Skip to main content

The Emission Price Dynamics

  • Chapter
Environmental Finance and Investments

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 1533 Accesses

Abstract

Since the creation of the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) in 2005, a burgeoning academic literature has emerged to identify the key price drivers of European Union Allowances. This chapter overviews the main econometric studies that investigate energy prices, weather events, and macroeconomic shocks as determinants of allowance prices. A coal-to-gas switching model is introduced and calibrated to real data. Given the importance of understanding the emission permit price formation, this remaining of this chapter provides an overview of deterministic and stochastic equilibrium permit price models suggested in the literature. Several market design institutions are considered. Banking and borrowing limitations, strategic trading interactions, and asymmetric information in the permit market are the most relevant.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 89.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    While the following list of papers is certainly not complete, it contains most of the processes that have been suggested in the literature: Alberola and Chevallier (2009), Bunn and Fezzi (2009), Hintermann (2010), Gronwald et al. (2011), and Creti et al. (2012).

  2. 2.

    A more detailed description of some of these models is provided in the next section.

  3. 3.

    The National Balancing Point is a virtual trading location for the sale, purchase and exchange of UK natural gas. It is the pricing and delivery point for the Intercontinental Exchange natural gas futures contract. Currently, it is the most liquid gas trading point in Europe. The Argus-McCloskey Coal Price Index service is the source of the API prices, which are the key indexes used for international physical and derivatives coal business. The API#2 index is the industry standard reference price used to trade coal imported into northwest Europe. The API 2 index is an average of the Argus CIF Rotterdam assessment and McCloskey’s northwest European steam coal marker.

  4. 4.

    Therm stands for 100,000 British thermal units (Btu).

  5. 5.

    A detailed description of the calibration procedure can be found in Brigo et al. (2009). We refer to Daskalakis et al. (2009) and Chevallier (2011) for a discussion of the model extensions.

  6. 6.

    This section has been written together with Georg Grüll.

  7. 7.

    The formulation as a maximization problem is chosen to simplify the comparison exercise with the other models under investigation.

  8. 8.

    It is interesting to observe that the firm’s target function is similar to the one used in the stochastic models where a fine for non-compliance is explicitly modelled in the objective function.

  9. 9.

    There are modelling choice that make Seifert et al. (2008) different from Chesney and Taschini (2012) and Carmona et al. (2009). In particular, pollution emissions are broken down into emissions before abatement activities and after abatement activities.

References

  • Alberola, E., & Chevallier, J. (2009). European carbon prices and banking restrictions: evidence from phase I. Energy Journal, 30, 51–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Sala-i Martin, X. (1995). Economic growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benz, E., & Trück, S. (2008). Modeling the price dynamics of CO2 emission allowances. Energy Economics, 31(1), 4–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brigo, D., Dalessandro, A., Neugebauer, M., & Triki, F. (2009). A stochastic processes toolkit for risk management: geometric Brownian motion, jumps, GARCH and variance gamma models. Journal of Risk Management in Financial Institutions, 2(4), 365–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bunn, D., & Fezzi, C. (2009). Structural interactions of European carbon trading and energy prices. The Journal of Energy Markets, 4, 53–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carmona, R., Fehr, M., Hinz, J., & Porchet, A. (2009). Market design for emission trading schemes. SIAM Review, 9(3), 465–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesney, M., & Taschini, L. (2012). The endogenous price dynamics of emission allowances and an application to CO2 option pricing. Applied Mathematical Finance, 19(5), 447–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chevallier, J. (2011). Econometric analysis of carbon markets: the European union emission trading scheme and the clean development mechanism. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cleveland, R. B., Cleveland, W. S., McRae, J., & Terpenning, I. (1990). STL: a seasonal-trend decomposition procedure based on loess. Journal of Official Statistics, 6(1), 3–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Creti, A., Jouvet, P., & Mignon, V. (2012). Carbon price drivers: phase I versus phase II equilibrium? Energy Economics, 34(1), 327–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crocker, T. (1966). The economics of air pollution: Vol. 1. The structuring of atmospheric pollution control systems. New York: Harold Wolozin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cronshaw, M. B., & Kruse, J. B. (1996). Regulated firms in pollution permit markets with banking. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9, 179–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dales, J. (1968). Pollution property and prices. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daskalakis, G., Psychoyios, D., & Markellos, R. N. (2009). Modeling CO2 emission allowance prices and derivatives: evidence from the European trading scheme. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33(7), 1230–1241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fusai, G., & Roncoroni, A. (2008). Implementing models in quantitative finance: methods and cases. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gronwald, M., Ketterer, J., & Trück, S. (2011). The dependence structure between carbon emission allowances and financial markets—a copula analysis. Economic Record, 87(1), 105–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grüll, G., & Kiesel, R. (2009). Pricing CO 2 permits using approximation approaches. Preprint.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hintermann, B. (2010). Allowance price drivers in the first phase of the EU ETS. Journal of Environmental Economics and Managements, 59(1), 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kijima, M., Maeda, A., & Nishide, K. (2010). Equilibrium pricing of contingent claims in tradable permit markets. The Journal of Futures Markets, 30(6), 559–589.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kling, C., & Rubin, J. D. (1997). Bankable permits for the control of environmental pollution. Journal of Public Economics, 64, 101–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery, W. (1972b). Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs. Journal of Economic Theory, 5, 395–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paolella, M. S., & Taschini, L. (2008). An econometric analysis of emission–allowances prices. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32(10), 2022–2032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pontryagin, L., Boltayanskii, V., Gamkrelidze, R., & Mishchenko, E. (1962). The mathematical theory of optimal processes. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, J. D. (1996). A model of intertemporal emission trading, banking, and borrowing. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 31, 269–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seifert, J., Uhrig-Homburg, M., & Wagner, M. (2008). Dynamic behavior of CO2 spot prices. Journal of Environmental Economics and Managements, 56, 180–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taschini, L., & Urech, S. (2010). The real option to fuel switch in the presence of expected windfall profits under the EU ETS. Journal of Energy Markets, 3(2), 27–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tietenberg, T. (1985). Emission trading: an exercise in reforming pollution policy. Working paper, Resources for the Future, Washington D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uhrig-Homburg, M., & Wagner, M. (2007). Futures price dynamics of CO 2 emission certificates—an empirical analysis. Preprint.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

This Appendix provides an overview of the techniques used to solve static and dynamic linear optimization problems and some details about the models introduced before.

6.1.1 Solving Static Optimization Problems

Definition 6.19

(Lagrangian)

Let \(x = (x_{1}, \ldots, x_{n}) \in\mathbb{R}^{n}\) and let f(x),g 1(x),…,g m (x) be functions.

Then the Lagrangian of the following static nonlinear optimization problem

is given by

Definition 6.20

(Static convex optimization with non-negative control variables)

Let x=(x 1,…,x n′,x n′+1,…,x n ). Assume that f(x),g 1(x),…,g m (x) are convex functions that are continuously differentiable. Furthermore, assume that there exists \(\tilde{x} \in\mathbb{R}^{n}\) such that \(g_{j}(\tilde{x})< 0\) holds for all non-linear constraints. We consider the following optimization problem:

$$\everymath{\displaystyle} \begin{array}{l@{\quad}l@{\quad}l} \min_{x_1,\ldots,x_n}\bigl\{f(x)\bigr\}& \\ \text{subject to}& g_j(x) \leq0 &\text{for } j=1,\ldots,m \text{ and}\\ &x_i\geq0 &\text{for } i=1, \ldots, n'\ (n' \leq n). \end{array} $$

Theorem 6.21

(Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions)

\(x=(\tilde{x}_{1},\ldots, \tilde{x}_{n})\) is the optimal solution of the optimization problem of Definition 6.20 if and only if there exists \(\tilde{u}\in\mathbb{R}^{m}\) such that all the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions are satisfied:

For i=1,…,n′

(A.1)
(A.2)
(A.3)

and for i=n′+1,…,n

(A.4)

and for j=1,…,m

(A.5)
(A.6)
(A.7)

6.1.2 Solving Dynamic Optimization Problems

Theorem 6.22

(Dynamic optimization problem)

Let T<∞ and let f and g be twice differentiable concave functions. Consider the following dynamic, deterministic optimization problem

(A.8)
(A.9)
(A.10)
(A.11)

Then the Hamiltonian is defined as

(A.12)

and the solution of the optimization problem must satisfy

(A.13)
(A.14)
(A.15)
(A.16)

Remark

  1. (a)

    x(t) is called control variable. The state variable s(t) is influenced by the choice of the control variable.

  2. (b)

    Equation (A.13) is similar to the condition in a static non-linear optimization problem.

  3. (c)

    Equation (A.15) restates the condition on the state variable (cf. Eq. (A.9)).

  4. (d)

    Equation (A.16) is called transversality condition.

Proof 9 (Idea)

A rigorous proof can be found in Pontryagin et al. (1962). The following proof is along the lines of Barro and Sala-i Martin (1995).

First, we rewrite the constraint as an integral and set up the Lagrangian function with the continuum of multipliers u(t) for the dynamic constraint and the multiplier v for the terminal condition of the state variable:

Second, integration by parts of

and using the definition of the Hamiltonian yields

(A.17)

Third, solve the problem using perturbation analysis:

Let \(\bar{x}(t)\) be the optimal path for the control variable. The constraint \(\dot{s}(t) = g (s(t), x(t), t )\) yields an optimal path for the state variable that we denote by \(\bar{s}(t)\). Define the perturbations of the optimal paths by

where ε is a scalar and p (x):=p (x)(t) and p (s):=p (s)(t) are called perturbation functions. The perturbation analysis is completed by using that near the optimum small perturbations do not affect the maximum value of our optimization problem, that is,

(A.18)

Applying the chain rule to Eq. (A.17) yields

Since \(\frac{\partial L}{\partial\varepsilon} (s(t),\bar{x}(t),t )=0\) must hold for any choice of perturbation functions, we obtain

Combining v=u(T) and vâ‹…s(T)=0, the complementary slackness condition from the terminal constraint, yields the so-called transversality condition

 □

6.1.3 Relationship Between Optimality Conditions

Lemma 6.23

A solution of the joint cost minimization problem satisfies the conditions of a market equilibrium.

Proof 10

Using the conditions given in (6.11) and (6.12) we show that

satisfy the conditions given in (6.7)–(6.10).

Conditions (6.11) and (6.12) imply Eq. (6.7):

Since \(\frac{\partial C^{i}}{\partial Q^{i}}(\widetilde{Q}^{i})+\tilde{u}\leq0\) for and \(\widetilde{Q}^{i}\geq0\) all i=1,…,n, it follows from \(\sum^{n}_{i=1}\widetilde{Q}^{i} [\frac{\partial C^{i}}{\partial Q^{i}}(\widetilde {Q}^{i})+\tilde{u} ]=0\) that \(\widetilde{Q}^{i} [\frac{\partial C^{i}}{\partial Q^{i}}(\widetilde{Q}^{i})+\tilde {u} ]=0\) holds for all i=1,…,n. Therefore, \(\widetilde{Q}^{i}\) and \(\tilde {u}\) satisfy Eq. (6.7) for all i=1,…,n.

Conditions (6.11) and (6.12) imply Eq. (6.8):

If \(\bar{u}_{i} = \tilde{u} = \bar{S}\), \(\bar{S}-\bar{u}_{i}=0\) satisfied for all i=1,…,n by any \(\bar{\theta}^{i}\).

Conditions (6.11) and (6.12) imply Eq. (6.9):

By \(\bar{Q}^{i} =\widetilde{Q}^{i}\) and \(N^{i}+\bar{\theta}^{i} -\widetilde{Q}^{i} = 0\), Eq. (6.9) is satisfied for any \(\bar{u}_{i}\).

Conditions (6.11) and (6.12) imply Eq. (6.10):

 □

Lemma 6.24

Any emission vector that satisfies the conditions of a market equilibrium is a solution of the joint cost minimization problem.

Proof 11

Using the conditions given in (6.7)–(6.10) we show that

satisfy the conditions given in (6.11) and (6.12).

Conditions (6.7)–(6.10) imply Eq. (6.11):

By Eq. (6.8), \(\bar{u}_{i} = \bar{S}\). Therefore,

which implies \(\sum^{n}_{i=1}\bar{Q}^{i} [\frac{\partial C^{i}}{\partial Q^{i}}(\bar{Q}^{i})+\bar{S} ]=0\). Therefore, \(\bar{Q}^{i}\) and \(\tilde{u}=\bar{S}\) satisfy Eq. (6.11).

Conditions (6.7)–(6.10) imply Eq. (6.12):

By Eq. (6.9) and (6.10), \(\sum^{n}_{i=1}(N-\bar{Q}^{i}) \geq-\sum^{n}_{i=1}\bar{\theta}^{t} \geq0\).

By Eq. (6.8), Eq. (6.9) becomes \(\bar{S} [N^{t} +\bar{\theta}^{i} -\bar{Q}^{i} ]=0\). By Eq. (6.10),

Therefore, \(\bar{Q}^{i}\) and \(\tilde{u}=\bar{S}\) satisfy Eq. (6.12). □

6.1.4 The Solution for a Representative Agent in Seifert et al. (2008)

After showing the equivalence between the market equilibrium and the joint cost problem, Seifert et al. (2008) solves the cost optimization problem of a representative agent as follows.

Let us define q t , the total cumulative emissions minus the number of allowances bought and sold, as:

Definition 6.25

(Market equilibrium)

A market equilibrium with associated optimal strategies, consisting of \(\bar{S}_{t}\), \((\bar{\alpha}^{1}_{t},\ldots,\alpha^{n}_{t})\) and \((\bar{\theta}^{1}_{t},\ldots,\theta^{n}_{t})\), solves the firms’ individual cost optimization problems as given in Definition 6.11 and satisfies the market clearing condition

Definition 6.26

(Global optimization problem)

The central planner minimizes joint costs of the firms by choosing optimal abatement strategies:

(A.19)

The dynamics of the total cumulative emissions are given in Lemma 6.27. A characteristic partial differential equation (PDE) and an analytical expression for the allowance price can be found in Theorem 6.29.

Lemma 6.27

(SDE for emissions of the representative agent q t )

Assume that the emission rate before abatement activities, β t , follows

  1. (i)

    the White–Noise process β t ∼N(β 0,σ 2) or

  2. (ii)

    the arithmetic Brownian motion β t =β 0+σW t .

Then the SDE for the cumulative emissions of the representative agent are given by

where H t is (i) H t =σ and (ii) H t =σ(T−t).

Proof 12

See online appendix of Seifert et al. (2008). □

Definition 6.28

(Optimization problem of the representative agent)

Given the allowance price S, the representative agent minimizes its expected costs by choosing an optimal abatement strategy:

(A.20)

Theorem 6.29

(Permit price dynamics)

Let V(t,q t ) be the expected value of an optimal policy for the optimization problem in Definition 6.28 between time t and T.

Denote its partial derivatives by V t , V q , V qq .

  1. (a)

    Assume that the emission rate before abatement activities is given by the arithmetic Brownian motion in Lemma 6.27.

    Then the characteristic PDE of the allowance price is given by

    with boundary condition

    and the allowance price is given by

  2. (b)

    Assuming that the emission rate before abatement activities is given by the White–Noise process in Lemma 6.27. Then the characteristic PDE of the allowance price is given by

    and there is an analytical formula for the allowance price:

    where \(\operatorname{erf}c(x)=1-\operatorname{erf}(x)=\frac{2}{\sqrt{\pi}}\int^{\infty}_{x} e^{-t^{2}}\,dt\) is the complementary error function.

Proof 13 (Idea)

Similar to the proof of Lemma 6.13, Itô’s lemma and Lemma 6.27 imply

By the principle of optimality

(A.21)

Subtracting V(t,q t ) on both sides of Eq. (A.21) yields

(A.22)

Maximizing the expression within the curly brackets by deriving it with respect to α t and setting it to zero yields

(A.23)

The characteristic PDE is obtained by setting the expression within the curly brackets in Eq. (A.22) to zero and by inserting the formula for α t into this equation:

(A.24)

The spot price equals marginal abatement costs as shown in Lemma 6.13, that is,

  1. (a)

    The proof is completed by using (ii) of Lemma 6.27.

  2. (b)

    The characteristic PDE follows directly from Eq. (A.24) by using part (i) of Lemma 6.27. A solution of this PDE is derived by Seifert et al. (2008). □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Chesney, M., Gheyssens, J., Taschini, L. (2013). The Emission Price Dynamics. In: Environmental Finance and Investments. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-36623-9_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics