Skip to main content

International Biodiversity Management with Technological Change

  • Chapter
Green Growth and Sustainable Development

Part of the book series: Dynamic Modeling and Econometrics in Economics and Finance ((DMEF,volume 14))

Abstract

This document examines a group of countries where the conservation of land benefits anybody through biodiversity. All countries produce the same good from labor and land and improve their productivity through abatement investment. The international agency performing biodiversity management is self-interested. Three cases of biodiversity management are compared: (i) laissez-faire, (ii) the regulation of land use, and (iii) subsidies to the conservation of land. The results are the following. Regulation promotes biodiversity, abatement and welfare. Because subsidies must be financed by distortionary taxes, the replacement of regulation by subsidies hampers biodiversity, abatement and welfare. Applied to NATURA 2000 in the EU, this suggests that regulation without any budget is the appropriate degree of authority for the Commission.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    If the countries were heterogeneous, then there could be multiple equilibria.

  2. 2.

    With the general form of the utility function, \(\int_{T}^{\infty}c_{j}^{1-\beta}b^{\delta}e^{-{\rho}(\theta-T)}d\theta\), where β∈[0,1) is a constant, it would be very difficult to find a stationary state in the model.

  3. 3.

    This corresponds well to the institutions of the EU.

  4. 4.

    This is a modification of the idea of Grossman and Helpman (1994), who assume that a policy maker’s welfare is a linear function of both the political contributions and the utilities of the lobbies. This characterizes the fact that the policy maker cares about (a) its revenue from political contributions and (b) the possibility of being re-elected, which depends of the utility of the electorate (i.e. the members of the lobbies). This setup is simplified by ignoring the utilities of the lobbies. Because the policy instruments must maximize the utility of each lobby in equilibrium [cf. condition (iii) in Appendix C], the results would not change if Grossman and Helpman’s original welfare function were used.

  5. 5.

    The crucial point in the common agency game is that each country j can credibly commit itself to its contribution function R j (b).

References

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1998). Endogenous growth theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbier, E. B., & Schulz, C.-E. (1997). Wildlife, biodiversity and trade. Environment and Development Economics, 2(2), 145–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Pindyck, K. (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1997). Common agency and coordination: general theory and application to management policy making. Journal of Political Economy, 105(4), 752–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Endres, A., & Radke, V. (1999). Land use, biodiversity, and sustainability. Journal of Economics, 70(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johal, S., & Ulph, A. (2002). Globalization, lobbying, and international environmental governance. Review of International Economics, 10(3), 387–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, A. J. (1998). Step change or stasis? EC environmental policy after the Amsterdam summit. Environmental Politics, 7(1), 227–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacArthur, R., & Wilson, E. O. (1967). The theory of island biography. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Majone, G. (1996). Regulating Europe. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ledoux, L., Crooks, S., Jordan, A., & Turner, K. (2000). Implementing EU biodiversity policy: UK experiences. Land Use Policy, 17(4), 257–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostermann, O. P. (1998). The need for management of nature conservation sites designated under Natura 2000. Journal of Applied Ecology, 35(6), 968–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowthorn, B., & Brown, G. (1999). When a high discount rate encourages biodiversity. International Economic Review, 40(2), 315–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swanson, T. M. (1994). The economics of extinction revisited and revised: a generalized framework for the analysis of the problems of endangered species and biodiversity losses. Oxford Economics Papers, 46(4), 800–821.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, N., & Christophersen, T. (2002). The influence of non-governmental organizations on the creation of Natura 2000 during the European policy process. Forest policy and economics, 4(1), 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful to Timothy Swanson and Duncan Knowler for their constructive comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tapio Palokangas .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix A: Equations (21) and (22) and Function (23)

Noting (5) and (8), the function (15) has the partial derivatives:

(41)
(42)

The maximization of the expected utility (18) by (l j ,b j ) s.t. (9) and (12), given (τ,s,η,b,R j ,R), is equivalent to the maximization of

$$E\int_T^\infty a^{\gamma_j}\frac{b^{\delta}}{1+\tau}\phi(l_j,b_j,s,\eta,\tau)e^{-\rho(\theta-T)}d\theta $$

s.t. (9) and (12), given (τ,s,η,b,R j ,R). The value of this optimal program starting at time T is

(43)

The Bellman equation corresponding to the optimal program (43) is given by (cf. Dixit and Pindyck 1994)

$$ \rho \varOmega_j=\max\limits_{ (l_{j},b_j) \mbox{\scriptsize{ s.t. (9)}}}\varLambda^j(l_j,b_j, \gamma_j,\underline{b},s,\eta,\tau), $$
(44)

where

(45)

The first-order conditions corresponding to the Bellman equation (44) and (45) are ∂Λ j/∂l j =0 and ∂Λ j/∂b j =0. To solve the dynamic program, I assume that the value of the program, Ω j , is in fixed proportion to the instantaneous utility at the optimum:

(46)

where φ j is a constant and \(l_{j}^{*}\) and \(b_{j}^{*}\) are the optimal values of l j and b j . From (46) it follows that

$$ \varOmega_j(\gamma_j+1,\underline{b},s,\eta, \tau)/\varOmega_j(\gamma_j,\underline{b},s,\eta,\tau)=a. $$
(47)

Inserting (46) and (47) into the Bellman equation (44) and (45) yields

(48)

Noting (41), (42), (45), (47) and (48), the first-order conditions corresponding to the maximization (44) are given by

(49)
(50)

In the system consisting of the international agency budget (11) and the first-order conditions (49) and (50) for all countries j∈[0,1], there is symmetry throughout j∈[0,1]. This implies l j =l and b j =b for j∈[0,1]. From this, (1), (5), (6), (13), (14), (15) and (17) it follows that

(51)

This implies (20). Inserting (51), l j =l and b j =b back to (49) and (50) yields (21) and (22).

Noting l j =l, b j =b, (15), (43), (46) and (51), the expected utility of country j, (18), can be written as follows:

Appendix B: Equations (25) and (26)

The average serial number of technology in the economy is given by

$$ \gamma=\int_{0}^1\gamma_jdj. $$
(52)

Given the Poisson property of the improvement of technology in countries j∈[0,1] (cf. Sect. 2.2), one obtains the following. In a small period of time dt, the probability that abatement investment will lead a jump from γ to γ+1 is given by λzdt, while the probability that abatement investment will remain without success is given by 1−λzdt. Noting (9), this defines a Poisson process χ with

$$ d\chi= \begin{cases} 1 & \mbox{with probability }\lambda (1-l)dt, \cr 0 & \mbox{with probability }1-\lambda(1-l)dt, \end{cases}\quad l\doteq\int_{0}^1l_jdj, $$
(53)

where is the increment of the process χ.

Because there is perfect symmetry throughout countries j∈[0,1] in the system (2), (53), (21) and (22), there is l j =l=l P and b j =b=b P for j∈[0,1] in equilibrium. Because there is one-to-one correspondence from (η,s) to (l P,b P), one can replace the subsidies (η,s) by (l P,b P) as the international agency’s policy instruments. Thus, the international agency maximizes (24) by (l P,b P) s.t. technological change (53). Noting (5), (17) and (52), one obtains the value function of this maximization as follows:

Noting (8), this leads to the first-order conditions

These equations imply (25) and (26).

Appendix C: The Lobbying Game

Following Dixit et al. (1997), a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium for this game is a policy ζ and a set of contribution schedules R 1(ζ),…,R J (ζ) such that the following conditions (i)–(iv) hold:

  1. (i)

    Contributions R j are non-negative but no more than the contributor’s income, Γ j ≥0.

  2. (ii)

    The policy ζ maximizes the international agency’s welfare (27) taking the contribution schedules R j as given.

  3. (iii)

    Country j cannot have a viable strategy R j (ζ) that yields it a higher level of utility than in equilibrium, given the others’ contributions.

  4. (iv)

    Country j provides the international agency at least with the level of utility as in the case in which it offers nothing (R j =0), and the international agency responds optimally given the contribution functions of the other countries.

Appendix D: Equation (37)

Given η=0, (7), (8), (13), (14), (17), (19) and (20), the international agency budget constraint (11) becomes

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Palokangas, T. (2013). International Biodiversity Management with Technological Change. In: Crespo Cuaresma, J., Palokangas, T., Tarasyev, A. (eds) Green Growth and Sustainable Development. Dynamic Modeling and Econometrics in Economics and Finance, vol 14. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-34354-4_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics