Skip to main content

Openness, Human Capital, and Productivity Growth in the Chinese Regions

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 864 Accesses

Abstract

The study in this chapter empirically examines the effects of openness and human capital on total factor productivity growth in the Chinese regions. In this chapter we build models of technology diffusion in which follower economies achieve productivity growth by taking advantage of technological spillovers from the world technology frontier. We hypothesize that China’s regional productivity growth is a positive function of regional openness and regional human capital, and a negative function of the current level of regional productivity. By applying panel data fixed effects and GMM regression methods, our analysis shows that human capital has both a growth effect and a convergence effect on regional total factor productivity across the Chinese regions. This result implies that besides its direct, static level effect on output as an accumulable factor input, human capital also exerts indirect, dynamic impacts on output through its growth and convergence effects on total factor productivity. Our analysis also shows that regional openness has a growth effect on regional total factor productivity in China.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In previous chapters (Chaps. 3 and 4), we specified a Cobb-Douglas production function with Harrod-neutral (labor-augmenting) technological progress. This was because technological progress must take the labor-augmenting form in order for the model to have a steady state with constant growth rates. It is clear, however, that with the Cobb-Douglas functional form, labor-augmenting (Harrod-neutral), capital-augmenting (Solow-neutral), and Hicks-neutral technological progress are all essentially the same.

  2. 2.

    These 28 provincial-level regions include provinces, ethnic minority autonomous regions, and three municipalities (Beijing, Tianjin, and Shanghai) in mainland China. Owing to missing data, Tibet, Chongqing and Hainan are not included in our sample.

  3. 3.

    Cross-country studies such as those of Hall and Jones (1999) and Aiyar and Feyrer (2002) assume a value of α that is 1/3, for the reason that this value is broadly consistent with national income accounts data for developed countries. However, given the evidence provided by existing literature, we think that the value 1/3 is too low for the Chinese regions.

  4. 4.

    For more details about regional inequality in productivity change between the coastal and non-coastal provinces, see, for example, Chen et al. (2009).

  5. 5.

    Relevant data on regional foreign trade are also obtained from the Chinese Statistical Yearbooks.

  6. 6.

    However, this GMM method has its problems too. Lagged levels can be weak instruments for first differences, especially when the explanatory variables are highly persistent, and the GMM estimator is likely to be severely biased (Durlauf et al. 2004). To mitigate the problem of weak instruments, Blundell and Bond (2000) show that an extended system GMM estimator, in which lagged first-differences of the series are also used as instruments for the levels equations, can dramatically reduce the potentially large biases induced by the aforementioned first-differenced GMM estimator. However, it is beyond the scope of this analysis to incorporate the use of this more sophisticated system GMM approach into the current analysis.

  7. 7.

    These 28 provincial-level regions include provinces, ethnic minority autonomous regions, and three municipalities (Beijing, Tianjin, and Shanghai) in mainland China. Owing to missing data, Tibet, Chongqing and Hainan are not included in our sample.

  8. 8.

    They are derived by following a simulation process. See Appendix B of Wu (2008).

  9. 9.

    Thus, according to Wu (2008), the application of a rate of depreciation of 7 % in Wu (2004) or that of 9.6 % in Zhang (2008) would lead to an underestimation of China’s regional physical capital stock levels.

  10. 10.

    For a review of different depreciation rates and initial values of physical capital used in various studies when applying the perpetual inventory approach in the case of China or its regions, see, for example, Wu (2011).

  11. 11.

    The rate for the first 4 years, 13.4 %, corresponds to the average return to an additional year of schooling in sub-Saharan Africa. The rate for the second 4 years, 10.1 %, is the average return to an additional year of schooling worldwide, while that for schooling above the eighth year, 6.8 %, is taken from the average return to an additional year in the OECD.

  12. 12.

    We are forced to perform this five-group division on the regional population aged six and above only because data on the distribution of educational attainment in the regional employed population or working-age population are not available.

  13. 13.

    Here, in calculating h e, we assume that a worker who has completed university or higher level of education has 17 years of schooling on average.

  14. 14.

    In the next subsection, we will examine how a change in the assumed value of α will affect our regression results.

  15. 15.

    In our data, the minimum, maximum, and average values of ln A it are 2.905, 6.477 and 4.687, respectively.

  16. 16.

    The term ln F it  ln h it is still insignificant if it is included in the regression equation, so regression (3) excludes this term.

  17. 17.

    In order to save space, the results of the regressions in this subsection are not explicitly reported in tables. However, the results are available from the author upon request.

References

  • Aiyar Shekhar, Feyrer J (2002) A contribution to the empirics of total factor productivity. Dartmouth College working paper no. 02–09

    Google Scholar 

  • Amemiya T (1967) A note on the estimation of Balestra-Nerlove models, vol 4, Technical report. Institute for Mathematical Studies in Social Sciences, Stanford University, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Speigel MM (1994) The role of human capital in economic development: evidence from aggregate cross-country data. J Monet Econ 34(2):143–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (2000) GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Econ Rev 19(3):321–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borensztein E, Ostry JD (1996) Accounting for China’s growth performance. Am Econ Rev 86(2):224–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandt L, Zhu X (2010) Accounting for China’s growth. Working papers tecipa-394. Department of Economics, University of Toronto, Toronto, Canada

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen K-H, Huang Y-J, Yang C-H (2009) Analysis of regional productivity growth in China: a generalized metafrontier MPI approach. China Econ Rev 20(4):777–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow GC (1993) Capital formation and economic growth in China. Q J Econ 108(3):809–842

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow GC (2008) Another look at the rate of increase in TFP in China. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 6(2):219–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow GC, Li K-W (2002) China’s economic growth: 1952–2010. Econ Dev Cult Change 51(1):247–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA, Temple JRW (2004) Growth econometrics. Vassar College Department of Economics working paper series 61. Vassar College Department of Economics

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleisher Belton, Haizheng Li, Minqiang Zhao (2010) Human capital, economic growth, and regional inequality in China. J Dev Econ 92(2):215–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE, Jones CI (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Q J Econ 114:83–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Islam Nazrul (1995) Growth empirics: a panel data approach. Q J Econ 110:1127–1170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Islam Nazrul, Erbiao Dai, Hiroshi Sakamoto (2006) Role of TFP in China’s growth. Asian Econ J 20(2):127–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang Yanqing (2011) Understanding openness and productivity growth in China: an empirical study of the Chinese provinces. China Econ Rev 22(3):290–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klenow P, Rodriguez-Clare A (1997) The neoclassical revival in growth economics: has it gone too far? NBER Macroecon Annu 12:73–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE (2009) Trade and the diffusion of the industrial revolution. Am Econ J Macroecon 1(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J (1974) Schooling, experience, and earnings. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Phelps E (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 56:69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott EC (1998) Needed: a theory of total factor productivity. Int Econ Rev 39(3):525–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G (1994) Returns to investment in education: a global update. World Dev 22:1325–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Yan, Yudong Yao (2003) Sources of China’s economic growth 1952–1999: incorporating human capital accumulation. China Econ Rev 14(1):32–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2001) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1997) China 2020: development challenges in the new century. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu Yanrui (2004) China’s economic growth: a miracle with Chinese characteristics. Routledge Curzon Press, London\New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu Yanrui (2008) The role of productivity in China’s growth: new estimates. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 6(2):141–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu Yanrui (2011) Total factor productivity growth in China: a review. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 9(2):111–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (2003) Gold into base metals: productivity growth in the people’s republic of China during the reform period. J Polit Econ 111:1220–1261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Jun (2008) Estimation of China’s provincial capital stock (1952–2004) with applications. J Chin Econ Bus Stud 6(2):177–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng J, Hu A, Bigsten A (2009) Measuring potential output in a rapidly developing economy: the case of China in comparison with the US and EU. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, July/August 2009, pp 317–342

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Jiang, Y. (2014). Openness, Human Capital, and Productivity Growth in the Chinese Regions. In: Openness, Economic Growth and Regional Disparities. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-40666-9_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-40666-9_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-40665-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-40666-9

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics