Skip to main content

Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Productivity Growth in China

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Openness, Economic Growth and Regional Disparities

Abstract

This chapter presents an analytic framework and empirical evidence expanding our understanding of the roles of foreign direct investment in shaping regional productivity growth in China. The study investigates the impacts of foreign direct investment (FDI) on China’s regional economic performance and growth. In this study, we build two versions of the relevant theoretical model, one excluding and one including human capital. By using a nonlinear least squares regression technique, our empirical analyses based on the two versions of our theoretical model show that foreign direct investment tends to exert both a general growth effect and a convergence effect on productivity across the Chinese provinces over our sample period. Our findings imply, at least in the case of the Chinese regions, that in addition to its direct, static level effect on output as an accumulable production input, foreign direct investment may also exert indirect, dynamic impacts on output through its growth and convergence effects on productivity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It should be noted that China’s FDI inflows and foreign trade are closely linked. Foreign Invested Enterprises (FIE’s) generally account for over 50 % of China’s exports and 60 % of China’s imports. See, for example, Whalley and Xin (2010) for a recent discussion of the relationship between China’s FDI inflows and foreign trade.

  2. 2.

    Highly unevenly distributed FDI inflows, substantially different degrees of opening up to foreign trade, and huge income disparities across different regions in China, especially those between coastal and inland provinces, are prominent issues during China’s economic transition (see, for example, Yin 2011). For income disparities, for example, by the year 1999 interregional income inequality in China had exceeded that in any other country (see, for example, Yang 1999), and in the year 2005 per capita income of the richer coastal provinces was 2.5 times higher than that of the inland provinces (see, for example, Zhu et al. 2008).

  3. 3.

    Some of such recent studies on the relationship between China’s growth and opening up include, for example, Zhang (1999), Démurger (2000), DaCosta and Carroll (2001), Yao and Zhang (2001), Démurger et al. (2002), Bao et al. (2002), Hu and Owen (2003), Wang and Gao (2003), Zhang (2006), Madariaga and Poncet (2007), Ouyang (2009), Whalley and Xin (2010) and Jiang (2011), to name but a few.

  4. 4.

    According to Zhang (2006), there are a few exceptions. See, for example, Footnote 1 of Zhang (2006).

  5. 5.

    In addition, there is also some evidence for imports-related spillovers, but it is weaker than for FDI.

  6. 6.

    Kokko (1996) argues that this finding may help explain some of the contradictory findings of earlier empirical spillover studies, most of which have assumed that the spillovers are strictly proportional to foreign presence.

  7. 7.

    See Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992), Islam (1995), and Madariaga and Poncet (2007) for details about the specification of the empirical model. The methodology of Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992), further strengthened due to the extension of Islam (1995) and others to panel data, can in principle be used to evaluate not only the Solow model but other candidate growth models as well (Bernanke and Gürkaynak 2001).

  8. 8.

    See Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) and Islam (1995) for a justification of the assumed value of (g + δ).

  9. 9.

    Just as in earlier chapters, here for simplicity of exposition we treat the “population” and “the number of workers” as identical.

  10. 10.

    See previous chapters for a justification for the use of the LSDV regression method.

  11. 11.

    Owing to missing data, we can only include 27 out of the 31 Chinese mainland regions in our sample. Also, we can only cover the period 1991–2005 because of missing data prior to 1991.

  12. 12.

    We assume FDI capital depreciates at an annual rate of 3 %. In a sense, this rate is low. However, we have tried other values of the FDI depreciation rate and found the regression results are not sensitive to the change in the assumed FDI depreciation rate.

  13. 13.

    To save space, we have not summarized the regressions results in a table.

  14. 14.

    This nonlinear least squares method is similar in structure to, for example, those used by de la Fuente and Doménech (2001) and Jiang (2011).

  15. 15.

    These province-level regions in mainland China include provinces, ethnic minority autonomous regions, and municipalities. For the sake of brevity, however, we call all these province-level regions ‘provinces’.

  16. 16.

    For the sake of self-containedness of this chapter, we repeat the description of Zhang (2008)’s calculation procedure in this footnote as follows, though the same description of the calculation procedure has appeared already in Chap. 5. To calculate the annual capital depreciation rate, Zhang (2008) has assumed a geometrically diminishing relative efficiency of capital goods. Under this assumption, the official rate of residual value to the total value of capital goods, which is 3–5 %, implies that, when capital goods come to the end of their life duration, their relative efficiency is only (about) 4 % of new capital goods. The three broad components of fixed capital formation, namely, “completion of construction and installation”, “purchases of equipment and instruments”, and other investments, have an average life duration of 45 years, 20 years and 25 years, respectively. The rates of depreciation for the three broad components are then calculated to be 6.9 %, 14.9 % and 12.1 %, respectively (for all provinces). To calculate the rate of depreciation for overall fixed capital formation, Zhang (2008) then uses 63 %, 29 % and 8 %, which are national-level percentage shares of the three components in total fixed formation (corresponding provincial-level data are unavailable), averaged over the period 1952–2004, as the relative weights of the three components comprising total fixed capital formation. This method leads to the result of an annual rate of depreciation for fixed capital formation of 9.6 % for all provinces.

  17. 17.

    See, for example, Chow and Li (2002), Chow (2008), Zheng, Hu, and Bigsten (2009) and Brandt and Zhu (2010) for related discussions. Specifically in the case of China or the Chinese province-level regions, according to the national income accounts and the national input–output tables constructed by the National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS), we are able to find that the factor share of capital (α) is roughly 0.5 in the non-agricultural sector, about 0.3 in the agricultural sector, and about 0.40–0.42 for the entire economy (Brandt and Zhu 2010). However, Brandt and Zhu (2010) argue that the high factor share of labor in agriculture (which is about 0.7) is inconsistent with estimates made on the basis of household data, which, instead, suggest a labor share in the vicinity of 0.5. Therefore, Brandt and Zhu (2010) assume that α is 0.5 for all sectors in their study throughout their sample period. The difference between the value of α in China and those in some other countries may suggest that in China a different technology is being used or production inputs are organized in a different way.

  18. 18.

    The theoretical model as well as the subsequent empirical analysis in this section does not incorporate the possibility of interregional spatial dependence in terms of the effects of FDI. According to theoretical arguments from new economic geography and endogenous growth models, the phenomenon of such spatial dependence has been associated with the existence of spillovers that cross regional borders. Fingleton and Lόpez-Bazo (2006), for example, advocate applying appropriate tools of spatial econometrics to test for the existence of such spillovers and estimate the magnitude of their effects. However, such tests are beyond the scope of our present analysis in this chapter.

  19. 19.

    A similar functional form has been used in a cross-country growth study of Hall and Jones (1999).

  20. 20.

    Better-educated workers have a comparative advantage in implementing new technologies. See, for example, Benhabib and Speigel (1994) and Prescott (1998).

  21. 21.

    The derivative /dE is the return to schooling estimated in a Mincerian wage regression (Mincer 1974).

  22. 22.

    These rates of return are based on Psacharopoulos (1994)’s survey of evidence from many countries on return-to-schooling estimates. For a recent discussion of human capital and economic growth in China, see Fleisher, Li, and Zhao (2010).

References

  • Aitken BJ, Harrison AE (1999) Do domestic firms benefit from direct foreign investment? Evidence from Venezuela. Am Econ Rev 89(3):605–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alfaro L, Chanda A, Kalemli-Ozcan S, Sayek S (2004) FDI and economic growth: the role of local financial markets. J Int Econ 64(1):89–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bao S, Chang GH, Sachs JD, Woo WT (2002) Geographic factors and China’s regional development under market reforms, 1978–98. China Econ Rev 13(1):89–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Speigel MM (1994) The role of human capital in economic development: evidence from aggregate cross-country data. J Monet Econ 34(2):143–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS, Gürkaynak RS (2001) “Is Growth Exogenous? Taking Mankiw, Romer, and Weil Seriously. NBER macroeconomics annual 2001, 16, pp 11–57, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.A.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borensztein E, De Gregorio J, Lee J-W (1998) How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth? J Int Econ 45(1):115–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt L, Zhu X (2010) Accounting for China’s growth. Working papers tecipa-394. Department of Economics, University of Toronto, Toronto, Canada

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung K, Lin P (2004) Spillover effects of FDI on innovation in China: evidence from the provincial data. China Econ Rev 15(1):25–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow GC (2008) Another look at the rate of increase in TFP in China. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 6(2):219–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow GC, Li K-W (2002) China’s economic growth: 1952–2010. Econ Dev Cult Change 51(1):247–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DaCosta M, Carroll W (2001) Township and village enterprises, openness and regional economic growth in China. Post-Comm Econ 13(2):229–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Fuente A, Doménech R (2001) Schooling data, technological diffusion and the neoclassical model. Am Econ Rev 91(2):323–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Démurger S (2000) Economic opening and growth in China. OECD Development Centre Studies, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Demurger S, Sachs J, Woo WT, Bao S, Chang G, Mellinger A (2002) Geography, economic policy and regional development in China. Asian Econ Pap 1(1):146–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, Hoekman B (2000) Foreign investment and productivity growth in Czech enterprises. World Bank Econ Rev 14(1):49–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durham JB (2004) Absorptive capacity and the effects of foreign direct investment and equity foreign portfolio investment on economic growth. Eur Econ Rev 48(2):285–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fingleton B, Lόpez-Bazo E (2006) Empirical growth models with spatial effects. Pap Reg Sci 85(2):177–198

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleisher B, Li H, Zhao MQ (2010) Human capital, economic growth, and regional inequality in China. J Dev Econ 92(2):215–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Hu D (2001) Regional disparity in China 1985–1994: the effects of globalization and economic liberalization. Ann Reg Sci 35(1):3–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fung KC, Iizaka H, Tong SY (2004) FDI in China: policy, recent trend and impact. Glob Econ Rev 33(2):99–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma S (2005) Absorptive capacity and productivity spillovers from FDI: a threshold regression analysis. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 67(3):281–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma S, Gong Y (2008) FDI, linkages and the efficiency of state-owned enterprises in China. J Dev Stud 44(5):728–749

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma S, Görg H (2002) Foreign direct investment, spillovers and absorptive capacity: evidence from quantile regressions. GEP research paper 02/14. University of Nottingham, Nottingham, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Girma S, Wakelin K (2002) Are there regional spillovers from FDI in the UK? GEP research paper, no. 16. University of Nottingham

    Google Scholar 

  • Girma S, Greenaway D, Wakelin K (2001) Who benefits from foreign direct investment in the UK? Scott J Polit Econ 48(2):119–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass AJ, Saggi K (1998) International technology transfer and the technology gap. J Dev Econ 55(2):369–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hale G, Long C (2006) FDI spillovers and firm ownership in China: labor markets and backward linkages, vol 25, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco working paper series. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE, Jones CI (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Q J Econ 114(1):83–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu A, Robert FO (2003) Gravitation at home and abroad: openness and imbalanced regional growth in China. In: Proceedings of 4th international conference on Chinese economy the efficiency of China’s economic policy, CERDI, Université d’Auvergne, Clermont-Ferrand

    Google Scholar 

  • Islam N (1995) Growth empirics: a panel data approach. Q J Econ 110:1127–1170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Javorcik BS (2004) Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages. Am Econ Rev 94(3):605–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang Yanqing (2011) Economic environment, technology diffusion, and growth of regional total factor productivity in China. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 9(2):151–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller W, Yeaple SR (2009) Multinational enterprises, international trade, and productivity growth: firm-level evidence from the United States. Rev Econ Stat 91(4):821–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinoshita Y (2000) R&D and technology spillovers through FDI: innovation and absorptive capacity. IMF working paper, no. 349

    Google Scholar 

  • Kokko A (1996) Productivity spillovers from competition between local firms and foreign affiliates. J Int Dev 8(4):517–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kugler M (2006) Spillover from foreign direct investment: within or between industries. J Dev Econ 80(2):444–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuo C-C, Yang C-H (2008) Knowledge capital and spillover on regional economic growth: evidence from China. China Econ Rev 19(4):594–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Z (2008) Foreign direct investment and technology spillovers: theory and evidence. J Dev Econ 85(1–2):176–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil DN (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 107:407–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madariaga N, Poncet S (2007) FDI in Chinese cities: spillovers and impact on growth. World Econ 30(5):837–862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J (1974) Schooling, experience, and earnings. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunnenkamp P, Stracke R (2007) Foreign direct investment in post-reform India: likely to work wonders for regional development? Working paper no. 1375. Kiel Institute of World Economics, Kiel

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouyang P (2009) Economic growth, industrial development and inter-regional spillovers from foreign direct investment: evidence from China. Working paper, Department of Economics, Syracuse University

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott EC (1998) Needed: a theory of total factor productivity. Int Econ Rev 39(3):525–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G (1994) Returns to investment in education: a global update. World Dev 22:1325–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Gao T (2003) Openness, income and growth in China. Working paper, Department of Economics, University of Missouri-Columbia

    Google Scholar 

  • Whalley J, Xin X (2010) China’s FDI and Non-FDI economies and the sustainability of future high Chinese growth. China Econ Rev 21(1):123–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang DT (1999) Urban-biased policies and rising income inequality in China. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 89(2):306–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao Shujie, Zongyi Zhang (2001) Regional growth in China under economic reforms. J Dev Stud 38(2):167–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yin H (2011) Characteristics of inter-regional income disparities in China. Soc Sci China 32(3):123–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang KH (1999) How does FDI interact with economic growth in a large developing country? The case of China. Econ Syst 23(4):291–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang KH (2006) Foreign direct investment and economic growth in China: a panel data study for 1992–2004, conference of “WTO, China and Asian Economies, University of International Business and Economics, Beijing

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J (2008) Estimation of China’s provincial capital stock (1952–2004) with applications. J Chinese Econ Bus Stud 6(2):177–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang X, Zhang K (2003) How does globalisation affect regional inequality within a developing country? Evidence from China. J Dev Stud 39(4):47–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng J, Hu A, Bigsten A (2009) Measuring potential output in a rapidly developing economy: the case of China in comparison with the US and EU. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, St. Louis, U.S.A. July/Aug 2009, pp 317–342

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhu S, Lai M, Fu X (2008) Spatial characteristics and dynamics of provincial total factor productivity in China. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 6(2):197–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Jiang, Y. (2014). Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Productivity Growth in China. In: Openness, Economic Growth and Regional Disparities. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-40666-9_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-40666-9_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-40665-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-40666-9

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics