Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Contributions to Management Science ((MANAGEMENT SC.))

  • 696 Accesses

Abstract

The final chapter synthesises the study’s empirical results on the impact of managerial discretion on performance to generate far-reaching implications for research and practice that work towards resolving the discretion puzzle. There are five major contributions: (1) a proof of the importance of granularity for resolving the discretion puzzle; (2) a new empirically-validated discretion model (as a tool kit for future applications) that accounts for granularity; (3) for empirical research, an appraisal of existing research designs and recommendations for future research designs that can help avoid the discretion puzzle’s arbitrary results; (4) for theoretical research, evidence on the applicability of principal-agent theory and stewardship theory, and recommendations for future theory development; and (5) for practice, actionable advice to the top management of Chinese firms and multinationals on how to manage managers in China. This chapter concludes with a discussion of the present study's limitations and accordingly suggests new avenues of research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    As explained in Sect. 1.3, the present study employs a database of 467 plant managers in China that was developed by McKinsey & Company, the London School of Economics, and Stanford University (2008).

  2. 2.

    The present study’s discretion puzzle relates to the managerial discretion of managers in organisations and is therefore distinct from the puzzle of discretion (Pratt and Sossin 2009) that concerns judicial discretion in law.

  3. 3.

    Managerial discretion theory (e.g. Abrahamson and Hambrick 1997; Berman et al. 2005; Carpenter and Golden 1997; Caza 2007, 2011; Huiyuan Chen 2006; Crossland 2007; Crossland and Hambrick 2007; Datta et al. 2003; Finkelstein and Boyd 1998; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990; Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007; Haleblian and Finkelstein 1993; Hambrick and Abrahamson 1995; Hambrick and Finkelstein 1987; Hambrick et al. 1993; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007; Keegan 2006; Keegan and Kabanoff 2008; Key 2002; Yougen Li and Zhao 2004; Magnan and St-Onge 1997; Quigley and Hambrick 2009; Rajagopalan and Finkelstein 1992; Thomas and Peyrefitte 1996; Zhang and Li 2008b; Zhang et al. 2006a, b).

  4. 4.

    Principal-agent theory (e.g. Agrawal and Knoeber 1996; Baysinger and Butler 1985; Berger et al. 1997; Brush et al. 2000; Chang and Wong 2003; Childs and Mauer 2008; Denis et al. 1997; Eisenhardt 1989; Fama 1980; Fama and Jensen 1983a, b; He et al. 2009; Jensen 1986; Jensen and Meckling 1976; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Jensen and Ruback 1983; Laffont and Martimort 2002; Lang et al. 1995; Levinthal 1988; Ongore 2011; Shleifer and Vishny 1997; Spremann 1987; Thépot 2007; Thomsen and Pedersen 2000; Walters 1995; Wang et al. 2008; Weidenbaum and Jensen 1993; Werner and Tosi 1995, p. 1673; Xu et al. 2005; Zou 1989).

  5. 5.

    Stewardship theory (e.g. Albanese et al. 1997; Arthurs and Busenitz 2003; Corbetta and Salvato 2004; Davis et al. 1997a, b; Dicke and Ott 2002; Donaldson 1990; Donaldson and Davis 1989, 1991, 1993, 1994; Eddleston and Kellermanns 2007; Fox and Hamilton 1994; Lane et al. 1999; Liu and Cai 2004; Miller and Le Breton-Miller 2006; Mills and Keast 2009; Muth and Donaldson 1998; Salvato 2002; Tian and Lau 2001; Tosi et al. 2003; Van Slyke 2007; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005; Zahra 2003).

  6. 6.

    The fictitious scatter plot format has been used throughout the present study (e.g. Fig. 2.1 in Sect. 2.2.2). In terms of the algebraic notation utilised throughout Chap. 2, Fig. 7.1 depicts performance as a linear function of discretion (i.e. \( P=d\cdot D+c\cdot C+m\cdot \left( {D\cdot M} \right) \)), with the impact of discretion on performance (i.e. \( {{{\partial P}} \left/ {{\partial D}} \right.}=d+m\cdot M \)) represented by the slopes of the lines. When the impact of discretion on performance is positive (\( {{{\partial P}} \left/ {{\partial D}} \right.}>0 \)), the line is upwards-sloping and when the impact is negative, it is downwards-sloping.

  7. 7.

    The influences derived from principal-agent theory include the manager’s natural predisposition to performance maximisation, compensation control mechanisms, the nature of managerial activities, monitoring control mechanisms, and the manager’s ability, knowledge, and information (see Table 2.9 in Sect. 2.3.2.2; e.g. Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Cheng et al. 2006; Davis et al. 1997b; Eisenhardt 1989; Fama and Jensen 1983b; Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007; Jensen and Meckling 1976; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Wang et al. 2008; Zhang and Li 2008b). Likewise, stewardship theorists have argued that the principal’s and manager’s psychological characteristics, perceptions of the organisation’s situational characteristics, and expectations may act as potential influences on whether managers use their discretion so as to increase or decrease performance (see Sect. 2.3.3.2; e.g. Argyris 1973a, b; Brown 1969; Caza 2007; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 27–43; French and Raven 1959; Gibson et al. 1991; Hofstede 1980, 1991; Katz and Kahn 1978; Khanchel 2009, p. 98; Lane et al. 1999, p. 1079; Lawler 1986, 1992; Maslow 1970; McGregor 1960; Mills and Keast 2009; Simon 1957a, b; Triandis 1990, 1995; Triandis et al. 1993; Turner 1981; Van Slyke 2007, p. 164; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005; Walton 1980, 1985).

  8. 8.

    This difference in hiring discretion’s impact by firm type is significant (see Sect. 6.2.2). As explained in Box 2.6 in Sect. 2.4.2, this might be due to cultural and management philosophy differences (e.g. Aminpour and Woetzel 2006, pp. 46–47; Hanne Chen 2004, p. 128; Crossland and Hambrick 2007, p. 14; Hexter 2006, pp. 4–6; Hexter and Woetzel 2007a, p. 4; Hoover 2006, p. 92; McGregor 2005, pp. 273–274). In addition, Sect. 6.2.3 finds that firm size influences the impact of discretion on performance in the present study.

  9. 9.

    As discussed in Sects. 2.2.3 and 7.3.2, there are several modelling methodologies for differentiating research designs by influences on managers, such as investigating only managers subject to similar influences (e.g. only managers in comparable Chinese firms), investigating groups of managers each subject to similar influences (e.g. splitting managers into Chinese firms and multinationals) or combining managers in a sample but accounting for differences by modelling influences as moderators (e.g. Arnold 1982; Carte and Russell 2003, pp. 480–495; Chin et al. 2003, pp. 196–200; Henseler and Fassott 2010, pp. 719–721; Irwin and McClelland 2001, p. 105; Rigdon et al. 1998, p. 1; Venkatraman 1989, p. 426). The corollary is that if a unit of analysis is broadly-defined (e.g. Chinese firms and multinationals) and the modelling methodology does not distinguish between influences on managers via grouping or moderators, granularity may be too limited to accurately reveal the underlying impacts of discretion on performance.

  10. 10.

    In short, as to dimension of discretion, whenever discretion’s impact on performance granularly differs by dimensions of discretion (as for plant managers in Table 7.1), arbitrarily positive, neutral or negative impacts of discretion may be estimated by research designs that do not differentiate between discretion dimensions (i.e. unidimensional measures, as the ones presented above). Whether discretion is then found to improve, not alter or reduce performance would depend on the discretion dimensions into which the measure principally taps, e.g. capital investment discretion versus hiring discretion. As to influences on managers, whenever discretion’s impact on performance granularly differs by influences on managers (as for plant managers in Table 7.1), then arbitrarily positive, neutral or negative impacts of discretion may be estimated by research designs that do not differentiate between these influences (i.e. combine managers under distinct influences into a single broadly-defined unit of analysis without using grouping or moderators). Whether discretion is then found to improve, not alter or reduce performance would depend on the influences on the managers that predominate in the sample, e.g. the management philosophy and culture of Chinese firms.

  11. 11.

    As to condition (i), a number of empirical studies demonstrate that the underlying landscape of impacts of discretion on performance differs in a granular way (as in Table 7.1, e.g. positive for one discretion dimension under one set of influences on managers and negative for another dimension under another set of influences). In other words, various studies confirm the postulate that there is no single positive, neutral or negative impact of discretion on performance but rather that managers may use their discretion differently to impact on performance depending on the area of work in which discretion is granted (i.e. dimension of discretion; e.g. Groves et al. 1994; Xiaoyang Li 2007) and depending on various influences on the manager (e.g. Caza 2007; Cheng et al. 2006; López-Navarro and Camisón-Zornoza 2003; Wang et al. 2008; Zhang and Li 2008b; Zhao et al. 2010). As to condition (ii), Sects. 1.1 and 2.2.3 have shown that many existing studies have indeed employed research designs with limited granularity, often failing to differentiate the estimated impact of discretion on performance by dimensions of discretion and influences on managers (e.g. Bowen et al. 2008; Chang and Wong 2003; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Groves et al. 1994; He et al. 2009; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Stano 1976; Venaik 1999; Werner and Tosi 1995; Zhang 1997). As to condition (iii), distinct non-granular research designs (e.g. measures tapping into distinct discretion dimensions or units of analysis facing distinct influences) were found to be prevalent in existing studies in Sect. 2.2.3 (e.g. Adams et al. 2005; Huiyuan Chen 2006; Cheng et al. 2006; Heinecke 2011; Thomas and Peyrefitte 1996; Walters 1995; Wang et al. 2008; Xu et al. 2005; Yan et al. 2010; Zhang and Li 2008b).

  12. 12.

    Notwithstanding this compelling step towards resolving the discretion puzzle by establishing the importance of granularity for future research, this study recognises its limitations and allows for the fact that other approaches to resolving the discretion puzzle might exist (see Sect. 7.6).

  13. 13.

    The importance of granularity was established in Sect. 7.1 by confirming the postulate that discretion does not universally have a single positive, neutral or negative impact on performance by virtue of a thorough, in-depth review of managerial discretion theory, principal-agent theory, and stewardship theory (see Chap. 2), an empirical proof-by-counter-example for plant managers in China (see Chap. 6), and various studies with complementary findings (e.g. Caza 2007; Cheng et al. 2006; Groves et al. 1994; Xiaoyang Li 2007; López-Navarro and Camisón-Zornoza 2003; Wang et al. 2008; Zhang and Li 2008b; Zhao et al. 2010).

  14. 14.

    Managerial discretion, industry technology intensity, and firm size explain nearly a third of the variation of performance among plant managers in Chinese firms and multinationals in this study (see Sect. 5.1.2). More detailed descriptions of the new discretion model appear elsewhere in this study, i.e. in Chap. 4 (derivation and specification), Chap. 5 (validation), Chap. 6 (application), and Chap. 7 (interpretation).

  15. 15.

    These empirical results are used in Sect. 7.5 to derive recommendations for top management on how to adjust the degrees of managerial discretion granted to their plant managers in China so as to raise performance.

  16. 16.

    See Equation (6.1) in Sect. 6.1, which for the average Chinese firm estimates how expanding firm size empirically alters a manager’s discretion (\( D \) by \( a \)) and thereby his/her managerial action, that via the direct effect (\( d \)) impacts on performance (\( P \) by \( d\cdot a \))—yielding the ‘Mediating Effect (da)’ in Fig. 7.2.

  17. 17.

    One may view the new discretion model as a general model and many of the existing studies reviewed in Sect. 2.2 as special cases of this model. These special cases tend to oversimplify the context of managerial discretion in terms of granularity: They frequently model discretion as a unidimensional construct instead of differentiating discretion by multiple dimensions as in the new discretion model, and they often aggregate many managers into one unit of analysis instead of differentiating by influences on managers (see Sects. 1.1 and 2.2.3; e.g. Bowen et al. 2008; Chang and Wong 2003; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Groves et al. 1994; He et al. 2009; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Stano 1976; Venaik 1999; Werner and Tosi 1995; Zhang 1997).

  18. 18.

    In order to account for greater granularity, the theories are woven into the new discretion model with more fine-grained granularity than in many previous studies (see Sect. 2.2), simultaneously differentiating the impact of discretion on performance by dimensions of discretion (as derived from managerial discretion theory) and by influences on managers (as derived from principal-agent theory and stewardship theory).

  19. 19.

    The limitations of the new discretion model are discussed in Sect. 7.6.

  20. 20.

    Table 7.1 shows discretion’s performance impact in average-sized Chinese firms and multinationals in China.

  21. 21.

    The study’s four discretion dimensions in Table 7.2 are examples that demonstrate the multidimensionality of discretion for plant managers in China. Nevertheless, there may well be other dimensions of discretion beyond these four dimensions, which will need to be further investigated in future research (see Sect. 7.6).

  22. 22.

    Principal-agent theory (see Sect. 2.3.2) and stewardship theory (see Sect. 2.3.3) have tended to treat discretion as a single overall (i.e. unidimensional) construct that either reduces or improves performance across the different dimensions of the manager’s work rather than differentiating between these dimensions (see Sect. 2.1.2; e.g. Chang and Wong 2003; Dicke and Ott 2002, p. 468; Fox and Hamilton 1994, p. 74; He et al. 2009; Spremann 1987, p. 18; Vargas Sánchez 2005, p. 19; Xu et al. 2005). In contrast, by using the counter example of plant managers in China, this study has empirically found that managers may use discretion differently to impact on performance depending on the dimension of their work in which discretion is granted (see Sect. 6.2.1). E.g. in average-sized multinationals, granting discretion to plant managers raises performance in the area of capital investments but reduces performance in the dimension of hiring workers.

  23. 23.

    As described in Sect. 2.1.2, most empirical studies have assumed that discretion is unidimensional in the sense that discretion (across multiple areas of the manager’s work) can be measured overall by a single construct, which then is expected to either increase, not alter, or decrease performance.

  24. 24.

    As explained in Sect. 2.1.2, only a small minority of studies have treated discretion as multidimensional, assuming that multiple constructs are needed to represent discretion overall (across multiple domains of the manager’s work) and that single constructs can only meaningfully represent a specific dimension of discretion.

  25. 25.

    Acemoglu et al. (2007) measure autonomy for British firms only in the domain of employment decisions and autonomy for French firms only in the domain of investment decisions in two out of their three datasets.

  26. 26.

    For instance, Caza (2007, pp. 14–16) combines indicators on the manager’s discretion in training resources, hiring, firing, and assigning specific tasks into a unidimensional discretion construct to investigate its impact on performance, although he later finds that discretion covers multiple dimensions (pp. 26–82).

  27. 27.

    For example, Agarwal et al. (2009, p. 2221) proxy managerial discretion by the length of lockup, notice, and redemption periods for the hedge funds under investigation.

  28. 28.

    For example, Venaik’s (1999) construct aims to represent discretion in marketing decisions.

  29. 29.

    Xiaoyang Li (2007) uses separate constructs for investment decision discretion and labour decision discretion.

  30. 30.

    Thomas and Peyrefitte (1996) investigate the impact of discretion on performance using Finkelstein and Hambrick’s (1990) industry-level discretion, which has been further advanced in subsequent studies (e.g. Abrahamson and Hambrick 1997; Datta et al. 2003; Hambrick and Abrahamson 1995; Hambrick et al. 1993; Keegan 2006; Keegan and Kabanoff 2008).

  31. 31.

    Either direct indicator(s) within one dimension of discretion to represent one specific dimension of discretion or direct indicators across several dimensions of discretion separated into multiple discretion constructs.

  32. 32.

    The study’s influences on managers in Table 7.2 (e.g. firm type) are only examples of the realm of influences, which are specified more fully in the study’s general theoretical discretion model in Fig. 4.4 in Sect. 4.1.2.

  33. 33.

    E.g. Table 7.2 shows that hiring discretion hardly impacts on performance in average-sized Chinese firms but reduces performance in multinationals, suggesting that firm type influences discretion’s impact on performance. As explained in Box 2.6 in Sect. 2.4.2, this might be due to cultural and management philosophy differences (e.g. Aminpour and Woetzel 2006, pp. 46–47; Hanne Chen 2004, p. 128; Crossland and Hambrick 2007, p. 14; Hexter 2006, pp. 4–6; Hexter and Woetzel 2007a, p. 4; Hoover 2006, p. 92; McGregor 2005, pp. 273–274). Section 6.2.3 finds that firm size can also influence the impact of discretion on performance.

  34. 34.

    E.g. with hiring discretion not significantly altering performance in Chinese firms but reducing it in multinationals (see Table 7.2), a research design that fails to differentiate between these firm types could arbitrarily estimate either an insignificant or negative overall impact of hiring discretion on performance, depending on the sample’s composition (i.e. whether the influences of Chinese firms or multinationals predominate).

  35. 35.

    Section 4.1.2 has presented the general theoretical discretion model in Fig. 4.4, which includes various influences on managers derived from principal-agent theory (see Table 2.9 in Sect. 2.3.2.2; e.g. Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Cheng et al. 2006; Davis et al. 1997b; Eisenhardt 1989; Fama and Jensen 1983b; Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007; Jensen and Meckling 1976; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Wang et al. 2008; Zhang and Li 2008b) and stewardship theory (see Sect. 2.3.3.2; e.g. Argyris 1973a, b; Brown 1969; Caza 2007; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 27–43; French and Raven 1959; Gibson et al. 1991; Hofstede 1980, 1991; Katz and Kahn 1978; Khanchel 2009, p. 98; Lane et al. 1999, p. 1079; Lawler 1986, 1992; Maslow 1970; McGregor 1960; Mills and Keast 2009; Simon 1957a, b; Triandis 1990, 1995; Triandis et al. 1993; Turner 1981; Van Slyke 2007, p. 164; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005; Walton 1980, 1985).

  36. 36.

    In the above example where sales & marketing discretion has a positive impact in small Chinese firms but a negative impact in large Chinese firms, a research design failing to granularly differentiate by firm size might find a positive impact if its sample focused on small firms and a negative impact if it focused on large firms.

  37. 37.

    Section 2.2.3 has explained that the unit of analysis has varied across studies in terms of influences on managers and that these studies have rarely differentiated their research designs by these influences (e.g. Adams et al. 2005; Agarwal et al. 2009; Barnabas and Mekoth 2010; Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003, 2004; Huiyuan Chen 2006; Cheng et al. 2006; Crossland and Hambrick 2007; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Groves et al. 1994; He et al. 2009; Heinecke 2011; Khanchel 2009; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Yougen Li and Zhao 2004; López-Navarro and Camisón-Zornoza 2003; Ongore 2011; Stano 1976; Tang 2008; Thomas and Peyrefitte 1996; Venaik 1999; Walters 1995; Wang et al. 2008; Werner and Tosi 1995; Williamson 1963; Xu et al. 2005; Yan et al. 2010; Zhang and Li 2008b; Zhang and Xie 2008; Zhang 1997; Zhao et al. 2010).

  38. 38.

    This is the multi-group comparison approach for testing moderating effects (see Sect. 4.3.1; e.g. Arnold 1982; Henseler and Fassott 2010, pp. 719–721; Rigdon et al. 1998, p. 1; Venkatraman 1989, p. 426).

  39. 39.

    This is the product term approach for testing moderating effects (see Sect. 4.3.1; e.g. Carte and Russell 2003, pp. 480–495; Chin et al. 2003, pp. 196–200; Irwin and McClelland 2001, p. 105). The relationship between the multi-group comparison approach and the product term approach was discussed in Sect. 2.2.4. Moreover, this study has explained how the product term approach (i.e. ‘Moderators’) can be combined with the multi-group comparison approach (i.e. ‘Grouping’) to test for three-way interaction (see Box 2.2 in Sect. 2.3.2.2; e.g. Henseler and Fassott 2010, p. 722) and thereby establish that e.g. firm size amplifies capital investment discretion’s positive performance impact in Chinese firms but dampens it in multinationals.

  40. 40.

    For instance, scholars could tailor the model to alternative units of analysis (e.g. sales managers in Germany), investigate other dimensions of discretion, and examine other influences on managers than those analysed in the present study (e.g. as taken from the general theoretical discretion model in Fig. 4.4 in Sect. 4.1.2).

  41. 41.

    This is possible due to the sample’s strong statistical representativeness (see Sect. 5.5; e.g. Fogiel 2000, pp. 158–160; Garson 2002, pp. 139–196; Gliner and Morgan 2000, p. 148; Wooldridge 2002, pp. 298–299).

  42. 42.

    The empirical discretion model’s system of multiple structural equations in vector/matrix notation can be tailored to an arbitrary number of dimensions of discretion and influences on managers, and the comparative statics and hypothesis tests can be specified to cater for alternative research objectives. E.g. the model can be harnessed to evaluate the total impact of firm size or any other antecedent on any type of discretion and on performance. For deriving the comparative statics, the appropriate structural equation in Box 4.6 (see Sect. 4.3.1) is simply differentiated partially with respect to the construct of interest, such as firm size. As shown in Equation (6.1) in Sect. 6.1, this yields an expression of the total ceteris paribus impact of e.g. firm size on performance as a combination of various effects. Such a comparative static can be used (as Sect. 6.1 shows) to investigate whether e.g. greater firm size incites top management to grant more capital investment discretion to plant managers, who in turn utilise this greater latitude of action in a performance-enhancing manner, in which case part of the better performance in larger firms would be mediated via managerial discretion. Moreover, future research can model other moderating or control effects than the ones in this study. E.g. the moderating effects of industry technology intensity (\( {A_1} \)) can be modelled by not constraining the respective moderating effect parameters (\( {m_{1,1 }} \) to \( {m_{4,1 }} \)) in the matrix \( \mathbf{m} \) in Equation (4.24) in Sect. 4.3.1 to be zero. Likewise, one might control for other confounding factors—either by including more control variables in the vectors \( \mathrm{ A} \) and \( \mathrm{ c} \) or by including them as grouping variables for multi-group comparisons (cf. firm type).

  43. 43.

    Scholars may also choose to harness the comprehensive assessment system for other partial least squares (PLS) models and potentially even tailor the output of PLS software packages (see Sect. 5.1.1) to report in the structure of this new holistic cascading hierarchy of evaluation criteria, assessment tests, and thresholds.

  44. 44.

    For example, as described in Box 7.2, scholars can examine how antecedents (e.g. firm size) affect a manager’s discretion and how they affect performance via a variety of channels, such as by inciting top management to adjust the granular mix of managerial discretion granted (see Equation (6.1) in Sect. 6.1). Future studies can also test the impact of discretion on organisational outcomes other than performance, given that discretion might significantly affect managerial power (Carpenter and Golden 1997), managerial compensation (Finkelstein and Boyd 1998; Magnan and St-Onge 1997; Rajagopalan and Finkelstein 1992; Werner and Tosi 1995; Wright and Kroll 2002; Zhang and Xie 2008), workers’ incentives (Groves et al. 1994), a successor chief executive officer’s age (Wang 2009), top management team tenure, trust (Perrone et al. 2003), strategic attention (Abrahamson and Hambrick 1997), environmental commitment (Aragon-Correa et al. 2004), pricing (Cameron 2000), organisational knowledge creation (Oh 2002), and research and development (Zhang et al. 2006a, b).

  45. 45.

    In addition, theories might help scholars determine which degree of granularity is appropriate for future empirical research to build a consistent granular landscape similar to that in Table 7.2 (see Sect. 7.4.3).

  46. 46.

    Both principal-agent theory and stewardship theory as well as many empirical studies in the extant literature have tended to treat discretion as unidimensional (i.e. as having a single overall performance impact) rather than treating it granularly (i.e. differentiating between multiple distinct dimensions of discretion; see Sect. 2.1.2; e.g. Barnabas and Mekoth 2010; Bloom et al. 2008; Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Cheng et al. 2006; Dicke and Ott 2002, p. 468; Fox and Hamilton 1994, p. 74; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; He et al. 2009; Marin and Verdier 2006; Spremann 1987, p. 18; Vargas Sánchez 2005, p. 19; Xu et al. 2005).

  47. 47.

    The reader can find a thorough, in-depth literature review on the existing theories in Sect. 2.3 as well as empirical hypothesis tests on the theories’ applicability in Sect. 6.2.4.

  48. 48.

    In addition to the overall positive (stewardship theory) and negative (principal-agent theory) impact of discretion on performance, the theories specify moderating influences on managers that may affect the extent to which managers behave in a performance-enhancing versus performance-reducing way (see Sects. 2.3.2 and 2.3.3). These influences are further examined in the subsequent sections (see Sects. 7.4.2 and 7.4.3).

  49. 49.

    Since the final theory reviewed in Sect. 2.3.1, managerial discretion theory, does not specify the direction of discretion’s performance impact as either positive or negative, it does not explain discretion’s impact and makes no prediction that needs to be tested (e.g. Abrahamson and Hambrick 1997; Berman et al. 2005; Carpenter and Golden 1997; Caza 2007, 2011; Huiyuan Chen 2006; Crossland 2007; Crossland and Hambrick 2007; Datta et al. 2003; Finkelstein and Boyd 1998; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990; Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007; Haleblian and Finkelstein 1993; Hambrick and Abrahamson 1995; Hambrick and Finkelstein 1987; Hambrick et al. 1993; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007; Keegan 2006; Keegan and Kabanoff 2008; Key 2002; Yougen Li and Zhao 2004; Magnan and St-Onge 1997; Quigley and Hambrick 2009; Rajagopalan and Finkelstein 1992; Thomas and Peyrefitte 1996; Zhang and Li 2008b; Zhang et al. 2006a, b).

  50. 50.

    Principal-agent theory (e.g. Agrawal and Knoeber 1996; Baysinger and Butler 1985; Berger et al. 1997; Brush et al. 2000; Chang and Wong 2003; Childs and Mauer 2008; Denis et al. 1997; Eisenhardt 1989; Fama 1980; Fama and Jensen 1983a, b; He et al. 2009; Jensen 1986; Jensen and Meckling 1976; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Jensen and Ruback 1983; Laffont and Martimort 2002; Lang et al. 1995; Levinthal 1988; Ongore 2011; Shleifer and Vishny 1997; Spremann 1987; Thépot 2007; Thomsen and Pedersen 2000; Walters 1995; Wang et al. 2008; Weidenbaum and Jensen 1993; Werner and Tosi 1995, p. 1673; Xu et al. 2005; Zou 1989).

  51. 51.

    Stewardship theory (e.g. Albanese et al. 1997; Arthurs and Busenitz 2003; Corbetta and Salvato 2004; Davis et al. 1997a, b; Dicke and Ott 2002; Donaldson 1990; Donaldson and Davis 1989, 1991, 1993, 1994; Eddleston and Kellermanns 2007; Fox and Hamilton 1994; Lane et al. 1999; Liu and Cai 2004; Miller and Le Breton-Miller 2006; Mills and Keast 2009; Muth and Donaldson 1998; Salvato 2002; Tian and Lau 2001; Tosi et al. 2003; Van Slyke 2007; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005; Zahra 2003).

  52. 52.

    The geometric mean of the number of employees in mainland China in the study’s representative sample of 467 firms is approximately 800 employees for Chinese firms and 1,000 for multinationals (see Sect. 7.5.2).

  53. 53.

    The inapplicability of the theories is further exemplified by the insignificant performance impact of sales & marketing discretion in Table 7.2, which neither principal-agent theory nor stewardship theory predicts. Although principal-agent theory can be consistent with an insignificant impact in exceptional cases—i.e. when control mechanisms are so effective that they unhinge the theory’s assumptions (see Box 2.1 and Box 2.2 in Sect. 2.3.2.2; e.g. Agrawal and Knoeber 1996, p. 377; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 7)—the main prediction of principal-agent theory is that discretion decreases performance, i.e. has a significantly negative impact on performance (see Sect. 2.3.2; e.g. Caza 2007, p. 10; Caza 2011; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 7; Davis et al. 1997b, p. 38; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007, p. 4; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Zhao et al. 2010).

  54. 54.

    The Chinese firms investigated have between 150 and 5,000 employees in mainland China, whereas the multinationals employ between 200 and 5,000 employees in mainland China (see Box 7.4 in Sect. 7.5.2).

  55. 55.

    Future research might explore whether managers tend to consistently use their capital investment discretion to improve performance (as stewards) across studies and explore reasons why stewardship theory might apply.

  56. 56.

    These influences have been embedded into the study’s new discretion model (see Fig. 4.4 in Sect. 4.1.2). As these influences shift the manager’s natural predisposition to performance maximisation towards those of an agent (i.e. assumption 1: self-serving utility maximisation and assumption 4: less performance-maximising interests than the principal), the impact of discretion on performance becomes more negative. By contrast, as these influences shift towards stewardship (i.e. assumption 1: pro-organisational utility maximisation and assumption 4: equally or more performance-maximising interests than the principal), the impact of discretion on performance becomes more positive. These moderating influences on managers have been derived from a wide range of studies reviewed in section 2.3.3.2 (e.g. Argyris 1973a, b; Brown 1969; Caza 2007; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 27–43; French and Raven 1959; Gibson et al. 1991; Hofstede 1980, 1991; Katz and Kahn 1978; Khanchel 2009, p. 98; Lane et al. 1999, p. 1079; Lawler 1986, 1992; Maslow 1970; McGregor 1960; Mills and Keast 2009; Simon 1957a, b; Triandis 1990, 1995; Triandis et al. 1993; Turner 1981; Van Slyke 2007, p. 164; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005; Walton 1980, 1985).

  57. 57.

    Figure 6.9 in Sect. 6.2.4 visualises this on a calibrated scatter plot for average-sized firms, which measures performance (on the vertical axis) as a function of different dimensions of discretion (on the horizontal axis). According to the existing reconciliation, a sample might be dominated by agents (leading to a downwards-sloping negative impact of discretion), dominated by stewards (leading to an upwards-sloping positive impact) or similarly mixed between agents and stewards (leading to a horizontal insignificant impact of discretion). However, Fig. 6.9 reveals that the same sample of plant managers in the same average-sized Chinese firms and multinationals in China is dominated by significant agency behaviour (downwards-sloping line) in some dimensions of the manager’s work and by significant stewardship behaviour (upwards-sloping line) in others.

  58. 58.

    See Sects. 2.1.2 and 2.3.3.2 (e.g. Albanese et al. 1997, p. 610; Chang and Wong 2003; Davis et al. 1997a, p. 612, Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 27–43; Dicke and Ott 2002, p. 468; Fox and Hamilton 1994, p. 74; He et al. 2009; Lane et al. 1999, p. 1079; Spremann 1987, p. 18; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005, p. 19; Xu et al. 2005). Similarly, empirical studies in the existing literature have often modelled discretion as having a single overall impact on performance (see Sect. 2.1.2; e.g. Barnabas and Mekoth 2010; Bloom et al. 2008; Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Cheng et al. 2006; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Marin and Verdier 2006).

  59. 59.

    Although the reconciliation does not differentiate between dimensions of discretion, it allows a relationship between a principal and a manager to change over time (e.g. from agency to stewardship) and a principal to have stewardship relationships with some managers and agency relationships with others (Albanese et al. 1997, p. 610; Davis et al. 1997a, p. 612). However, this does not overcome the need to differentiate by dimension of discretion, since the observed stewardship behaviour for capital investments and agency behaviour for e.g. hiring were observed at the same point in time and relate to the same set of managers.

  60. 60.

    Studies often fail to differentiate by dimension of discretion and by influences on managers (see Sects. 1.1 and 2.2.3; e.g. Bowen et al. 2008; Chang and Wong 2003; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Groves et al. 1994; He et al. 2009; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Stano 1976; Venaik 1999; Werner and Tosi 1995; Zhang 1997).

  61. 61.

    In other words, whether managers use their discretion to improve performance (as stewards) or to reduce performance (as agents) may not only depend on various influences on managers (columns) that promote stewardship or agency behaviour but also may granularly depend on the dimension of discretion in which discretion is granted (rows; i.e. area of the manager’s work). Indeed, this study empirically confirms that the extent to which plant managers in China use their discretion more like stewards (i.e. performance-improving) or more like agents (i.e. performance-reducing) depends on the area of their work in which discretion is granted (i.e. dimension of discretion) and on influences on managers (e.g. firm type and firm size; see Sect. 6.2.4). As to dimensions of discretion, Sect. 6.2.1 has found that in average-sized firms, plant managers tend to use discretion for making capital investments in a significantly more performance-improving way (i.e. as in stewardship theory) than they do when using discretion for any other dimension investigated. As to influences on managers, Sects. 6.2.2 and 6.2.3 have established that the degree of performance-improving versus performance-reducing uses of discretion significantly differs between firm types and firm sizes in a granular way, as specified in the new discretion model (i.e. with three-way interaction; see Box 2.2 in Sect. 2.3.2.2; e.g. Henseler and Fassott 2010, p. 722). For instance, firm size amplifies capital investment discretion’s positive performance impact in Chinese firms but dampens it in multinationals.

  62. 62.

    See Sect. 2.3.1 (e.g. Adams et al. 2005; Crossland and Hambrick 2007; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990; Hambrick and Finkelstein 1987; Misangyi 2002; Quigley and Hambrick 2009; Tang 2008; Zhao et al. 2010).

  63. 63.

    Principal-agent theory predicts discretion’s performance impact to be mostly negative (e.g. Caza 2007, p. 10; Caza 2011; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 7; Davis et al. 1997b, p. 38; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007, p. 4; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Zhao et al. 2010); stewardship theory predicts it to be positive (e.g. Corbetta and Salvato 2004; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 25–26; Donaldson and Davis 1991, p. 52; Eddleston and Kellermanns 2007, p. 547; Khanchel 2009, pp. 98–99; Liu and Cai 2004, p. 4; Mills and Keast 2009, pp. 14–15; Tosi et al. 2003, p. 2054; Van Slyke 2007, pp. 165–167; Vargas Sánchez 2004, p. 3, 2005, pp. 18–19).

  64. 64.

    E.g. the same manager may be psychologically motivated to act as a steward in some dimensions of work (e.g. capital investments) and as an agent in other dimensions (e.g. hiring workers). Likewise, a manager enticed to diligently work as a steward in multiple dimensions of work might only have the ability to realise his/her performance-enhancing intentions in dimensions where he/she is well-versed (e.g. capital investments) but not in dimensions outside the scope of his/her core competences (e.g. sales & marketing activities). This might explain why the impact on performance in average-sized multinationals (see Table 7.2) is positive for capital investment discretion, negative for hiring discretion, and insignificant for sales & marketing discretion.

  65. 65.

    As explained in Sect. 7.4.2, principal-agent theory and stewardship theory tend to treat discretion as a unidimensional construct that respectively reduces and improves performance regardless of the area of the manager’s work in which it is granted (see Sect. 2.1.2; e.g. Chang and Wong 2003; Dicke and Ott 2002, p. 468; Fox and Hamilton 1994, p. 74; He et al. 2009; Spremann 1987, p. 18; Vargas Sánchez 2005, p. 19; Xu et al. 2005). The existing reconciliation of principal-agent theory and stewardship theory inherits this unidimensional view that a given manager behaves as either an agent or a steward at a given point in time across the various dimensions of his/her work (see Sect. 2.3.3.2; e.g. Albanese et al. 1997, p. 610; Davis et al. 1997a, p. 612; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 27–43; Lane et al. 1999, p. 1079; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005). As the multidimensionality of discretion was derived based on managerial discretion theory (see Sect. 2.1.2; e.g. Carpenter and Golden 1997, p. 195; Caza 2007, pp. 26–82; Chen 2006; Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007, p. 245; Hambrick and Abrahamson 1995, p. 1439; Hambrick and Finkelstein 1987, pp. 371–402; Hambrick et al. 1993, p. 409), one may view this extension of the existing reconciliation of principal-agent theory and stewardship theory as an integration of all three theories (as in the study’s new discretion model).

  66. 66.

    Based on the literature in Sect. 2.3.3.2 (e.g. Argyris 1973a, b; Brown 1969; Caza 2007; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 27–43; French and Raven 1959; Gibson et al. 1991; Hofstede 1980, 1991; Katz and Kahn 1978; Khanchel 2009, p. 98; Lane et al. 1999, p. 1079; Lawler 1986, 1992; Maslow 1970; McGregor 1960; Mills and Keast 2009; Simon 1957a, b; Triandis 1990, 1995; Triandis et al. 1993; Turner 1981; Van Slyke 2007, p. 164; Vargas Sánchez 2001, 2004, 2005; Walton 1980, 1985).

  67. 67.

    The study’s general theoretical discretion model synthesises these influences on managers into two distinct shapes at the top-left corner in Fig. 4.4 in Sect. 4.1.2. Influences in the upper shape moderate the direction of discretion’s impact on performance (i.e. positive or negative) and include compensation control mechanisms as well as the aforementioned psychological characteristics, situational characteristics, and expectations. Influences in the lower shape amplify or dampen this impact and include the nature of managerial activities, monitoring control mechanisms as well as ability, knowledge, and information (see Sect. 4.1.2). These influences can help explain differences by columns in the granular landscape of impacts of discretion in Table 7.2. E.g. among these influences on managers, differences in an organisation’s situational characteristics (e.g. management philosophy and cultural differences) between Chinese firms and multinationals might explain why plant managers tend to use hiring discretion to significantly reduce performance in average-sized multinationals but not in average-sized Chinese firms in Table 7.2 above (see Box 2.6 in Sect. 2.4.2).

  68. 68.

    E.g. a plant manager might view capital investments as an important means to improve performance and thus be motivated to diligently enhance performance when granted capital investment discretion (as in Table 7.2). Yet the same manager might derive greater satisfaction from using hiring discretion to fulfil a personal desire (e.g. leading a large factory or fulfilling social obligations in a ‘guanxi’ network by hiring acquaintances; e.g. Schramm and Taube 2003; Taube and Schramm 2006).

  69. 69.

    See Box 2.2 in Sect. 2.3.2.2 (e.g. Berger et al. 1997, p. 1411; Burkart et al. 1997, p. 705; Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 6; Eisenhardt 1989, p. 60; Fama and Jensen 1983b; Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007, pp. 237–243; Holmstrom 1979; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Levinthal 1988, p. 153; Rumelt 1984; Spremann 1987, pp. 10–11; Tirole 1988; Verhoest 2003, pp. 2–5; Wang et al. 2008; Werner and Tosi 1995, p. 1673).

  70. 70.

    Finally, one should note that compared with the existing theories, this approach has at least two advantages. First, it helps explain why a manager is not always a pure agent or a pure steward but rather might use discretion to reduce performance in certain dimensions of his/her work and to improve performance in other dimensions. Second, it helps explain why managers might use discretion to not affect performance. As Sect. 7.4.2 describes, a neutral impact of discretion (e.g. sales & marketing discretion) would need to be interpreted in existing theories as resulting from an insufficiently granular research design that mixes agents and stewards in a sample so that their negative and positive impacts statistically average out. This new approach still allows for such an explanation (i.e. when research designs do not fully distinguish between dimensions of discretion or influences on managers). Yet it also draws attention to the possibility that the individual manager might actually use discretion in a way that does not affect performance, which might occur if e.g. he/she has limited abilities (see above) or control mechanisms are completely effective (see Sect. 2.3.2, especially Box 2.1).

  71. 71.

    As explained in Sect. 7.6, the dimensions of discretion and influences on managers in Table 7.2 are only examples of the possible realm of relevant dimensions and influences by which scholars should differentiate. One may naturally believe that the accuracy of results increases with the degree of granularity adopted, so it remains to be determined what granularity degree is suitable for obtaining consistent findings across studies. Theoretical research can motivate which granular differentiation might be required (e.g. by ability, as in the preceding discussion). Empirical research can verify whether such differentiations between dimensions of discretion and influences on managers are necessary (i.e. reveal distinct impacts of discretion) or whether they can be aggregated. For instance, the study’s empirical tests in Sect. 6.2.1 have confirmed the need to separate dimensions of discretion, and the tests in Sects. 6.2.2 and 6.2.3 have underlined the need to distinguish between influences on managers (e.g. firm type and firm size). Existing empirical studies finding significant influences on managers that moderate discretion’s impact on performance can also give indications on what differentiations might be necessary, e.g. managerial experience (Caza 2007), managerial incentives (Cheng et al. 2006), top management pay gap (Zhang and Li 2008b), corporate control via performance monitoring, incentive systems, and social integration (Wang et al. 2008), export joint venture group composition (López-Navarro and Camisón-Zornoza 2003), and market competition (Zhao et al. 2010).

  72. 72.

    E.g. the same manager may be psychologically motivated to act as a steward in some dimensions of work (e.g. capital investments) and as an agent in other dimensions (e.g. hiring workers). Likewise, a manager enticed to diligently work as a steward in multiple dimensions of work might only have the ability to realise his/her performance-enhancing intentions in dimensions where he/she is well-versed (e.g. capital investments) but not in dimensions outside the scope of his/her core competences (e.g. sales & marketing activities). This might explain why the performance impact in average-sized multinationals (see Table 7.2) is positive for capital investment discretion, negative for hiring discretion, and insignificant for sales & marketing discretion.

  73. 73.

    According to stewardship theory, discretion tends to increase performance (see Sect. 2.3.3; e.g. Corbetta and Salvato 2004; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 25–26; Donaldson and Davis 1991, p. 52; Eddleston and Kellermanns 2007, p. 547; Khanchel 2009, pp. 98–99; Liu and Cai 2004, p. 4; Mills and Keast 2009, pp. 14–15; Tosi et al. 2003, p. 2054; Van Slyke 2007, pp. 165–167; Vargas Sánchez 2004, p. 3, 2005, pp. 18–19).

  74. 74.

    According to principal-agent theory, discretion tends to decrease performance (see Sect. 2.3.2; e.g. Caza 2007, p. 10; Caza 2011; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 7; Davis et al. 1997b, p. 38; Eisenhardt 1989; Fama 1980; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007, p. 4; Jensen and Meckling 1976; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Spremann 1987; Zhao et al. 2010).

  75. 75.

    See Sect. 1.1 on the discretion puzzle (e.g. Agarwal et al. 2009; Barnabas and Mekoth 2010; Caza 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Groves et al. 1994; He et al. 2009; Heinecke 2011; Khanchel 2009; Yougen Li and Zhao 2004; López-Navarro and Camisón-Zornoza 2003; Stano 1976; Venaik 1999; Williamson 1963; Xu et al. 2005).

  76. 76.

    The underlying indicator of capital investment discretion ranges from approximately zero to 600,000 USD (converted from RMB using purchasing power parity) in the sample of Chinese firms and from approximately zero to 1,000,000 USD in the sample of multinationals. For both Chinese firms and multinationals, the underlying indicators of hiring discretion, new product introduction discretion, and sales & marketing discretion range from scores of 1 to 5, where 1 indicates that all decisions are taken at corporate headquarters and 5 that the plant manager has the full discretion to make all the decisions (see Sect. 4.2.2).

  77. 77.

    E.g. in average-sized multinationals, performance is empirically predicted to fall by 0.23 standard deviations for every one standard deviation increase in hiring discretion—whether from a low to a medium level or from a medium to a high level of hiring discretion (see Chap. 6). The reason is that each discretion construct is modelled as having a constant linear effect on performance (see Sect. 4.3.1). It should be noted that as the construct of capital investment discretion (which has a constant linear effect on performance) logarithmically transforms the indicator of capital investment discretion, which is recorded as a monetary limit in USD (see Sect. 4.2.2), the plant manager’s capital investment discretion in USD has a diminishing effect on performance: Extending capital investment discretion from 1,000 USD to 10,000 USD (factor ten) is modelled as having the same performance impact as a rise from 10,000 USD to 100,000 USD (factor ten).

  78. 78.

    See Sects. 1.2, 5.4, and 7.6 (e.g. Caza 2007, p. 46; Corcoran 2001, p. 154; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990, p. 500; Galavan 2005, p. 174; Granger 1969; Grant and Rice 2007, p. 367; Keuzenkamp 2000, p. 261; Rosenbaum 1989, p. 341; Sánchez 2008, p. 5; Shaughnessy et al. 2005, p. 367; Simon 1954, pp. 477–478; Wagner 2002, pp. 287–292; Wald et al. 1988, p. 72).

  79. 79.

    Chapter 3 has meticulously specified the unit of analysis as (1) the plant manager (i.e. the most senior manager at a plant below the firm’s CEO in mainland China) (2) of small and medium-sized enterprises (i.e. firms with 150–5,000 employees in total in mainland China) (3) in the manufacturing sector (i.e. primary US SIC code from 20 to 39) (4) throughout mainland China (i.e. all of China excluding Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan) (5) in the latter half of 2007 (i.e. July to December 2007).

  80. 80.

    In fact, managerial discretion, industry technology intensity, and firm size alone explain nearly a third of the entire variation of performance among plant managers in Chinese firms and multinationals (see Sect. 5.1.2).

  81. 81.

    For plant managers in China, performance in Chinese firms is significantly higher in more technology-intensive industries (e.g. medical, precision, and optical instruments; Loschky 2008, p. 7) than in less technology-intensive industries (e.g. wood and products of wood and cork; Loschky 2008, p. 7).

  82. 82.

    While there is comparatively little evidence that the plant manager’s discretion systematically varies with industry technology intensity, significant evidence is found that Chinese firms in higher-technology industries tend to award lower new product introduction discretion, i.e. tend to take decisions for introducing new products at corporate headquarters in China instead of placing them at the discretion of their plant managers.

  83. 83.

    The representative sample of 467 Chinese firms and multinationals was collected using a standardised scoring system during 467 detailed ‘double-blind’ interviews with plant managers of approximately 45 min each by specially-trained native Chinese graduate students from top business schools (see Sects. 5.2 and 5.5).

  84. 84.

    See Sect. 7.5 (e.g. Grant 2006, pp. 24–25; Hexter and Woetzel 2007a, pp. 3–4, Hexter and Woetzel 2007b, pp. viii–xi; Lassen et al. 2009, pp. 20–22; Raes et al. 2011, p. 102; Rao and Rastogi 1997; Willcocks and Griffiths 2010, p. 177).

  85. 85.

    Given that managerial discretion measures the leeway of a manager to take action and therefore to influence performance, adjusting the discretion granted to middle managers is a potentially significant lever for top management to pull when managing their middle managers in China (see Sect. 2.1.1; e.g. Adams et al. 2005; Crossland and Hambrick 2007; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990; Hambrick and Finkelstein 1987; Misangyi 2002; Quigley and Hambrick 2009; Tang 2008; Zhao et al. 2010). In addition to discretion having a potentially important impact on performance, it has been empirically demonstrated that discretion may significantly affect managerial power (Carpenter and Golden 1997), managerial compensation (Finkelstein and Boyd 1998; Magnan and St-Onge 1997; Rajagopalan and Finkelstein 1992; Werner and Tosi 1995; Wright and Kroll 2002; Zhang and Xie 2008), workers’ incentives (Groves et al. 1994), a successor chief executive officer’s age (Wang 2009), top management team tenure, trust (Perrone et al. 2003), strategic attention (Abrahamson and Hambrick 1997), environmental commitment (Aragon-Correa et al. 2004), pricing (Cameron 2000), organisational knowledge creation (Oh 2002), and research and development (Zhang et al. 2006a, b).

  86. 86.

    As explained in Sect. 4.2.2, capital investment discretion is measured as the z-score of the natural logarithm of the maximum capital investment (as a monetary limit) that a given plant manager can undertake without prior authorisation from corporate headquarters in China.

  87. 87.

    This positive impact of capital investment discretion on performance (and the negative impacts of certain other dimensions of discretion; see Sect. 6.2.4) is not limited to the sample of 467 Chinese firms and multinationals but can indeed be generalised to the entire population of tens of thousands of relevant plant managers in China: There is a nearly 0 % chance (see the p-values in Table 6.6 in Sect. 6.2.4, i.e. 0.0000000001 % for Chinese firms and 0.02 % for multinationals) that capital investment discretion’s impact on performance as estimated in the sample (+0.40 for average-sized Chinese firms and +0.41 for average-sized multinationals) diverges from zero by as much as observed due to sampling error when the true population parameter is zero. In large Chinese firms (which are two standard deviations larger than average), the performance improvement is estimated to be even stronger: +0.64 standard deviations (see Sect. 6.2.3).

  88. 88.

    On the performance scale that assesses the extent to which the plant manager’s practices reflect best practices (see Sect. 4.2.1), a top-performing Chinese firm (i.e. third quartile) exceeds average performance by 0.82 standard deviations in the sample. Hence, improving performance by 0.4 standard deviations by extending capital investment discretion closes nearly half (\( 0.40/0.82\approx 0.5 \)) of the performance gap among Chinese firms.

  89. 89.

    The reader can also infer these results for average-sized firms from Fig. 7.4 below by checking whether the lines measuring discretion’s performance impact are positive, neutral or negative at average firm size (\( {A_2}=0 \)).

  90. 90.

    The horizontal axis gauges firm size (\( {A_2} \)) in terms of by how many standard deviations a firm exceeds average size. Firm size measures the z-score of the natural logarithm of the number of employees in mainland China in the firm in which the plant manager works (see Sect. 4.2.4). This includes employees at the firm’s plants in mainland China and at the firm’s other organisational entities in mainland China (e.g. corporate headquarters in mainland China) but excludes employees outside of mainland China. As the 5,000 employees threshold for the unit of analysis (see Chap. 3) refers to employees in mainland China, the implications apply to multinationals with an arbitrarily large number of employees outside of mainland China, provided they employed no more than 5,000 employees within mainland China at the time of investigation.

  91. 91.

    As explained in greater detail in Sect. 6.2.3, the vertical axis measures the impact of discretion on performance (\( {{{\partial P}} \left/ {{\partial {D_k}}} \right.} \)) in terms of by how many standard deviations performance changes as managerial discretion (\( {D_k} \)) is extended by one standard deviation. Using the example of average-sized Chinese firms from above, extending capital investment discretion (\( {D_1} \)) by one standard deviation (from e.g. 10,000 to 100,000 RMB) was found to improve performance by 0.40 (\( ={{{\partial P}} \left/ {{\partial {D_1}}} \right.} \)) standard deviations. This is precisely where the solid line (Chinese firms) crosses the vertical axis (\( {{{\partial P}} \left/ {{\partial {D_1}}} \right.} \)) at average firm size (\( {A_2}=0 \)) in the top left graph.

  92. 92.

    As the sample estimates may differ from the true population values by sampling error (see Sect. 4.3.3), practitioners are advised to conservatively view only strongly positive (e.g. at least \( +0.22 \)) and strongly negative (e.g. at most \( -0.22 \)) impacts in the sample as significant impacts in the population (see Box 7.4).

  93. 93.

    E.g. as inferences should be limited to the sample’s domain to avoid extrapolation, Chinese firms should have 150–5,000 employees in mainland China and multinationals 200–5,000 employees in mainland China.

  94. 94.

    E.g. when such influences as the manager’s ability are extremely weak or no monitoring control mechanisms are in place, then their moderating effects may be so strong that discretion’s impact on performance changes.

  95. 95.

    The underlying indicator of capital investment discretion ranges from approximately zero to 600,000 USD (converted from RMB using purchasing power parity) in the sample of Chinese firms and from approximately zero to 1,000,000 USD in the sample of multinationals. For both Chinese firms and multinationals, the underlying indicators of hiring discretion, new product introduction discretion, and sales & marketing discretion range from scores of 1 to 5, where 1 indicates that all decisions are taken at corporate headquarters and 5 that the plant manager has the full discretion to make all the decisions (see Sect. 4.2.2).

  96. 96.

    E.g. in average-sized multinationals, performance is empirically predicted to fall by 0.23 standard deviations for every one standard deviation increase in hiring discretion—whether from a low to a medium level or from a medium to a high level of hiring discretion (see Chap. 6). The reason is that each discretion construct is modelled as having a constant linear effect on performance (see Sect. 4.3.1). It should be noted that as the construct of capital investment discretion (which has a constant linear effect on performance) logarithmically transforms the indicator of capital investment discretion, which is recorded as a monetary limit in USD (see Sect. 4.2.2), the plant manager’s capital investment discretion in USD has a diminishing effect on performance: Extending capital investment discretion from 1,000 USD to 10,000 USD (factor ten) is modelled as having the same performance impact as a rise from 10,000 USD to 100,000 USD (factor ten).

  97. 97.

    Practitioners should thus bear in mind that instead of proving that granting plant managers more e.g. capital investment discretion will cause an improvement in performance, the results only establish that those firms granting more capital investment discretion tend to exhibit stronger performance than firms granting less capital investment discretion (see Sects. 1.2, 5.4, and 7.6; e.g. Caza 2007, p. 46; Corcoran 2001, p. 154; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990, p. 500; Galavan 2005, p. 174; Granger 1969; Grant and Rice 2007, p. 367; Keuzenkamp 2000, p. 261; Rosenbaum 1989, p. 341; Sánchez 2008, p. 5; Shaughnessy et al. 2005, p. 367; Simon 1954, pp. 477–478; Wagner 2002, pp. 287–292; Wald et al. 1988, p. 72).

  98. 98.

    In the study’s representative sample of 467 firms, the average-sized Chinese firm (defined by \( A_2^{Chinese }=0 \)) has approximately 800 employees in mainland China and the average-sized multinational (defined by \( A_2^{Multi. }=0 \)) has approximately 1,000 employees in mainland China. As \( {A_2} \) logarithmically transforms the number of employees (see Sect. 4.2.4), these average numbers of employees are geometric means. The arithmetic means are higher: approximately 1,100 employees for Chinese firms and 1,400 employees for multinationals, since before the logarithmic transformation the firm size distribution exhibits stronger positive skewness.

  99. 99.

    This includes employees at the firm’s plants in mainland China and at the firm’s other organisational entities in mainland China (e.g. corporate headquarters in China) but excludes employees outside of mainland China.

  100. 100.

    Assuming the impacts of discretion on performance (that combine direct and moderating effects in Fig. 7.4) have standard errors no larger than the largest standard error estimated in the sample for either direct effects or moderating effects (which is \(+0.13\)), then an estimated impact of discretion on performance of \(+0.22\) has a t-value of at least \(t=+0.22/+0.13=1.69\) (see Equation (4.46) in Sect. 4.3.3), which is significant at the 10 % level. The thresholds of \(+0.22\) and \(-0.22\) are therefore used as rough heuristics for significance.

  101. 101.

    E.g. finding a strongly positive impact of capital investment discretion on performance (e.g. \(+0.64\)) would suggest that practitioners should extend their plant managers’ managerial discretion for capital investments.

  102. 102.

    As explained in Chap. 2, principal-agent theory (see Sect. 2.3.2) and stewardship theory (see Sect. 2.3.3) have tended to treat discretion as a single overall construct that either reduces performance and thus should be constrained (in principal-agent theory) or improves performance and thus should be extended (in stewardship theory; see Sect. 2.1.2; e.g. Chang and Wong 2003; Dicke and Ott 2002, p. 468; Fox and Hamilton 1994, p. 74; He et al. 2009; Spremann 1987, p. 18; Vargas Sánchez 2005, p. 19; Xu et al. 2005). Likewise, empirical studies in the existing literature have often modelled discretion as having a single overall impact on performance (e.g. Barnabas and Mekoth 2010; Bloom et al. 2008; Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Cheng et al. 2006; Gammelgaard et al. 2010; Marin and Verdier 2006).

  103. 103.

    This was formally established by testing Hypothesis 1 in Sect. 6.2.1 for the counter example of plant managers in China, where significant differences in the impact on performance were observed by dimension of discretion. E.g. in average-sized Chinese firms, a plant manager’s capital investment discretion has a positive impact on performance but new product introduction discretion has a negative impact (see Sect. 7.5.2).

  104. 104.

    As formally tested in terms of Hypothesis 2 in Sect. 6.2.2 and as depicted in Fig. 7.4 in Sect. 7.5.2, the success factor of managerial discretion can have significantly different impacts on performance in Chinese firms versus multinationals and thus needs to be adjusted in different ways. Hiring discretion, for example, is only found to significantly reduce performance in average-sized multinationals but not in average-sized Chinese firms, which implies that the best practice to constrain hiring discretion in these multinationals cannot be expected to enhance performance in average-sized Chinese firms. Likewise, capital investment discretion significantly improves performance and thus ought to be extended in large Chinese firms but not in large multinationals. This study’s findings even suggest that among large companies, sales & marketing discretion strengthens performance and thus should be extended in multinationals but harms performance and thus should be constrained in Chinese firms (see Sect. 7.5.2).

  105. 105.

    These influences on the manager may play a role in determining the extent to which best practices on harnessing the success factor of managerial discretion can be exchanged between Chinese firms and multinationals. They were derived from the literature and embodied in the study’s new general theoretical discretion model (see Fig. 4.4 in Sect. 4.1.2 and Box 2.6 in Sect. 2.4.2). E.g. the organisation’s situational characteristics (i.e. management philosophy and cultural differences) may differ between Chinese firms and multinationals (e.g. Aminpour and Woetzel 2006, pp. 46–47; Hanne Chen 2004, p. 128; Crossland and Hambrick 2007, p. 14; Hexter 2006, pp. 4–6; Hexter and Woetzel 2007a, p. 4; Hoover 2006, p. 92; McGregor 2005, pp. 273–274), which stewardship theorists have argued to affect the extent to which managers use their discretion to positively rather than negatively affect performance (see Sect. 2.3.3.2; e.g. Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 32–43; Lawler 1986, 1992; Triandis 1990, 1995; Triandis et al. 1993; Van Slyke 2007, p. 164; Vargas Sánchez 2004; Walton 1980, 1985). Similarly, with different types of firms attracting different people, the psychological characteristics and expectations that stewardship theorists have argued to influence how managers use discretion might differ between Chinese firms and multinationals (see Sect. 2.3.3.2; e.g. Argyris 1973a; b; Brown 1969; Caza 2007; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 38–43; French and Raven 1959; Gibson et al. 1991; Katz and Kahn 1978; Khanchel 2009, p. 98; Maslow 1970; McGregor 1960; Mills and Keast 2009; Simon 1957a, b; Turner 1981; Van Slyke 2007; Vargas Sánchez 2004, pp. 4–5, 2005, pp. 24–25). In addition, Chinese firms and multinationals might differ in terms of their compensation control mechanisms, which can moderate the impact of discretion on performance in principal-agent theory (see Sect. 2.3.2; e.g. Agrawal and Knoeber 1996, p. 378; Berger et al. 1997, p. 1411; Burkart et al. 1997, p. 705; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 6; Cheng et al. 2006; Eisenhardt 1989, p. 60; Fama and Jensen 1983a, p. 345; Jensen and Meckling 1976; Jensen and Murphy 1990, p. 226; Levinthal 1988, p. 153; Spremann 1987, p. 10; Wang et al. 2008; Werner and Tosi 1995, p. 1673; Zhang and Li 2008b).

  106. 106.

    Box 2.6 in Sect. 2.4.2 gives a potential explanation for why firm size can moderate discretion’s impact on performance. E.g. firm size might affect monitoring control mechanisms, which aim to reduce the principal’s asymmetry of information regarding the manager’s actions and thus aim to improve the impact of discretion on performance (see Sect. 2.3.2; e.g. Berger et al. 1997, p. 1411; Burkart et al. 1997, p. 705; Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 6; Eisenhardt 1989, p. 60; Fama and Jensen 1983b; Levinthal 1988, p. 153; Spremann 1987, pp. 10–11; Verhoest 2003, pp. 2–5; Wang et al. 2008; Werner and Tosi 1995, p. 1673). In particular, Caza (2007, pp. 12–20) argues that a larger firm with multiple units (here plants) that are similar to that led by the (plant) manager under consideration provide the principal with more informational benchmarks to assess the (plant) manager’s performance and thus potentially constrain his/her misconduct.

  107. 107.

    Furthermore, as firm size expands, the impact of capital investment discretion on performance becomes more positive among Chinese firms and less positive among multinationals (see Hypothesis 3 in Sect. 6.2.3).

  108. 108.

    In addition to firm size, the general theoretical discretion model derived in Sect. 4.1.2 (see Fig. 4.4) presents other possible influences on managers that may alter the impact of discretion on performance over time and thus should be monitored for changes that may require practitioners to adjust the discretion mix granted. E.g. as the practitioner’s assessment of the manager’s ability and the extent to which the manager can be trusted evolve over time, the impact of discretion on performance may change (see Box 2.4 in Sect. 2.3.3.2 and Sect. 4.1.2; e.g. Caza 2007, 2011; Chang and Wong 2003; Davis et al. 1997b, pp. 23–43; Xiaoyang Li 2007; Mills and Keast 2009; Van Slyke 2007; Vargas Sánchez 2004, pp. 4–5, 2005, pp. 24–25). Practitioners are therefore advised to examine whether these influences in the general theoretical discretion model have undergone changes in their company and accordingly adjust the discretion granted over time.

  109. 109.

    E.g. the positive impact of capital investment discretion and the negative impact of hiring discretion could average out to a positive, neutral or negative overall impact on performance in a non-granular research design.

  110. 110.

    E.g. hiring discretion’s impact on performance is negative in multinationals but insignificant in Chinese firms.

  111. 111.

    This can be achieved by postulating that the influences on managers in the study’s new discretion model (see Sect. 7.2) which entice them to behave in performance-reducing ways (as agents) or performance-enhancing ways (as stewards) differ between the dimensions of the manager’s work (see Sect. 7.4.3). For example, the same manager may be psychologically inclined to act as a steward in some dimensions of work (e.g. capital investments) and as an agent in other dimensions (e.g. hiring workers). Likewise, a manager enticed to diligently work as a steward in multiple dimensions of work might only have the ability to realise his/her performance-enhancing intentions in dimensions where he/she is well-versed (e.g. capital investments) but not in dimensions outside the scope of his/her core competences (e.g. sales & marketing activities). This might explain why the performance impact in average-sized multinationals (see Table 7.2) is positive for capital investment discretion, negative for hiring discretion, and insignificant for sales & marketing discretion.

  112. 112.

    The tool kit allows scholars to rapidly tailor the new discretion model to various units of analysis (e.g. R&D managers in India or top management in the United States) and various research objectives (e.g. investigating how antecedents affect discretion and thereby performance). It comprises a general version of the new discretion model in graphical and mathematical terms, corresponding measurement and structural models, a new assessment system for validity and reliability, and tutorial examples on how to apply and interpret the model.

  113. 113.

    These limitations are based on the delimitations of the research objective (see Box 1.1 in Sect. 1.2) as well as the caveats involved in drawing conclusions for practitioners (which Sects. 7.5 and 7.5.2 describe in detail).

  114. 114.

    For instance, scholars might extend the study’s granularity by dimensions of discretion to the dimensions of performance. If discretion improves some dimensions of performance but reduces others, then the different unidimensional performance measures in the literature might tap into different dimensions of performance and thus reveal different positive, neutral, and negative impacts of discretion. Indeed, e.g. Khanchel (2009) and Wang et al. (2008) find a positive impact of discretion on some performance measures but a neutral or negative impact on other performance measures. Another extension to be explored is that discretion’s performance impact might be inversed U-shaped rather than linear (e.g. Huiyuan Chen 2006; Zhang and Li 2008b), so linear impacts might turn out positive if studies focused on lower levels of discretion and negative if they focused on higher levels. Section 7.5 accounts for this possibility by warning practitioners not to extend discretion beyond the study’s specific domain of discretion (e.g. beyond 1,000,000 USD of capital investment discretion in multinationals).

  115. 115.

    For plant managers of small and medium-sized enterprises in the manufacturing sector throughout mainland China in the latter half of 2007 (see Chap. 3).

  116. 116.

    These four dimensions of discretion include capital investment discretion, hiring discretion, new product introduction discretion, and sales & marketing discretion (see Sect. 4.2.2).

  117. 117.

    As noted above, this might be achieved by synchronising future empirical and theoretical research using the new discretion model in an effort to uncover a consistent granular landscape (see Table 7.2 and Sect. 7.4.3). As to the dimensions of discretion, it might then be found that additional dimensions are required (e.g. strategy discretion), that the existing dimensions need to be further differentiated (e.g. hiring shop-floor workers versus hiring supervisors) or that dimensionality is not best distinguished between the areas of work (but rather between e.g. work that is easy to monitor versus hard to monitor). As to influences on managers, one might investigate further influences (e.g. industry, region or ability; see the new discretion model in Sect. 4.1.2) or further differentiate existing influences (e.g. multinationals in firm type by country of origin or by underlying differences in management philosophy) so as to obtain the appropriate degree of granularity.

  118. 118.

    The model fulfils every assessment test of statistical conclusion validity, reliability, construct validity, internal validity, and external validity, even when faced with particularly conservative thresholds from the literature.

  119. 119.

    The dynamics of discretion (i.e. the analysis of discretion over time, such as differentiating between short-term and long-term effects) have been kept out of the scope of the research objective (see Sect. 1.2). Nonetheless, this study advises future studies to explore the dynamics of discretion, given that the dynamics are at an early stage of research in the literature (e.g. Finkelstein and Peteraf 2007, pp. 243–245; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007, p. 1; Kayhan 2008, pp. 1–6) and the study’s findings underline their potential importance: E.g. Sect. 7.5.3 establishes that practitioners might need to adjust the discretion granted over time so as to achieve the full potential performance benefits from harnessing the success factor of managerial discretion.

  120. 120.

    First, introducing all necessary controls is a prerequisite for establishing that an association is causal rather than spurious, but can generally not be achieved in practice (e.g. Bachman and Schutt 2010, p. 170; Corcoran 2001, p. 154; Davis 1985, pp. 63–64; Galavan 2005, p. 174; Grant and Rice 2007, p. 367; Hanssens et al. 2003, p. 298; Hellevik 1988, p. 38; Jaccard and Turrisi 2003, pp. 1–2; Jackman 1975, p. 182; Keuzenkamp 2000, p. 261; Rosenbaum 1989, p. 341; Sánchez 2008, p. 5; Shaughnessy et al. 2005, p. 367; Simon 1954, pp. 477–478; Wald et al. 1988, p. 72). This study has successfully introduced relevant controls to remedy spurious effects and has established robustness to further controls (see Sects. 5.4.1 and 5.4.3). Second, even after including all relevant controls, the direction of causality (e.g. from discretion to performance) cannot be empirically verified in observational cross-sectional studies (e.g. Caza 2007, p. 46; Finkelstein and Hambrick 1990, p. 500; Wagner 2002, pp. 287–292). To mitigate this threat to internal validity (see Sect. 5.4), this study has carefully scrutinised the theoretical mechanisms suggested in the literature, which support the direction of causality to run from discretion to performance (see Sects. 2.3.2 on principal-agent theory and 2.3.3 on stewardship theory). Nevertheless, it cannot be ruled out that past performance can also affect the levels of discretion granted, thereby potentially introducing reverse causality with feedback (e.g. Bloom and Van Reenen 2007, p. 1375; Chang and Wong 2003, p. 22; Glaister et al. 2003, p. 316; Hutzschenreuter and Kleindienst 2007; Walters 1995).

  121. 121.

    E.g. instead of proving that granting plant managers more capital investment discretion will cause an improvement in performance, the results only establish that those firms granting more capital investment discretion tend to exhibit stronger performance than those firms granting less capital investment discretion.

References

  • A.O. Smith Corporation: Gongchang jingli zhiwei miaoshu [Plant manager job description]. http://www.aosmith.com.cn/business/joinus/SRDutyDes.aspx?id=972 (2011). Accessed 04 March 2011

  • Abrahamson, E., Hambrick, D.C.: Attentional homogeneity in industries: the effect of discretion. J. Organ. Behav. 18, 513–532 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., Lelarge, C., Van Reenen, J., Zilibotti, F.: Technology, information, and the decentralization of the firm. Q. J. Econ. 122(4), 1759–1799 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, R.B., Almeida, H., Ferreira, D.: Powerful CEOs and Their Impact on Corporate Performance. Rev. Financ. Stud. 18(4), 1403–1432 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Agarwal, V., Daniel, N.D., Naik, N.Y.: Role of managerial incentives and discretion in hedge fund performance. J. Finance 64(5), 2221–2256 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal, A., Knoeber, C.R.: Firm performance and mechanisms to control agency problems between managers and shareholders. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 31(3), 377–397 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  • Albanese, R., Dacin, M.T., Harris, I.C.: Agents as Stewards. Acad. Manag. Rev. 22(3), 609–611 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Aminpour, S., Woetzel, J.R.: Applying lean manufacturing in China. The McKinsey Quarterly, 2006 Special Edition: Serving the New Chinese Consumer, pp. 40–49. (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Aragon-Correa, J.A., Matías-Reche, F., Senise-Barrio, M.E.: Managerial discretion and corporate commitment to the natural environment. J. Bus. Res. 57(9), 964–975 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Argyris, C.: Organization man: rational and self-actualizing. Publ. Admin. Rev. 33, 354–357 (1973a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Argyris, C.: Some limits of rational man organizational theory. Publ. Admin. Rev. 33, 253–267 (1973b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, H.J.: Moderator variables: a clarification of conceptual, analytic, and psychometric issues. Organ. Behav. Hum. Perform. 29(2), 143–174 (1982)

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthurs, J.D., Busenitz, L.W.: The boundaries and limitations of agency theory and stewardship theory in the venture capitalist/entrepreneur relationship. Entrepren. Theor. Pract. 28(2), 145–162 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bachman, R., Schutt, R.K.: The Practice of Research in Criminology and Criminal Justice, 4th edn. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnabas, N., Mekoth, N.: Autonomy, market orientation and performance in Indian retail banking. Asia Pac. J. Market. Logist. 22(3), 330–350 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Baysinger, B.D., Butler, H.N.: Corporate governance and the board of directors: performance effects of changes in board composition. J. Law Econ. Organ. 1(1), 101–124 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, P.G., Ofek, E., Yermack, D.L.: Managerial entrenchment and capital structure decisions. J. Finance 52(4), 1411–1438 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman, S.L., Phillips, R.A., Wicks, A.C.: Resource dependence, managerial discretion and stakeholder performance. Paper presented at the Academy of Management Annual Meeting Proceedings, Honolulu, HI (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Blomström, M., Kokko, A.: Multinational corporations and spillovers. J. Econ. Surv. 12(3), 247–277 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., Van Reenen, J.: Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. Q. J. Econ. 122(4), 1351–1408 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., Dorgan, S., Dowdy, J., Van Reenen, J.: Management practice and productivity: why they matter. McKinsey & Company Operations Extranet. http://www.mckinsey.it/storage/first/uploadfile/attach/140062/file/management_practice.pdf (2007). Accessed 27 June 2011

  • Bloom, N., Sadun, R., Van Reenen, J.: Measuring and Explaining Decentralization Across Firms and Countries. Centre for Economic Performance (CEP), London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, R.M., Rajgopal, S., Venkatachalam, M.: Accounting discretion, corporate governance, and firm performance. Contemp. Account. Res. 25(2), 351–405 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M.E.: Identification and some conditions of organizational involvement. Adm. Sci. Q. 14(346–355) (1969)

    Google Scholar 

  • Brush, T.H., Bromiley, P., Hendrickx, M.: The free cash flow hypothesis for sales growth and firm performance. Strateg. Manag. J. 21(4), 455–472 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P.J., Clegg, J., Wang, C.: The impact of inward FDI on the performance of Chinese manufacturing firms. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 33(4), 637–655 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Burkart, M., Gromb, D., Panunzi, F.: Large shareholders, monitoring, and the value of the firm. Q. J. Econ. 112(3), 693–728 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, L.J.: Limiting buyer discretion: effects on performance and price in long-term contracts. Am. Econ. Rev. 90(1), 265–281 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • CareerStrides: Plant manager resume sample. http://www.careerstrides.com/resume_samples7.html (2011). Accessed 04 March 2011

  • Carpenter, M.A., Golden, B.R.: Perceived managerial discretion: a study of cause and effect. Strateg. Manag. J. 18(3), 187–206 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Carte, T.A., Russell, C.J.: In pursuit of moderation: nine common errors and their solutions. MIS Q. 27(3), 479–501 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Caza, A.J.: Three papers on managerial discretion. Business administration and psychology. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis. University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Caza, A.J.: Testing alternate predictions for the performance consequences of middle managers’ discretion. Hum. Resour. Manag. 50(1), 9–28 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaganti, R.S., Mahajan, V., Sharma, S.: Corporate board size, composition and corporate failures in retailing industry. J. Manag. Stud. 22(4), 400–417 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E.C., Wong, S.M.L.: Managerial discretion and firm performance in China’s listed firms. Working Paper 1036, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E.C., Wong, S.M.L.: Political control and performance in China’s listed firms. J. Comp. Econ. 32(4), 617–636 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, H.: KulturSchock China: VR China/Taiwan. Reise Know-How Verlag Peter Rump, Bielefeld, Germany (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, H.: Tantao jingli zizhuquan dui shangshi gongsi jixiao de yinxiang [Examining the Influence of Managerial Discretion on the Performance of Listed Companies]. Zhejiang daxue [Zhejiang University], Hangzhou, China (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, H., Hsiao, C., Nugent, J.B., Qiu, J.: Managerial autonomy, contractual incentives and productivity in a transition economy. Pac. Econ. Rev. 11(3), 341–361 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Child, J., Rodrigues, S.B.: The internationalization of Chinese firms: a case for theoretical extension? Manag. Organ. Rev. 1(3), 381–410 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Childs, P.D., Mauer, D.C.: Managerial discretion, agency costs, and capital structure. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1108218 (2008). Accessed 02 Dec 2008

  • Chin, W.W., Marcolin, B.L., Newsted, P.R.: A partial least squares latent variable modeling approach for measuring interaction effects: results from a Monte Carlo simulation study and an electronic-mail emotion/adoption study. Inf. Syst. Res. 14(2), 189–217 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M.G., Delmastro, M.: Delegation of authority in business organizations: an empirical test. J. Ind. Econ. 52(1), 53–80 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Corbetta, G., Salvato, C.: Self-serving or self-actualizing? Models of man and agency costs in different types of family firms: a commentary on ‘comparing the agency costs of family and non-family firms: conceptual issues and exploratory evidence’. Entrepren. Theor Pract. 28(4), 355–362 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Corcoran, M.: Mobility, persistence, and the consequences of poverty for children: child and adult outcomes. In: Danziger, S., Haveman, R.H. (eds.) Understanding Poverty, pp. 127–161. Russell Sage Foundation, New York, NY (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Crossland, C.: National Institutions and Managerial Discretion: A Taxonomy of 24 Countries. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the academy of management, Philadelphia, PA (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Crossland, C., Hambrick, D.C.: How national systems differ in their constraints on corporate executives: a study of CEO effects in three countries. Strateg. Manag. J. 28(8), 767–789 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Damewood, C.L: What Does a Plant Manager Do? http://www.wisegeek.com/what-does-a-plant-manager-do.htm (2010). Accessed 14 Aug 2010

  • Datta, D.K., Rajagopalan, N., Zhang, Y.: New CEO openness to change and strategic persistence: the moderating role of industry characteristics. Br. J. Manag. 14(2), 101–114 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J.A.: The Logic of Causal Order. Sage, Beverly Hills, CA (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J.H., Schoorman, F.D., Donaldson, L.: Davis, Schoorman, and Donaldson reply: The distinctiveness of agency theory and stewardship theory. Acad. Manag. Rev. 22(3), 611–613 (1997a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J.H., Schoorman, F.D., Donaldson, L.: Toward a stewardship theory of management. Acad. Manag. Rev. 22(3), 20–47 (1997b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H., Lehn, K.: The structure of corporate ownership: causes and consequences. J. Polit. Econ. 93(6), 1155–1177 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Denis, D.J., Denis, D.K., Sarin, A.: Agency problems, equity ownership, and corporate diversification. J. Finance 52(1), 135–160 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dicke, L.A., Ott, J.S.: A test: can stewardship theory serve as a second conceptual foundation for accountability methods in contracted human services? Int. J. Publ. Admin. 25(4), 463–487 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L.: The ethereal hand: organizational economics and management theory. Acad. Manag. Rev. 15(3), 369–381 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L., Davis, J.H: CEO governance and shareholder returns: agency theory or stewardship theory. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management, Washington, DC (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L., Davis, J.H.: Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and shareholder returns. Aust. J. Manag. 16(1), 49–64 (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L., Davis, J.H.: The need for theoretical coherence and intellectual rigour in corporate governance research: reply to critics of Donaldson and Davis. Aust. J. Manag. 18(2), 213–223 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L., Davis, J.H.: Boards and company performance—research challenges the conventional wisdom. Corp. Govern. Int. Rev. 2(3), 151–160 (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • Eddleston, K.A., Kellermanns, F.W.: Destructive and productive family relationships: a stewardship theory perspective. J. Bus. Ventur. 22(4), 545–565 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt, K.M.: Agency theory: an assessment and review. Acad. Manag. Rev. 14(1), 57–74 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, S., Gadiesh, O., DiPaola, P.: Multinationals can learn from Chinese companies. China Daily, 24 Jan 2007

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F.: Agency problems and the theory of the firm. J. Polit. Econ. 88(2), 288–307 (1980)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F., Jensen, M.C.: Agency problems and residual claims. J. Law Econ. 26(2), 327–349 (1983a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F., Jensen, M.C.: Separation of ownership and control. J. Law Econ. 26(2), 301–326 (1983b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, S., Boyd, B.K.: How much does the CEO matter? The role of managerial discretion in the setting of CEO compensation. Acad. Manage. J. 41(2), 179–199 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, S., Hambrick, D.C.: Top-management-team tenure and organizational outcomes: the moderating role of managerial discretion. Adm. Sci. Q. 35, 484–503 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, S., Peteraf, M.: Managerial activities: a missing link in managerial discretion theory. Strateg. Organ. 5(3), 237–248 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, M., Völckner, F., Sattler, H.: How important are brands? A cross-category, cross-country study. J. Market. Res. 47(5), 823–839 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogiel, M.: Statistics. Research & Education Association, Piscataway, NJ (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, M.A., Hamilton, R.T.: Ownership and diversification: agency theory or stewardship theory. J. Manag. Stud. 31(1), 69–81 (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • French, J.R.P., Raven, B.: The bases of social power. In: Cartwright, D. (ed.) Studies in Social Power, pp. 150–167. University of Michigan Institute for Social Research, Ann Arbor, MI (1959)

    Google Scholar 

  • Galavan, R.: Exploring the belief systems of senior managers: antecedents of managerial discretion. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, School of Management, Cranfield University, Cranfield, UK (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gammelgaard, J., McDonald, F., Stephan, A., Tüselmann, H., Dörrenbächer, C.: Performance Effects of Subsidiary Developments in Collaboration, and Decision Making Power (CIBEM Working Paper). Department of International Economics and Management, Copenhagen Business School, Frederiksberg, Denmark (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Garson, G.: Guide to Writing Empirical Papers, Theses, and Dissertations. Marcel Dekker, New York, NY (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, J.L., Ivancevich, J.M., Donnelly, J.H.: Organizations. Irwin, Homewood, IL (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaister, K.W., Husan, R., Buckley, P.J.: Decision-making autonomy in UK international equity joint ventures. Br. J. Manag. 14(4), 305–322 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gliner, J.A., Morgan, G.A.: Research Methods in Applied Settings: An Integrated Approach to Design and Analysis. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C.W.J.: Investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods. Econometrica 37(3), 424–438 (1969)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grant, A: What executives are asking about China: from entry to execution. The McKinsey Quarterly, 2006 Special Edition: Serving the New Chinese Consumer (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grant, K.S., Rice, D.C.: Exposure to environmental chemicals and developmental risk: contributions from studies with monkeys. In: Burbacher, T., Grant, K.S., Sackett, G.P. (eds.) Primate Models of Children’s Health and Developmental Disabilities, pp. 377–420. Elsevier, New York, NY (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Groves, T., Hong, Y., McMillan, J., Naughton, B.: Autonomy and incentives in Chinese state enterprises. Q. J. Econ. 109(1), 183–209 (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • Guojia fazhan he gaige weiyuanhui [National Development and Reform Commission]: Qiche chanye fazhan zhengce [Automotive Industry Development Policy] (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Haleblian, J., Finkelstein, S.: Top management team size, CEO dominance, and firm performance: the moderating roles of environmental turbulence and discretion. Acad. Manag. J. 36(4), 844–863 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hambrick, D.C., Abrahamson, E.: Assessing managerial discretion across industries: a multimethod approach. Acad. Manag. J. 38(5), 1427–1441 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hambrick, D.C., Finkelstein, S.: Managerial discretion: a bridge between polar views of organizational outcomes. In: Straw, B.M., Cummings, L.L. (eds.) Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 9, pp. 369–406. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hambrick, D.C., Geletkanycz, M.A., Fredrickson, J.W.: Top executive commitment to the status quo: some tests of its determinants. Strateg. Manag. J. 14(6), 401–418 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanssens, D.M., Parsons, L.J., Schultz, R.L.: Market Response Models: Econometric and Time Series Analysis. Kluwer Academic, Norwell, MA (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • He, W., Mukherjee, T.K., Wei, P.: Agency problems in tracking stock and minority carve-out decisions: explaining the discrepancy in short- and long-term performances. J. Econ. Finance 33(1), 27–42 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinecke, P.: Success Factors of Regional Strategies for Multinational Corporations: Appropriate Degrees of Management Autonomy. Springer, Berlin, Germany (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellevik, O.: Introduction to Causal Analysis: Exploring Survey Data by Crosstabulation. Norwegian University Press, Oslo, Norway (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Henseler, J., Fassott, G.: Testing moderating effects in PLS path models: an illustration of available procedures. In: Esposito Vinzi, V., Chin, W.W., Henseler, J., Wang, H. (eds.) Handbook of Partial Least Squares: Concepts, Methods and Applications in Marketing and Related Fields, pp. 713–736. Springer, Berlin, Germany (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hexter, J. Better manufacturing in China: an interview with two of PLP’s top executives. The McKinsey Quarterly, 1–6 Oct 2006

    Google Scholar 

  • Hexter, J., Woetzel, J.: Bringing best practice to China. McKinsey Quarterly 4, 1–7 (2007a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hexter, J., Woetzel, J.: Operation China: From Strategy to Execution. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA (2007b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G.: Culture’s Consequences: International Differences in Work-Related Values. Sage, Beverly Hills, CA (1980)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G.: Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind. McGraw-Hill, London, UK (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B.: Moral hazard and observability. Bell J. Econ. 10(1), 74–91 (1979)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, W.E.: Making China your second home market: an interview with the CEO of Danfoss. McKinsey Quarterly 1, 85–93 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • HRVillage: Plant manager job description. http://www.hrvillage.com/hrjobdesc/PlantManager.htm (2011). Accessed 04 March 2011

  • Hutzschenreuter, T., Kleindienst, I: A dynamic perspective on managerial discretion: the role of top management team characteristics and strategic agenda. Paper presented at the Annual Conference on Corporate Strategy, Vallendar, Germany, 11 May 2007

    Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, J.R., McClelland, G.H.: Misleading heuristics and moderated multiple regression models. J. Mark. Res. 38(1), 100–109 (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaccard, J., Turrisi, R.: Interaction Effects in Multiple Regression, 2nd edn. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackman, R.W.: Politics and Social Equality: A Comparative Analysis. Wiley, New York, NY (1975)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C.: Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. Am. Econ. Rev. 76(2), 323–329 (1986)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H.: Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J. Financ. Econ. 3(4), 305–360 (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C., Murphy, K.J.: Performance pay and top-management incentives. J. Polit. Econ. 98(2), 225–264 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C., Ruback, R.S.: The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence. J. Financ. Econ. 11, 5–50 (1983)

    Google Scholar 

  • Joseph, C. Plant manager job description. http://www.ehow.com/facts_5541729_plant-manager-job-description.html (2011). Accessed 04 March 2011

  • Katz, D., Kahn, R.L.: The Social Psychology of Organizations. Wiley, New York, NY (1978)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, L., Panhans, D., Poovan, B., Sobotka, B.: China Champions: How German Companies Can Successfully Integrate China Into Their Global Strategies. European Management Publications, Frankfurt a.M., Germany (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kayhan, A.: Managerial Discretion and the Capital Structure Dynamics, Working Paper. Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, LA (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Keegan, J.: The association between industry-level discretion and strategic variety: long-term strategic positions and current behaviours. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, School of Management, Queensland University of Technology, Brisbane, Queensland, Australia (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Keegan, J., Kabanoff, B.: Indirect industry- and subindustry-level managerial discretion measurement. Organ. Res. Methods 11(4), 682–694 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kesner, I.F.: Directors’ stock ownership and organizational performance: an investigation of fortune 500 companies. J. Manag. 13(3), 499–508 (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Keuzenkamp, H.A.: Probability, Econometrics and Truth: The Methodology of Econometrics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Key, S.: Perceived managerial discretion: an analysis of individual ethical intentions. J. Manag. Issues 14(2), 218–235 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Khanchel, I.: Le Rôle du Pouvoir Discrétionnaire du Dirigeant dans l’Amélioration de la Performance: Cas des Entreprises Tunisiennes. Revue des Sciences de Gestion 237(238), 95–103 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J.-J., Martimort, D.: The Theory of Incentives: The Principal-Agent Model. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P.J., Cannella, A.A., Lubatkin, M.H.: Ownership structure and corporate strategy: one question viewed from two different worlds. Strateg. Manag. J. 20(11), 1077–1086 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang, L., Poulsen, A., Stulz, R.: Asset sales, firm performance, and the agency costs of managerial discretion. J. Financ. Econ. 37(1), 3–37 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lassen, A.H., Waehrens, B.V., Boer, H.: Re-orienting the corporate entrepreneurial journey: exploring the role of middle management. Creativ. Innovat. Manag. 18(1), 16–23 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawler, E.E.: High Involvement Management. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA (1986)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawler, E.E.: The Ultimate Advantage. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Levinthal, D.: A survey of agency models of organizations. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 9(2), 153–185 (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, X.: Managerial autonomy, incentives and firm performance: evidence from investment climate survey in China. Paper presented at the Third Annual IB-BE Doctoral Research Workshop, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI, 02 Nov 2007

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, H.: Li Shufu zhi mou—Zhongguo minyingqiye de shengcun yangben [Mr Li Shufu’s Strategy—an Example for the Survival of Chinese Private Enterprises]. Sanlian shenghuo zhoukan [Lifeweek], (p. 577), (10 May 2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., Zhao, X.: Da gudong guquan, jingli zizhuquan yu gongsi jixiao [Ownership concentration, managerial discretion and company performance]. Zhongguo ruankexue [China Soft Science] 4, 86–92 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, X., Liu, X., Parker, D.: Foreign direct investment and productivity spillovers in the Chinese manufacturing sector. Econ. Syst. 25(4), 305–321 (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, K., Cai, S.: Gongsi zhili [Corporate Governance]. http://www.ntpu.edu.tw/pa/news/93news/attachment/931105-5.pdf (2004). Accessed 01 May 2010

  • López-Navarro, M.Á., Camisón-Zornoza, C.: The effect of group composition and autonomy on the performance of joint ventures (JVs): an analysis based on Spanish export JVs. Int. Bus. Rev. 12(1), 17–39 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Loschky, A.: Reviewing the nomenclature for high-technology trade—the sectoral approach. Paper presented at the 1st Meeting of the Working Party on International Trade in Goods and Trade in Services Statistics (WPTGS), OECD Headquarters, Paris, France, 22–24 Sept 2008

    Google Scholar 

  • Magnan, M.L., St-Onge, S.: Bank performance and executive compensation: a managerial discretion perspective. Strateg. Manag. J. 18(7), 573–581 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Marin, D., Verdier, T.: Corporate Hierarchies and the Size of Nations: Theory and Evidence. Paris School of Economics Mimeo, Paris, France (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Maslow, A.H.: Motivation and Personality. Harper & Row, New York, NY (1970)

    Google Scholar 

  • McGregor, D.: The Human Side of the Enterprise. McGraw-Hill, New York, NY (1960)

    Google Scholar 

  • McGregor, J.: One Billion Customers: Lessons from the Front Lines of Doing Business in China. Nicholas Brealey Publishing, London, UK (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • McKinsey & Company, London School of Economics, Stanford University: Management matters database on China (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Miesing, P., Kriger, M.P., Slough, N.: Towards a model of effective knowledge transfer within transnationals: the case of Chinese Foreign Invested Enterprises. J. Technol. Transf. 32, 109–122 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I.: The best of both worlds: exploitation and exploration in successful family businesses. In: Baum J.A.C., Dobrev S.D., Van Witteloostuijn A. (eds.) Ecology and strategy (Advances in Strategic Management), vol. 23, pp. 215–240. Emerald Group Publishing Limited (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, D.E., Keast, R.L.: Achieving better stewardship of major infrastructure assets through configuration of governance arrangements utilising stewardship theory. Paper presented at the 13th International Research Society for Public Management Conference (IRSPM XIII), Fredericksberg, Denmark, 06–08 April 2009

    Google Scholar 

  • Misangyi, V.F.: A test of alternative theories of managerial discretion. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Muth, M., Donaldson, L.: Stewardship theory and board structure: a contingency approach. Corp. Govern. Int. Rev. 6(1), 5–28 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Nooteboom, B.: Organisational learning and multinational strategy. ERIM Report Series, ERS-2004-004-ORG (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Oh, H.: The relationship between Work environment factors and organizational knowledge creation Process. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, The Faculty of the Graduate School of the University of Minnesota, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ongore, V.: Ownership Structure, Board, and Manager Discretion on Performance: The Effects of Ownership Structure, Board Effectiveness and Managerial Discretion on Firm Performance. LAP Lambert Academic Publishing, Saarbrücken, Germany (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmer, J.: The profit-performance effects of the separation of ownership from control in large U.S. industrial corporations. Bell J. Econ. Manag. Sci. 4(1), 293–303 (1973)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pascha, W.: Japans Stellung in Ost- und Südostasien: Ist Japan für Deutschland noch ein attraktiver Markt und Wirtschaftspartner in der Region? In: Riesenhuber, H., Kreiner, J. (eds.) Japan ist offen: Chancen für deutsche Unternehmen, pp. 57–70. Springer, Berlin, Germany (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrone, V., Zaheer, A., McEvily, B.: Free to be Trusted? Organizational constraints on trust in boundary spanners. Organ. Sci. 14(4), 422–439 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, A., Sossin, L.: A brief introduction of the puzzle of discretion. Can. J. Law Soc. 24(3), 301–312 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Quigley, T.J., Hambrick, D.C. When the former CEO remains board chair: effects on discretion, organizational change, and performance. Paper presented at the Academy of Management Annual Meeting, Chicago, IL, 2009

    Google Scholar 

  • Raes, A.M.L., Heijltjes, M.G., Glunk, U., Roe, R.A.: The interface of the top management team and middle managers: a process model. Acad. Manag. Rev. 36(1), 102–126 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajagopalan, N., Finkelstein, S.: Effects of strategic orientation and environmental change on senior management reward systems. Strateg. Manag. J. 13, 127–141 (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, T.V.S.R., Rastogi, R.: Discretionary Managerial Behavior. Springer, Berlin, Germany (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhard, M., Taube, M., Wasmer, C.: Industrienahe Technologiepolitik in China—Gefahr für die technologische Wettbewerbsfähigkeit Deutschlands? ifo Schnelldienst 60(23), 20–31 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rigdon, E.E., Schumacker, R.E., Wothke, W.: A comparative review of interaction and nonlinear modeling. In: Schumacker, R.E., Marcoulides, G.A. (eds.) Interaction and Nonlinear Effects in Structural Equation Modeling, pp. 1–16. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum, J.E.: Organization career systems and employee misperceptions. In: Arthur, M.B., Hall, D.T., Lawrence, B.S. (eds.) Handbook of Career Theory, pp. 329–353. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rumelt, R.: Towards a strategic theory of the firm. In: Lamb, R. (ed.) Competitive Strategic Management, pp. 556–570. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ (1984)

    Google Scholar 

  • Salvato, C.: Towards a stewardship theory of the family firm. Paper presented at the XIth Family Business Network Conference, Helsinki, Finland, 2002

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez, G.: PLS Historical Review. Department of Statistics and Operations Research. Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya, Barcelona, Spain (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Schramm, M., Taube, M.: The institutional economics of legal institutions, Guanxi, and corruption in the PR China. In: Kidd, J., Richter, F.-J. (eds.) Fighting Corruption in Asia: Causes, Effects and Remedies, pp. 271–296. World Scientific, Singapore (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaughnessy, J.J., Zechmeister, E.B., Zechmeister, J.S.: Research Methods in Psychology. McGraw-Hill, Boston, MA (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W.: A survey of corporate governance. J. Finance 52(2), 737–783 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A.: Spurious correlation: a causal interpretation. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 49, 467–479 (1954)

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A.: Administrative Behavior, 2nd edn. Macmillan, New York, NY (1957a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A.: Models of Man: Social and Rational. Wiley, New York, NY (1957b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Spremann, K.: Agent and principal. In: Bamberg, G., Spremann, K. (eds.) Agency Theory, Information, and Incentives, pp. 3–42. Springer, Berlin, Germany (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Stano, M.: Monopoly power, ownership control, and corporate performance. Bell J. Econ. 7(2), 672–679 (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sull, D.N.: Made in China: What Western Managers Can Learn from Trailblazing Chinese Entrepreneurs. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tan Xin.: Gongchang jingli [Plant Managers]. http://www.tanxin.net/info/view.php?info_id=2581 (2011). Accessed 04 March 2011

  • Tang, J.: Dominant CEO, deviant strategy, and extreme performance. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, The University of Western Ontario, London, Ontario, Canada (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Taube, M.: Chinas Rückkehr in die Weltgemeinschaft: Triebkräfte und Widerstände auf dem Weg zu einem ‘Global Player’. Duisburg Working Papers on East Asian Studies, 51, Institute for East Asian Studies, Gerhard-Mercator-Universität Duisburg, Duisburg, Germany (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Taube, M.: Spillover-effects, crowding-in and the contributions of FDI to growth in China: a review of the literature. Duisburg Working Papers on East Asian Studies, 74, Institute for East Asian Studies, Gerhard-Mercator-Universität Duisburg, Duisburg, Germany (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Taube, M.: Chinas rasante ökonomische Entwicklung: Grundlagen, Triebkräfte und Perspektiven des wirtschaftlichen Aufstiegs. Der Bürger im Staat 3(4), 186–194 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Taube, M., Schramm, M.: Private ordering of corrupt transactions: the case of the Chinese Guanxi networks and their challenge by a formal legal system. In: Graf Lambsdorff, J., Taube, M., Schramm, M. (eds.) The New Institutional Economics of Corruption, pp. 181–197. Routledge, Abingdon, UK (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Thépot, J.: Jensen et Meckling Trente Ans Après. Rev. Fr. Gest. 175, 15–22 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, A.S., Peyrefitte, J.: The impact of managerial discretion on firm performance. J. Bus. Strateg. 13(1), 21–41 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomsen, S., Pedersen, T.: Ownership structure and economic performance in the largest European companies. Strateg. Manag. J. 21(6), 689–705 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Thun, E.: Changing Lanes in China: Foreign Direct Investment, Local Governments, and Auto Sector Development. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tian, X.: Managing International Business in China. Cambridge University Press, New York, NY (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tian, J.J., Lau, C.-M.: Board composition, leadership structure and performance in Chinese shareholding companies. Asia Pac. J. Manag. 18(2), 245–263 (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J.: The Theory of Industrial Organization. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tosi, H.L., Brownlee, A.L., Silva, P., Katz, J.P.: An empirical exploration of decision-making under agency controls and stewardship structure. J. Manag. Stud. 40(8), 2053–2071 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H.C.: Cross-cultural studies of individualism and collectivism. In: Berman, J.J. (ed.) Nebraska Symposium on Motivation, vol. 37, pp. 41–134. University of Nebraska Press, Lincoln, NE (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H.C.: Individualism and Collectivism. Westview, Boulder, CO (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H.C., Dunnette, M., Hough, I.M. (eds.): Cross-Cultural Studies. Handbook of Industrial and Organizational Psychology (Vol. 4). Consulting Psychologists, Palo Alto, CA (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J.C.: The experimental social psychology of intergroup behavior. In: Turner, J.C., Giles, H. (eds.) Intergroup Behavior, pp. 66–101. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL (1981)

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Slyke, D.M.: Agents or stewards: using theory to understand the government-nonprofit social service contracting relationship. J. Publ. Admin. Res. Theor. 17(2), 157–187 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Vargas Sánchez, A.: La Teoría de la Agencia versus la Teoría del Servidor: una Aplicación a las Sociedades Cooperativas Agrarias de la Provincia de Huelva. Paper presented at the Best Papers Proceedings. X International Conference of AEDEM, Reggio Calabria, Italy, 04–06 Sept 2001

    Google Scholar 

  • Vargas Sánchez, A.: Development of corporate governance systems: agency theory versus stewardship theory in Welsh agrarian cooperative societies. Paper presented at the 4th Annual Conference of EURAM (European Academy of Management), St. Andrews, Scotland, 05–09 May 2004

    Google Scholar 

  • Vargas Sánchez, A.: Agency theory versus stewardship theory. http://www.slideworld.com/slideshows.aspx/AGENCY-THEORY-VERSUS-STEWARDSHIP-THEORY-ppt-914587 (2005). Acessed 01 May 2010

  • Venaik, S.: A model of global marketing in multinational firms: an empirical investigation. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, Australian Graduate School of Management, University of Sydney and University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Venkatraman, N.: The concept of fit in strategy research: toward verbal and statistical correspondence. Acad. Manag. Rev. 14(3), 423–444 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Verhoest, K.: Autonomy, contracting and competition: what is their effect on the performance of executive public organisations. Paper presented at the European Group on Public Administration (EGPA) 2003 Workshop ‘Governance: What do we Know?’, Lisbon, Portugal, 03–06 Sept. 2003

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J.: The causal effects of exports on firm size and labor productivity: first evidence from a matching approach. Econ. Lett. 77(2), 287–292 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wald, M., Carlsmith, J.M., Leiderman, P.H.: Protecting Abused and Neglected Children. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Walters, J.H.: Managerial Discretion, Top Managers' Perceptions, and Firm Performance: An Empirical Examination. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Walton, R.E.: Establishing and maintaining high-commitment work systems. In: Kimberly, J.R., Miles, R.H. (eds.) The Organizational Life Cycle: Issues in the Creating, Transformation, and Decline of Organizations. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA (1980)

    Google Scholar 

  • Walton, R.E.: From control to commitment in the workplace. Harv. Bus. Rev. 63(2), 76–84 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, H.: Essays on CEO turnover, succession, and compensation. Unpublished Thesis for Doctor of Philosophy, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, IL (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, T., Birkinshaw, J., Toulan, O.: Delegation and control mechanisms of multinational corporations in managing global customers. Paper presented at the Strategic Management Department Seminar Series, Department of Strategic Management at the Guanghua School of Management, Peking University, Beijing, China, 12 Nov 2008

    Google Scholar 

  • Weidenbaum, M., Jensen, M.: Modern corporations and private property. Society 30(1), 101–106 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Werner, S., Tosi, H.L.: Other people’s money: the effects of ownership on compensation strategy and managerial pay. Acad. Manag. J. 38(6), 1672–1691 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Willcocks, L., Griffiths, C.: The crucial role of middle management in outsourcing. MIS Quarterly Executive 9(3), 177–193 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E.: Managerial discretion and business behavior. Am. Econ. Rev. 53, 1032–1057 (1963)

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E.: The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. Free Press, New York, NY (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J.M.: Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 2nd edn. South-Western College Publishing, Mason, OH (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, P., Kroll, M.: Executive discretion and corporate performance as determinants of CEO compensation, contingent on external monitoring activities. J.Manage. Govern. 6(3), 189–214 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Xu, L.C., Zhu, T., Lin, Y.: Politician control, agency problems and ownership reform: evidence from China. Econ. Transit. 13(1), 1–24 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Yan, Y., Chong, C.Y., Mak, S.: An exploration of managerial discretion and its impact on firm performance: task autonomy, contractual control, and compensation. Int. Bus. Rev. 19(6), 521–530 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahra, S.A.: Ownership Involvement and international expansion: an empirical test of the stewardship theory among family firms. J. Bus. Ventur. 18(4), 495–512 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahra, S.A., Stanton, W.W.: The implications of board of directors composition for corporate strategy and performance. Int. J. Manag. 5, 229–236 (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, W.: Decision rights, residual claim and performance: a theory of how the Chinese state enterprise reform works. China Econ. Rev. 8(1), 67–82 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, C., Li, H.: Jingli zizhuquan, gaoguan baochou chaju yu gongsi yeji [Managerial Discretion, Top Management Pay Gap and Company Performance]. Zhongguo ruankexue [China Soft Science](4), 117–126 (2008b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, C., Li, H., Zhao, X.: Qiye guimo, jingli zizhuquan yu R&D touru guanxi yanjiu: laizi Zhongguo shangshi gongsi de jingyan zhengju [Research on the relationship between firm scale, managerial discretion and R&D expenditure: empirical EVIDENCE from China’s listed companies]. Kexue xue yanjiu [Studies in Science of Science] 24(3), 432–438 (2006a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, C., Zhao, X., Li, H.: Jiyu jingli zizhuquan de qiye R&D touru juece moxing ji shizheng yanjiu [Theoretical and empirical research on a decision model of enterprise R&D expenditure based on managerial discretion]. Guanli kexue [Management Sciences in China] 19(3), 8–13 (2006b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, X., Chu, P., Chen, C.: Perceived managerial discretion and firm performance: the moderating role of market competition. Soc. Behav. Pers. Int. J. 38(2), 145–157 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhongguo fuzhuang rencai wang [China apparel talent net]: Zuixin gongchang jingli [Latest Plant Managers] http://www.efjob.cn/resume/util/p155195.html (2011). Accessed 04 March 2011

  • Zhonghua renmin gongheguo zhongyang renmin zhengfu [The Central People’s Government of the People’s Republic of China]: Gaige kaifang 30 nian woguo jingji shehui fazhan chengjiu [Achievements in the development of China’s economy and society 30 years AFTER the initiation of reforms and opening-up] http://www.gov.cn/test/2008-11/12/content_1146712.htm (2008a). Accessed 08 March 2009

  • Zou, L.: Essays in Principal-Agent Theory. CIACO, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Guojia tongji ju [National Bureau of Statistics]: 2010 nian guomin jingji he shehui fazhan tongji gongbao [2010 National Economy and Society Development Statistics Bulletin]. http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjgb/ndtjgb/qgndtjgb/t20110228_402705692.htm (2011). Accessed 29 July 2011

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hagen Wülferth .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Wülferth, H. (2013). Conclusion. In: Managerial Discretion and Performance in China. Contributions to Management Science. Physica, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-35837-1_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics