also Sect. 2.c.(1).

  296. 296.

    Ibid.

  297. 297.

    Section 2.c.(2).

  298. 298.

    Polinsky (1980), p. 1111.

  299. 299.

    Machlup (1958), pp. 20 et seq.

  300. 300.

    For all theories see ibid., p. 20.

  301. 301.

    For all theories see ibid.

  302. 302.

    Osterrieth (2010), p. 5; Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), p. 37.

  303. 303.

    Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), p. 37.

  304. 304.

    Arguments against the patent protection per se will not be mentioned; see Machlup (1958), pp. 22 et seq.

  305. 305.

    Machlup (1958), p. 22; Götting (2006), pp. 353 et seq.

  306. 306.

    Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), pp. 37 et seq.

  307. 307.

    Ibid., p. 39; see also (regarding the situation in socialist states) Beier (1970), p. 3.

  308. 308.

    Mes (2011), § 24, m.n. 14.

  309. 309.

    von Bassewitz et al. (2004b), p. 608.

  310. 310.

    One may also argue that the idealistic reasons for a patent law system become less and less important: cf. Ann (2004), p. 603.

  311. 311.

    BGBl. II 1970, 391; BGBl. II 1984, 799.

  312. 312.

    Articles 20 and 21, Directive 2004/48/EC.

  313. 313.

    Bodenhausen (1968), p. 71.

  314. 314.

    van Zimmeren and van Overwalle (2011), p. 18.

  315. 315.

    Bodenhausen (1968), p. 70.

  316. 316.

    Footnote 6 in the official text.

  317. 317.

    Gervais (1998), pp. 293 and 297; Subramanian (2008), p. 446.

  318. 318.

    Subramanian (2008), p. 446.

  319. 319.

    World Trade Organisation Ministerial Conference Fourth Season (2001), p. 4.

  320. 320.

    Stern-Dombal (2007), p. 272 et seq.

  321. 321.

    van Zimmeren and van Overwalle (2011), p. 19.

  322. 322.

    Subramanian (2008), p. 447.

  323. 323.

    von Mühlendahl (2007), p. 377.

  324. 324.

    Osterrieth (2009), p. 545.

  325. 325.

    von Mühlendahl (2007), p. 380.

  326. 326.

    Article 5(3), EU and Protocol (No. 2) on the Application of the Principles of Subsidiarity and Proportionality.

  327. 327.

    Tomuschat and Currie (2010), p. 22.

  328. 328.

    Cf., inter alia, Schulte (1985), p. 772; Grzeszick (2007), p. 345 et seq.; Papier (2013), m.n. 198.

  329. 329.

    The situation where a liability rule by default applies directly after the patent grant is considered being equal with a situation where it applies at a later point in time.

  330. 330.

    Fechner (1999), p. 238.

  331. 331.

    Kraßer (1998), p. 519.

  332. 332.

    Bußmann (1977), p. 133; Timmann (2008), pp. 187 et seq.

  333. 333.

    Timmann (2008), pp. 191 et seq.

  334. 334.

    Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), p. 42.

  335. 335.

    For an overview of the different arguments in favour and against this view, see Timmann (2008), pp. 182 et seq.

  336. 336.

    Timmann (2008), p. 183.

  337. 337.

    Timmann (2008), p. 179; Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), pp. 26 et seq. and 41.

  338. 338.

    BVerfG NJW 1998, 3704.

  339. 339.

    Section B.2.c.

  340. 340.

    Papier (2013), m.n. 306.

  341. 341.

    Fechner (1999), p. 251.

  342. 342.

    Timmann (2008), p. 233; Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), p. 833.

  343. 343.

    Rogge (2006b), m.n. 16; Timmann (2008), p. 236.

  344. 344.

    Hilty makes a similar argument while referring to the use of legal licences in the area of copyright law: Hilty (2005), p. 341.

  345. 345.

    Keukenschrijver (2013a), m.n. 5.

  346. 346.

    Acts concerning the past are basically not permitted: Grzeszick (2013), m.n. 27; relatively unproblematic would be if the patent was not filed yet.

  347. 347.

    Ibid., m.n. 88 and 92.

  348. 348.

    Meyer-Ladewig (2006), Prot. No. 1, Art. 1 m.n. 2.

  349. 349.

    Ibid., Prot. No. 1, Art. 1 m.n. 11.

  350. 350.

    Bernsdorff (2011), m.n. 1.

  351. 351.

    Jarass (2006), p. 1091; Depenheuer (2006), m.n. 30.

  352. 352.

    Bernsdorff (2011), m.n. 15.

  353. 353.

    Depenheuer (2006), m.n. 29.

  354. 354.

    Ibid., m.n. 21.

  355. 355.

    ECJ, 14.07.1981, C-187/80—Merck v. Stephar; ECJ, 09.07.1985, C-19/84—Pharmon v. Hoechst.

  356. 356.

    Depenheuer refers to the above-cited decisions and mentions several times the term “exclusivity” while explaining Article 17, Section 2, EU-Charter, Depenheuer (2006), m.n. 30.

  357. 357.

    Geiger makes this argument while using the example of copyright law; see Geiger (2006), p. 382 et seq.

  358. 358.

    Section B.4.b.(1).

  359. 359.

    World Intellectual Property Organization (2010), p. 1.

  360. 360.

    Allison and Lemley (2000), p. 2121.

  361. 361.

    Section B.4.b.(2).

  362. 362.

    Section 81, Subsection 2, PatG.

  363. 363.

    See also Harhoff (2009).

  364. 364.

    Harhoff and Reitzig (2004), p. 445.

  365. 365.

    The number of patent applications almost doubled from 1992 to 2005; also the number of patent grants rose significantly: cf. World Intellectual Property Organization (2010), pp. 37 and 40.

  366. 366.

    EPO (2010a), pp. 18 et seq.

  367. 367.

    EPO (2009), pp. 22 et seq.

  368. 368.

    DPMA (2013), p. 96.

  369. 369.

    For an overview see Harhoff (2009), pp. 27 et seq.

  370. 370.

    See generally inter alia, Graf (2007); Wissenschaftlicher Beirat beim Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Technologie (2007), pp. 20 et seq.; Hilty (2009b), pp. 98 et seqq.

  371. 371.

    DPMA (2004).

  372. 372.

    EPO (2010b).

  373. 373.

    According to Kraßer, the EPO has a grant rate of around 74 % and the DPMA of almost 50 %: Kraßer and Bernhardt (2009), pp. 112 and 114. One must note, however, that figures vary in different publications—presumably due to different calculation methods. Moreover, one should be aware that the different grant rates may have several reasons, for instance one could expect that more important inventions are filed rather with the EPO than the DPMA.

  374. 374.

    DPMA (2004), p. 8.

  375. 375.

    Kinkeldey and Karamanli (2012), m.n. 16 et seq.; EPO (2010b), p. 353.

  376. 376.

    Mes (2011), § 4, m.n. 19 et seq.

  377. 377.

    Jestaedt (2001), p. 942.

  378. 378.

    For a summary of the criteria and indications named by the BGH, see Mes (2011), § 4, m.n. 33 et seqq.; Asendorf and Schmidt (2006), m.n. 50 et seq.

  379. 379.

    The Board 28 (2007), p. 7.

  380. 380.

    Astomio (2007), p. 251.

  381. 381.

    Harhoff and Wagner (2006), p. 23.

  382. 382.

    van Overwalle and Schovsbo (2007), p. 836.

  383. 383.

    Ernst & Young (2007), p. 10.

  384. 384.

    Sag and Rohde (2006), p. 16.

  385. 385.

    EPO (2007a).

  386. 386.

    One must note however that the EPO is viewed currently according to a survey among patent attorneys as having the best patent quality compared with the JPO, USPTO, the Korean and the Chinese patent office: Wild (2011), p. 72 et seq.

  387. 387.

    The counts relate to pendency until dispatch of the decisions: EPO et al. (2011), p. 57.

  388. 388.

    Gans et al. (2006), pp. 23 et seq.

  389. 389.

    Harhoff (2006), p. 24; more current figures were not published.

  390. 390.

    Ibid.

  391. 391.

    BPatG (2013), p. 140.

  392. 392.

    BGH (2012), p. 32; BGH (2013), p. 32.

  393. 393.

    Graham et al. (2003), p. 75; for the biotechnological and the pharmaceutical industry, see Harhoff and Reitzig (2004), p. 478.

  394. 394.

    EPO (2010c), Fee Code 010.

  395. 395.

    Appendix to Section 2, Subsection 1, PatKostG, Fee No. 313 600.

  396. 396.

    Harhoff and Reitzig mention that estimates from patent attorneys range between €15,000 and €25,000 for each party: Harhoff and Reitzig (2004), p. 450; according to van Pottelsberghe the costs including patent attorneys’ fees vary between €6,000 and €50,000: van Pottelsberghe (2009), p. 13.

  397. 397.

    BGH, GRUR 2009, 1100; in exceptional cases the value of the matter in dispute may be reduced (Section 144 PatG).

  398. 398.

    Rough estimates mention a range from €50,000 to €500,000: Harhoff and Reitzig (2004), p. 451; van Pottelsberghe mentions €50,000–250,000 for the first instance and €90,000–190,000 for the second instance: van Pottelsberghe (2009), p. 14.

  399. 399.

    Such behaviour is, of course, highly undesirable with regard to the general interest and the aim having certainty about the validity.

  400. 400.

    Mes (2011), § 81, m.n. 79 and 86.

  401. 401.

    Rogge (2006a), m.n. 39 et seq.; Halfmeier (2006), pp. 60 et seq.

  402. 402.

    Section B.4.b.(4).

  403. 403.

    Footnote 365.

  404. 404.

    von Graevenitz et al. (2008), p. 30, with reference to Kortum and Lerner (1998); Hall and Ziedonis (2001); Ziedonis (2004).

  405. 405.

    von Graevenitz et al. (2008), p. 30.

  406. 406.

    Cockburn et al. (2010), p. 920.

  407. 407.

    Siebert and von Graevenitz (2010), p. 240 et seq.

  408. 408.

    Cf., inter alia (the first two refer to the US system), Kortum and Lerner (1999); Hall (2004); Harhoff et al. (2007), pp. 65 et seq.

  409. 409.

    von Graevenitz et al. (2009).

  410. 410.

    von Graevenitz et al. (2008), p. 30, with reference to National Research Council of the National Academies (2007), pp. 1 et seq.

  411. 411.

    Heller and Eisenberg (1998); Goldstein (2009), p. 52.

  412. 412.

    Verbeure et al. (2006).

  413. 413.

    Schovsbo (2009), p. 612.

  414. 414.

    Section B.4.b.(3).

  415. 415.

    Siebert and von Graevenitz (2008), pp. 35 et seq.

  416. 416.

    Giuri et al. (2007), pp. 1107 et seq.

  417. 417.

    Ibid., p. 1118.

  418. 418.

    Chien (2003).

  419. 419.

    Some also use the term patent thicket; this does, however, not fit here because a situation is described where only one patent owner—and not several—files numerous applications.

  420. 420.

    This number consists of patent applications and granted patents in several EU member states; European Commission (2009), p. 521.

  421. 421.

    Ibid., pp. 520 et seq.

  422. 422.

    Many attempts for a definition were made: cf. Rubin (2007), p. 60.

  423. 423.

    Lemley (2008), p. 612.

  424. 424.

    Williams and Gardner (2006), p. 1.

  425. 425.

    Cf., inter alia, Luman and Dodson (2006), p. 12; Golden (2007), p. 2111 et seq.; Ohly (2008), p. 787.

  426. 426.

    Merges (2009), p. 1588.

  427. 427.

    Lemley and Shapiro (2007), p. 2009.

  428. 428.

    Niro and Greenspoon (2007), p. 14.

  429. 429.

    Repeatedly mentioned are especially the lawsuit between NPT and Research in Motion and United States Supreme Court, 15.05.2006, 547 U.S. 388—eBay v. MercExchange.

  430. 430.

    Schickedanz (2009), p. 901.

  431. 431.

    LG Mannheim, 27.02.2009, 7 O 94/08; LG Mannheim, GRUR Prax 2010, 318.

  432. 432.

    Ihlenfeld (2008).

  433. 433.

    http://www.ipcom-munich.com/home_en.html.

  434. 434.

    IPCom GmbH & Co. KG (2009).

  435. 435.

    Ihlenfeld (2008).

  436. 436.

    LG Mannheim, GRUR Prax 2010, 318.

  437. 437.

    Juve.de (2011).

  438. 438.

    LG Mannheim, 27.02.2009, 7 O 94/08.

  439. 439.

    German Upper Regional Court (Oberlandesgericht) Karlsruhe, GRUR-RR 2010, 120 et seq.

  440. 440.

    Osterrieth (2009), p. 543.

  441. 441.

    Schickedanz (2009), pp. 902 et seq.

  442. 442.

    See, especially, Fischmann (2010).

  443. 443.

    US Federal Trade Commission, 17.06.1996, C-3658, File No. 931 0097—Dell.

  444. 444.

    The case material can be found here: http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9305/index.shtm.

  445. 445.

    The case material can be found here: http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9302/index.shtm.

References

  • Allison JR, Lemley MA (2000) Who’s patenting what? An empirical exploration of patent prosecution. Vand Law Rev 53:2099–2174

    Google Scholar 

  • Andel N (1984) Zum Konzept der meritorischen Güter. Finanzarchiv 42:630–648

    Google Scholar 

  • Ann C (2004) Die idealistische Wurzel des Schutzes geistiger Leistungen. GRUR Int 2004:597–603

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki R, Schiff A (2008) Promoting access to intellectual property – patent pools, copyright collectives, and clearinghouses. R&D Manage 38:189–204

    Google Scholar 

  • Asendorf CD, Schmidt C (2006) § 4 PatG. In: Benkard G, Asendorf CD (eds) Patentgesetz, Gebrauchsmustergesetz. Beck’sche Kurz-Kommentare, 10th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Astomio M (2007) Obviously troublesome – how high should the standard be for obtaining a patent. J Pat Trademark Off Soc 89:239–252

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres I (1998) Protecting property with puts. Valparaiso Univ Law Rev 32:793–829

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres I, Balkin JM (1996) Legal entitlements as auctions – property rules, liability rules, and beyond. Yale Law J 106:703–750

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres I, Klemperer P (1999) Limiting patentees’ market power without reducing innovation incentives – the perverse benefits of uncertainty and non-injunctive remedies. Mich Law Rev 97:985–1033

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres I, Talley E (1995) Solomonic bargaining – dividing a legal entitlement to facilitate Coasean trade. Yale Law J 104:1027–1117

    Google Scholar 

  • Bearden NJ (2001) Ultimatum bargaining experiments – the state of the art. http://ssrn.com/abstract=626183

  • Beier F-K (1970) Die herkömmlichen Patentrechtstheorien und die sozialistische Konzeption des Erfinderrechts. GRUR 1970:1–6

    Google Scholar 

  • Beier F-K (1999) Exclusive rights, statutory licenses and compulsory licenses in patent and utility model law. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 30:251–274

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell A, Parchomovsky G (2002) Pliability rules. Mich Law Rev 101:1–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernsdorff N (2011) Art. 17. In: Meyer J (ed) Charta der Grundrechte der Europäischen Union, 3rd edn. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessen J, Meurer MJ (2008) Patent failure – how judges, bureaucrats, and lawyers put innovators at risk, 1st edn. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • BGH (2012) Übersicht über den Geschäftsgang bei den Zivilsenaten des Bundesgerichtshofs im Jahr 2011, Karlsruhe. http://www.bundesgerichtshof.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/DerBGH/StatistikZivil/jahresstatistikZivilsenate2011.pdf

  • BGH (2013) Übersicht über den Geschäftsgang bei den Zivilsenaten des Bundesgerichtshofs im Jahr 2012, Karlsruhe. http://www.bundesgerichtshof.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/DerBGH/StatistikZivil/jahresstatistikZivilsenate2012.pdf

  • Bishop M (2004) Essential economics, 1st edn. Bloomberg Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Bodenhausen GHC (1968) Guide to the application of the Paris convention for the protection of industrial property, 1st edn. Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Böttger F (2008) Zwangslizenzen im Patentrecht – Eine systematische Betrachtung der neueren Praxis insbesondere im Bereich der öffentlichen Gesundheit. GRUR Int 2008:881–891

    Google Scholar 

  • BPatG (2013) Jahresbericht 2012, Munich. http://www.bpatg.de/cms/media/Oeffentlichkeitsarbeit/Veroeffentlichungen/Jahresberichte/jahresbericht_2012.pdf

  • Brändel OC (1992) Rechtsfragen des ‘Erstreckungsgesetzes’ zum Schutzbereich und zur Benutzungslage von Patenten im vereinigten Deutschland. GRUR 1992:653–659

    Google Scholar 

  • Buccafusco C, Sprigman C (2010a) The creativity effect. http://works.bepress.com/christopher_buccafusco1/9

  • Buccafusco C, Sprigman C (2010b) Valuing intellectual property – an experiment. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1568962

  • Buchanan JM, Yoon YJ (2000) Symmetric tragedies – commons and anticommons. J Law Econ 43:1–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Buhrow A, Nordemann B (2005) Grenzen ausschließlicher Rechte geistigen Eigentums durch Kartellrecht (Q 187). GRUR Int 2005:407–419

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundeskartellamt (2011), Act against restraints of competition. http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/englisch_gwb/index.html

  • Burk DL (2009) Critical analysis – property rules, liability rules and molecular futures, bargaining in the shadow of the cathedral. In: van Overwalle G (ed) Gene patents and collaborative licensing models – patent pools, clearinghouses, open source models and liability regimes. Cambridge Intellectual Property and Information Law, 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 294–307

    Google Scholar 

  • Bußmann J (1977) Patentrecht und Marktwirtschaft. GRUR 1977:121–135

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi G (1997) Remarks – the simple virtues of the cathedral. Yale Law J 106:2201–2207

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi G, Melamed AD (1972) Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability – one view of the cathedral. Harv Law Rev 85:1089–1128

    Google Scholar 

  • Castro Bernieri R (2010) Ex-post liability rules in modern patent law. European studies in law and economics, 1st edn. Intersentia, Antwerpen

    Google Scholar 

  • Chien C (2003) Cheap drugs at what price to innovation – does the compulsory licensing of pharmaceuticals hurt innovation? Berkeley Technol Law J 18:853–907

    Google Scholar 

  • Christie AF, Rotstein F (2008) Duration of patent protection – does one size fit all? J Intellect Prop Law Pract 3:402–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1990) The firm, the market and the law, 1st edn. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Cockburn IM, MacGarvie MJ, Müller E (2010) Patent thickets, licensing and innovative performance. Ind Corp Change 19:899–925

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Nelson RR, Walsh JP (2000) Protecting their intellectual assets – appropriability conditions and why U.S. manufacturing firms patent (or not). http://www.nber.org/papers/w7552.pdf

  • Coleman JL, Kraus J (1986) Rethinking the theory of legal rights. Yale Law J 95:1335–1371

    Google Scholar 

  • Crane DA (2009) Intellectual liability. Tex Law Rev 88:253–300

    Google Scholar 

  • Cugno F, Ottoz E (2006) Static inefficiency of compulsory licensing – quantity vs. price competition. http://polis.unipmn.it/pubbl/RePEc/uca/ucapdv/cugnoottoz80.pdf

  • de Bronett G-K (2008) § 22 Das Verbot des Missbrauchs marktbeherrschender Stellungen im EG-Kartellrecht. In: Wiedemann G (ed) Handbuch des Kartellrechts, 2nd edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Denicolò V (1996) Patent races and optimal patent breadth and length. RAND J Econ 44:249–265

    Google Scholar 

  • Depenheuer O (2006) Art. 17. In: Tettinger PJ, Stern K (eds) Kölner Gemeinschaftskommentar zur Europäischen Grundrechte-Charta. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Depoorter B (2008) Property rules, liability rules and patent market failure. http://www.erasmuslawreview.nl/files/ELR_specialissue_04.pdf

  • Devlin A (2009) Indeterminism and the property-patent equation. Yale Law Policy Rev 28:61–106

    Google Scholar 

  • DPMA (2004) Guidelines for the examination procedure, Munich. http://www.dpma.de/docs/service/formulare_eng/patent_eng/p2796_1.pdf

  • DPMA (2013) Annual report 2012, Munich. http://dpma.de/docs/service/veroeffentlichungen/jahresberichte_en/dpma-annualreport2012.pdf

  • Elhauge E (2008) Do patent holdup and royalty stacking lead to systematically excessive royalties? J Competition Law Econ 4:535–570

    Google Scholar 

  • EPO (2007a) PAX – implementation handbook – version 1.1, 2, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • EPO (2007b) Scenarios for the future – how might IP regimes evolve by 2025? What global legitimacy might such regimes have? Munich. http://www.epo.org/news-issues/issues/scenarios/download.html

  • EPO (2009) Annual report 2008, Munich. http://www.epo.org/about-us/annual-reports-statistics/annual-report/2008.html

  • EPO (2010a) Annual report 2009, Munich. http://www.epo.org/about-us/annual-reports-statistics/annual-report/2009.html

  • EPO (2010b) Guidelines for examination in the European Patent Office, Munich. http://www.epo.org/law-practice/legal-texts/guidelines.html

  • EPO (2010c) Schedule of fees and expenses of the EPO, (applicable as from 1 April 2010), Fee Code 010

    Google Scholar 

  • EPO, JPO, Korean Intellectual Property Office, and USPTO (2011) Four office statistics report – 2010 edition. http://www.trilateral.net/statistics/tsr/fosr2010/fullreport.pdf

  • Epstein RA (1997) A clear view of the cathedral – the dominance of property rules. Yale Law J 106:2091–2212

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein RA (2008) The property rights movement and intellectual property. http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1085411

  • Ernst & Young (2007) Benchmarking project – productivity of the EPO, UKIPO & DPMA – final report. http://www.ipo.gov.uk/benchmarkingproject.pdf

  • European Commission (2009) Pharmaceutical sector inquiry – final report, Brussels. http://ec.europa.eu/competition/sectors/pharmaceuticals/inquiry/staff_working_paper_part1.pdf

  • Farber DA (1997) Parody lost/pragmatism regained – the ironic history of the Coase theorem. Va Law Rev 83:397–428

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell J, Shapiro C (2008) How strong are weak patents? Am Econ Rev 98:1347–1369

    Google Scholar 

  • Fechner F (1999) Geistiges Eigentum und Verfassung – Schöpferische Leistungen unter dem Schutz des Grundgesetzes, 1st edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischmann F (2010) Die Pflicht zur Lizenzerteilung in Patent-Ambush-Fällen nach deutschem und europäischem Kartellrecht. GRUR Int 2010:185–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox G (2007) The real Coase theorems. Cato Inst J 27:373–396

    Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann BM, Lemley MA (2007) Spillovers. Columbia Law Rev 107:257–301

    Google Scholar 

  • Fröhlich M (2008) Standards und Patente – Die ETSI IPR policy. GRUR 2008:205–218

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuchs A (2007) III. G. Verordnung (EG) Nr. 772/2004 der Kommission vom 27. April 2004 über die Anwendung von Artikel 81 Absatz 3 EG-Vertrag auf Gruppen von Technologietransfer-Vereinbarungen. In: Immenga U, Mestmäcker E-J (eds) Wettbewerbsrecht, 4th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Gans JS, Hsu DH, Stern S (2006) The impact of uncertain intellectual property rights on the market for ideas – evidence from patent grant delays. http://ssrn.com/abstract=895601

  • Geiger C (2006) ‘Constitutionalizing’ intellectual property law? The influence of fundamental rights on intellectual property in the European Union. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 37:371–406

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervais D (1998) The TRIPS agreement – drafting history and analysis, 1st edn. Sweet & Maxwell, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert RJ, Shapiro C (1990) Optimal patent length and breadth. RAND J Econ 21:106–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert RJ, Shapiro C (1996) An economic analysis of unilateral refusals to license intellectual property. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 93:12749–12755

    Google Scholar 

  • Giuri P et al (2007) Inventors and invention processes in Europe – results from the PatVal-EU survey. Res Policy 36:1107–1127

    Google Scholar 

  • Golden JM (2007) ‘Patent Trolls’ and patent remedies. Tex Law Rev 85:2111–2161

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein JA (2009) Critical analysis of patent pools. In: van Overwalle G (ed) Gene patents and collaborative licensing models – patent pools, clearinghouses, open source models and liability regimes. Cambridge intellectual property and information law, 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 50–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Götting H-P (2006) Der Begriff des Geistigen Eigentums. GRUR 2006:353–358

    Google Scholar 

  • Graf SW (2007) Improving patent quality through identification of relevant prior art – approaches to increase information flow to the patent office. Lewis Clark Law Rev 11:495–519

    Google Scholar 

  • Graff G, Zilberman D (2001) Towards an intellectual property clearinghouse for ag-biotechnology. IP Technol Today 3:1–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham SJH, Hall BH, Harhoff D, Mowery DC (2003) Patent quality control – a comparison of U.S. patent re-examinations and European patent oppositions. In: Cohen WM, Merrill SA (eds) Patents in the knowledge-based economy, 1st edn. The National Academies Press, Washington, DC, pp. 74–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber UP (2013) § 890 ZPO. In: Bernreuther J, others (eds) Münchener Kommentar zur Zivilprozessordnung mit Gerichtsverfassungsgesetz und Nebengesetzen, 4th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Grzeszick B (2007) Geistiges Eigentum und Artikel 14 GG. ZUM 2007:344–353

    Google Scholar 

  • Grzeszick B (2013) Art. 20 GG, VII. In: Maunz T, Dürig G (eds) Grundgesetz – Kommentar, 67th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney TL (2009) Harmonizing the exclusionary rights of patents with compulsory licensing. William Mary Law Rev 50:1395–1438

    Google Scholar 

  • Haddock DD, McChesney FS, Spiegel M (1990) An ordinary economic rationale for extraordinary legal sanctions. Calif Law Rev 78:1–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Halfmeier A (2006) Popularklagen im Privatrecht – Zugleich ein Beitrag zur Theorie der Verbandsklage. Jus privatum, 1st edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH (2004) Exploring the patent explosion. J Technol Transfer 30:35–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH, Ziedonis RH (2001) The patent paradox revisited – an empirical study of patenting in the U.S. semiconductor industry, 1979–1995. RAND J Econ 32:101–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243–1248

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D (2006) The battle for patent rights. In: Peeters C, van Pottelsberghe B (eds) Economic and management perspectives on intellectual property rights. Applied econometrics association series, 1st edn. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp. 21–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D (2009) Economic cost-benefit analysis of a unified and integrated European patent litigation system – final report. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/indprop/docs/patent/studies/litigation_system_en.pdf

  • Harhoff D, Reitzig M (2004) Determinants of opposition against EPO patent grants – the case of biotechnology and pharmaceuticals. Int J Ind Organ 22:443–480

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D, Wagner S (2006) Modeling the duration of patent examination at the European Patent Office. http://www.ip.mpg.de/shared/data/pdf/harhoff_wagner_06.pdf

  • Harhoff D, Hall BH, von Graevenitz G, Hoisl K, Wagner S, Gambardella A, Giuri P (2007) The strategic use of patents and its implications for enterprise and competition policies – final report. http://www.en.inno-tec.bwl.uni-muenchen.de/research/proj/laufendeprojekte/patents/stratpat2007.pdf

  • Heald PJ (2007) Transaction costs and patent reform. Santa Clara Comput High Technol Law J 23:447–462

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann A (2008) Die Relevanz des ‘more economic approach’ für das Recht des geistigen Eigentums. GRUR 2008:949–954

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller MA (1998) The tragedy of the anticommons – property in the transition from Marx to markets. Harv Law Rev 111:621–688

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller MA, Eisenberg RS (1998) Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research. Science 280:698–701

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (1990) Der Schutzbereich des Patents, 1st edn. Helbig & Lichtenhahn Verlag/Carl Heymanns Verlag, Basel/Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2005) Verbotsrecht vs. Vergütungsanspruch – Suche nach den Konsequenzen der tripolaren Interessenlage im Urheberrecht. In: Ohly A, Schricker G (eds) Perspektiven des geistigen Eigentums und Wettbewerbsrechts – Festschrift für Gerhard Schricker zum 70. Geburtstag, 1st edn. Beck, Munich, pp. 325–352

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2009a) Open innovation in einer Welt mit geistigem Eigentum. In: Picot A, Doeblin S (eds) Innovationsführerschaft durch Open Innovation – Chancen für die Telekommunikations-, IT- und Medienindustrie, 1st edn. Springer, Berlin, pp. 171–185

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2009b) The role of patent quality in Europe. In: Drexl J et al (eds) Technology and competition – technologie et concurrence – contributions in honour of Hanns Ullrich, 1st edn. Larcier, Brussels, pp 91–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, Spitzer ML (1993) Willingness to pay vs. willingness to accept – legal and economic implications. Wash Univ Law Q 71:59–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Ihlenfeld J (2008) IP-Com will angeblich 12 Milliarden Euro von Nokia – Bayerischer Rechteverwerter klagt gegen Nokia wegen Patentverletzung. http://www.golem.de/0801/57363.html

  • IPCom GmbH & Co. KG (2009) IPCom FRAND declaration. http://www.ipcom-munich.com/IPCom_Frand_Declaration.pdf

  • Jarass HD (2006) Der grundrechtliche Eigentumsschutz im EU-Recht. NVwZ 2006:1089–1095

    Google Scholar 

  • Jestaedt B (2001) Die erfinderische Tätigkeit in der neueren Rechtsprechung des Bundesgerichtshofs. GRUR 2001:939–944

    Google Scholar 

  • JPO (2009) Germany patent act – as amended by the act on improvement of enforcement of intellectual property rights of 31 July 2009. http://www.jpo.go.jp/shiryou_e/s_sonota_e/fips_e/pdf/germany_e/e_tokkyo.pdf

  • Juve.de (2011) Patent-Prozessserie – IPCom und Frohwitter erwirken Urteil gegen Nokia. http://www.juve.de/nachrichten/verfahren/2011/02/patent-prozessserie-ipcom-und-frohwitter-erwirken-urteil-gegen-nokia

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory – an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Knetsch JL, Thaler RH (1990) Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. J Polit Econ 98:1325–1348

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow L, Shavell S (1995) Do liability rules facilitate bargaining? A reply to Ayres and Talley. Yale Law J 105:221–233

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow L, Shavell S (1996) Property rules versus liability rules – an economic analysis. Harv Law Rev 109:713–790

    Google Scholar 

  • Keukenschrijver A (2013a) § 13 PatG. In: Busse R, Keukenschrijver A (eds) Patentgesetz. De-Gruyter-Kommentar Recht, 7th edn. De Gruyter Recht, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Keukenschrijver A (2013b) § 33 PatG. In: Busse R, Keukenschrijver A (eds) Patentgesetz. De-Gruyter-Kommentar Recht, 7th edn. De Gruyter Recht, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Kieff FS (2001) Property rights and property rules for commercializing inventions. Minn Law Rev 85:697–754

    Google Scholar 

  • Kieff FS (2006) Coordination, property, and intellectual property – an unconventional approach to anticompetitive effects and downstream access. Emory Law J 56:327–438

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinkeldey U, Karamanli T (2012) Art. 56 EPÜ. In: Benkard G et al (eds) Europäisches Patentübereinkommen – Kommentar, 2nd edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Klees A (2012) Das Missbrauchsverbot für beherrschende Unternehmen. In: Kilian W, Heussen B (eds) Computerrechts-Handbuch – Computertechnologie in der Rechts- und Wirtschaftspraxis, 31st edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Klemperer P (1990) How broad should the scope of patent protection be? RAND J Econ 21:113–130

    Google Scholar 

  • Klett AR, Sonntag M, Wilske S (2008) Intellectual property law in Germany – protection, enforcement and dispute resolution. German law accessible, 1st edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Kornhauser LA (1986) An introduction to the economic analysis of contract remedies. Univ Colo Law Rev 57:683–725

    Google Scholar 

  • Korobkin R (2003) The endowment effect and legal analysis. Northwest Univ Law Rev 97:1227–1293

    Google Scholar 

  • Kortum S, Lerner J (1998) Stronger protection or technological revolution – what is behind the recent surge in patenting? Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 48:247–304

    Google Scholar 

  • Kortum S, Lerner J (1999) What is behind the recent surge in patenting? Res Policy 28:1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraßer R (1990) Erfindungsschutz zwischen Patentanmeldung und Patenterteilung. GRUR Int 1990:732–742

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraßer R (1998) Äquivalenz und Abhängigkeit im Patentrecht. In: Großfeld B et al (eds) Festschrift für Wolfgang Fikentscher zum 70. Geburtstag, 1st edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen, pp. 516–540

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraßer R, Bernhardt W (2009) Patentrecht, 6th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Krattiger AF (2004) Financing the bioindustry and facilitating biotechnology transfer. IP Strategy Today 8:1–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Krauss MI (1999) Property rules and liability rules. http://ssrn.com/paper=151791

  • Krieger U (2001) Der Entschädigungsanspruch des § 33 I PatG. GRUR 2001:965–967

    Google Scholar 

  • Krier JE, Schwab SJ (1995) Property rules and liability rules – the cathedral in another light. N Y Univ Law Rev 70:440–483

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugmann M (2001) Die Rechtsweggarantie des GG – Zum Gebot eines qualitativen Rechtsschutzes. ZRP 2001:306–309

    Google Scholar 

  • Kur A, Schovsbo J (2011) Expropriation or fair game for all? The gradual dismantling of the IP exclusivity paradigm. In: Kur A, Levin M (eds) Intellectual property rights in a fair world trade system – proposals for reform of TRIPS, 1st edn. Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 408–451

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann M (1989) Property and intellectual property – property rights as restrictions on competition in furtherance of competition. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 20:1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley MA (2005) Property, intellectual property, and free riding. Tex Law Rev 83:1031–1075

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley MA (2008) Are universities patent trolls? Fordham Intellect Prop Media Entertain Law J 18:611–631

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley MA, Shapiro C (2005) Probabilistic patents. J Econ Perspect 19:75–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley MA, Shapiro C (2007) Patent holdup and royalty stacking. Tex Law Rev 85:1991–2049

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley MA, Weiser PJ (2007) Should property or liability rules govern information? Tex Law Rev 85:783–841

    Google Scholar 

  • Levmore S (1997) Unifying remedies – property rules, liability rules, and startling rules. Yale Law J 106:2149–2173

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewinsohn-Zamir D (2001) The choice between property rules and liability rules revisited – critical observations from behavioral studies. Tex Law Rev 80:219–260

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu K-C (2008) Rationalising the regime of compulsory patent licensing by the essential facilities doctrine. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 39:757–774

    Google Scholar 

  • Luman JF, Dodson CL (2006) No longer a myth, the emergence of the patent troll – stifling innovation, increasing litigation, and extorting billions. Intellect Prop Law J 18:12–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Maaßen S (2009) LG Mannheim – Kein Sukzessionsschutz bei FRAND-Erklärung. FD-GewRS 2009:279796

    Google Scholar 

  • Machlup F (1958) An economic review of the patent system – study no. 15 of the subcommittee on patents, trademarks, and copyrights of the committee on the judiciary. United States Senate, 85th Congress, 2nd session. In: Studies of the Subcommittee on Patents, Trademarks, and Copyrights, 1st edn. GPO, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • McAfee RP (2002) Competitive solutions – the strategist’s toolkit, 1st edn. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Menell PS (2007) The property rights movement’s embrace of intellectual property – true love or doomed relationship? http://ssrn.com/abstract=965083

  • Merges RP (1994a) Of property rules, Coase, and intellectual property. Columbia Law Rev 94:2655–2673

    Google Scholar 

  • Merges RP (1994b) Intellectual property rights and bargaining breakdown – the case of blocking patents. Tenn Law Rev 62:75–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Merges RP (1996) Contracting into liability rules – intellectual property rights and collective rights organizations. Calif Law Rev 84:1293–1393

    Google Scholar 

  • Merges RP (1999) Institutions for intellectual property transactions – the case of patent pools. http://www.law.berkeley.edu/files/pools(1).pdf

  • Merges RP (2009) The trouble with trolls – innovation, rent-seeking, and patent law reform. Berkeley Technol Law J 24:1583–1614

    Google Scholar 

  • Mes P (2011) Patentgesetz, Gebrauchsmustergesetz – Kommentar, 3rd edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer-Ladewig J (2006) Europäische Menschenrechtskonvention – Handkommentar. Nomos-Kommentar, 2nd edn. Nomos-Verlagsgesellschaft, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris M (1993) The structure of entitlements. Cornell Law Rev 78:822–898

    Google Scholar 

  • Mussett N (2013) BGB – English translation. http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/englisch_bgb

  • Nägele T, Jacobs S (2009) Zwangslizenzen im Patentrecht – unter besonderer Berücksichtigung des kartellrechtlichen Zwangslizenzeinwands im Patentverletzungsprozess. WRP 2009:1062–1075

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council of the National Academies (2007) Enhancing productivity growth in the information age – measuring and sustaining the new economy, 1st edn. National Academy Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuhaus W (1990) The claim for compensation under Section 33 of the German patent law in practice. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 30:526–531

    Google Scholar 

  • Niro RP, Greenspoon RP (2007) Are patent trolls really undermining the patent system? Licensing J 21:8–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1972) The optimum life of a patent – reply. Am Econ Rev 62:428–431

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohly A (2008) ‘Patenttrolle’ oder – Der patentrechtliche Unterlassungsanspruch unter Verhältnismäßigkeitsvorbehalt? Aktuelle Entwicklungen im US-Patentrecht und ihre Bedeutung für das deutsche und europäische Patentsystem. GRUR Int 2008:787–798

    Google Scholar 

  • Osterrieth C (2009) Patent-trolls in Europa – braucht das Patentrecht neue Grenzen? GRUR 2009:540–545

    Google Scholar 

  • Osterrieth C (2010) Patentrecht. NJW Praxis, 4th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Pahlow L (2008) Erfindungsschutz vor Patenterteilung. GRUR 2008:97–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Papier J (2013) Art. 14 GG. In: Maunz T, Dürig G (eds) Grundgesetz – Kommentar, 67th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Peukert A (2010) Individual, multiple and collective ownership of intellectual property rights – which impact on exclusivity? http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1563990

  • Picot A (1982) Transaktionskostenansatz in der Organisationstheorie – Stand der Diskussion und Aussagewert. Die Betriebswirtschaft 1982:267–284

    Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky AM (1980) Resolving nuisance disputes – the simple economics of injunctive and damage remedies. Stan Law Rew 32:1075–1112

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlinski JJ, Jourden F (1998) Remedies and the psychology of ownership. Vand Law Rev 51:1541–1582

    Google Scholar 

  • Rai AK, Reichman JH, Uhlir PF, Crossman C (2009) Pathways across the valley of death, novel intellectual property strategies for accelerating drug discovery. In: van Overwalle G (ed) Gene patents and collaborative licensing models – patent pools, clearinghouses, open source models and liability regimes. Cambridge Intellectual Property and Information Law, 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 247–288

    Google Scholar 

  • Remmert B (2013) Art. 19 Abs. 4 GG. In: Maunz T, Dürig G (eds) Grundgesetz – Kommentar, 67th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Riederer M (2007) Anmeldungen und Patente auf Geschäftsmethoden Statistischer Vergleich USA, EP und DE für den Zeitraum von 1995–2006. GRUR Int 2007:402–404

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogge R (2006a) § 22 PatG. In: Benkard G, Asendorf CD (eds) Patentgesetz, Gebrauchsmustergesetz. Beck’sche Kurz-Kommentare, 10th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogge R (2006b) § 24 PatG. In: Benkard G, Asendorf CD (eds) Patentgesetz, Gebrauchsmustergesetz, Beck’sche Kurz-Kommentare, 10th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogge R, Grabinski K (2006) Section § 142 PatG. In: Benkard G, Asendorf CD (eds) Patentgesetz, Gebrauchsmustergesetz. Beck’sche Kurz-Kommentare, 10th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin S (2007) Defending the patent troll – why these allegedly nefarious companies are actually beneficial to innovation. J Priv Equity 10:60–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Sag MJ, Rohde K (2006) Patent reform and differential impact. http://law.bepress.com/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=7353&context=expresso

  • Schankerman M (1998) How valuable is patent protection? Estimates by technology field. RAND J Econ 29:77–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharen U (2006) § 13 PatG. In: Benkard G, Asendorf CD (eds) Patentgesetz, Gebrauchsmustergesetz, Beck’sche Kurz-Kommentare, 10th edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM (1972) Nordhaus’ theory of optimal patent life – a geometric reinterpretation. Am Econ Rev 62:422–427

    Google Scholar 

  • Schickedanz W (2009) Patentverletzung durch Einsatz von geschützten Bauteilen in komplexen Vorrichtungen und die Rolle der Patent-Trolle. GRUR Int 2009:901–907

    Google Scholar 

  • Schovsbo J (2009) Increasing access to patented inventions by post-grant measures. Sci Public Policy 36:609–618

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulte H (1985) Die Erfindung als Eigentum. GRUR 1985:772–778

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulz N, Parisi F, Depoorter B (2002) Fragmentation in property – towards a general model. J Inst Theor Econ 158:594–613

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulze G (2008) § 29 UrhG. In: Dreier T, Schulze G (eds) Urheberrechtsgesetz – Urheberrechtswahrnehmungsgesetz, Kunsturhebergesetz; Kommentar, 3rd edn. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (2001) Navigating the patent thicket – cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting. Innov Policy Econ 1:119–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (2006) Injunctions, hold-up, and patent royalties. http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/royalties.pdf

  • Siebert R, von Graevenitz G (2008) Does licensing resolve hold up in the patent thicket? http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/2104

  • Siebert R, von Graevenitz G (2010) Jostling for advantage or not – choosing between patent portfolio races and ex ante licensing. J Econ Behav Organ 73:225–245

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith HE (2004) Property and property rules. N Y Univ Law Rev 79:1719–1798

    Google Scholar 

  • Sterk SE (2008) Property rules, liability rules, and uncertainty about property rights. Mich Law Rev 106:1285–1335

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern-Dombal CA (2007) Tripping over TRIPS – is compulsory licensing under ebay at odds with U.S. statutory requirements and TRIPS? Suffolk Univ Law Rev 41:249–277

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE, Walsh CE (2010) Band 1 zur Volkswirtschaftslehre – Mikroökonomie. Volkswirtschaftslehre, 4th edn. Oldenbourg, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian S (2008) Different rules for different owners – does a non-competing patentee have a right to exclude? A study of post-ebay cases. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 39:419–451

    Google Scholar 

  • Swope K, Schmitt P (2008) An experimental study of the holdout problem in a multilateral bargaining game. http://www.usna.edu/EconDept/RePEc/usn/wp/usnawp21.pdf

  • Tandon P (1982) Optimal patents with compulsory licensing. J Polit Econ 90:470–486

    Google Scholar 

  • The Board 28 (Board of the Administrative Council set up under Article 28 EPC) (2007) Future workload. p 7

    Google Scholar 

  • Timmann T (2008) Das Patentrecht im Lichte von Art. 14 GG. Geistiges Eigentum und Wettbewerbsrecht, 1st edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomuschat C, Currie DP (2010) Basic law for the Federal Republic of Germany. https://www.btg-bestellservice.de/pdf/80201000.pdf

  • van Overwalle G (2009) Of thickets, blocks and gaps, designing tools to resolve obstacles in the gene patent landscape. In: van Overwalle G (ed) Gene patents and collaborative licensing models – patent pools, clearinghouses, open source models and liability regimes. Cambridge Intellectual Property Information Law, 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 383–463

    Google Scholar 

  • van Overwalle G, Schovsbo J (2007) Policy options for the improvement of the European Patent System. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 38:834–838

    Google Scholar 

  • van Overwalle G, van Zimmeren E, Verbeure B, Matthijs G (2006) Models for facilitating access to patents on genetic inventions. Nat Rev Genet 7:143–148

    Google Scholar 

  • van Pottelsberghe B (2009) The European patent system and why it doesn’t work. Bruegel blueprint series, 1st edn. Bruegel, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • van Zimmeren E, van Overwalle G (2011) A paper tiger? Compulsory license regimes for public health in Europe. Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 42:4–40

    Google Scholar 

  • van Zimmeren E, Verbeure B, Matthijs G, van Overwalle G (2006) A clearing house for diagnostic testing – the solution to ensure access to and use of patented genetic inventions? Bull World Health Organ 84:352–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbeure B, van Zimmeren E, Matthijs G, van Overwalle G (2006) Patent pools and diagnostic testing. Trends Biotechnol 24:115–120

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbruggen J, Lõrincz A (2002) Patente und technische Normen. GRUR Int 2002:815–829

    Google Scholar 

  • von Bassewitz K, Kramer B, zu Prinz Waldeck und Pyrmont W (2004a) Innovationsschutz und Investitionsschutz für immaterielle Güter. GRUR Int 2004:609–610

    Google Scholar 

  • von Bassewitz K, Kramer B, zu Prinz Waldeck und Pyrmont W (2004b) Zusammenfassung des Vortrags ‘Innovationsschutz und Investitionsschutz für immaterielle Güter’ von Prof. Dr. Reto M. Hilty. GRUR Int 2004:607–608

    Google Scholar 

  • von Graevenitz G, Wagner S, Harhoff D (2008) Incidence and growth of patent thickets – the impact of technological opportunities and complexity. http://ssrn.com/paper=1240210

  • von Graevenitz G, Wagner S, Harhoff D (2009) How to measure patent thickets – a novel approach. http://ssrn.com/paper=1434056

  • von Mühlendahl A (2007) Enforcement of intellectual property rights – is injunctive relief mandatory? Int Rev Intellect Prop Competition Law 38:377–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner S (2006) Business method patents in Europe and their strategic use – evidence from franking device manufacturers. http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/1265/1/Wagner_bmp.pdf

  • Webman EJ (1995) Issues arising under an 18 month publication regime – the initial public response in light of EPC and PCT practice. J Pat Trademark Off Soc 77:909–920

    Google Scholar 

  • Weeds H (1999) Sleeping patents and compulsory licensing – an options analysis. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.11.4639&rep=rep1&type=pdf

  • Wild J (2011) Telling it how it is. Intellect Asset Manage 48:67–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams D, Gardner S (2006) Basic framework for effective responses to patent trolls. IP Links 17:1–5

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1987) The economic institutions of capitalism – firms, markets, relational contracting, 1st edn. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wissenschaftlicher Beirat beim Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Technologie (2007) Patentschutz und Innovation, Berlin. http://www.bmwi.de/Dateien/Patentserver/PDF/patentschutz-und-innovation,property=pdf,bereich=bmwi,sprache=de,rwb=true.pdf

  • World Intellectual Property Organization (2010) World intellectual property indicators, Geneva. http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/freepublications/en/intproperty/941/wipo_pub_941_2010.pdf

  • World Trade Organisation Ministerial Conference Fourth Season (2001) Declaration on the TRIPS agreement and public health, Doha. http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/minist_e/min01_e/mindecl_trips_e.htm

  • Wündisch S, Bauer S (2010) Patent-Cross-Lizenzverträge – Terra incognita? GRUR Int 2010:641–649

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziedonis RH (2004) Don’t fence me in – fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms. Manage Sci 50:804–820

    Google Scholar 

  • Zippelius R (1991) Quo vadis Grundgesetz? NJW 1991:23

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Krauspenhaar, D. (2015). Overuse of Exclusivity in Patent Law. In: Liability Rules in Patent Law. Munich Studies on Innovation and Competition, vol 1. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-40900-4_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics