Skip to main content

The City-State of Ancient Athens as a Prototype for an Entrepreneurial and Managerial Society

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 2077 Accesses

Abstract

In this paper we argue that a significant part of the wealth amassed by Athens in classical times emanated from the entrepreneurial incentives Athenians, rather consciously, instituted and applied in their city-state. To corroborate our view, we give a brief account of the political institutions and rules of governance of the city-state of Athens; we describe the economy within which entrepreneurs operated, and we explain the reasons why Athenians chose to establish an open society, based on international trade and incentives for almost everyone (including slaves) to pursue entrepreneurial activities. Lastly, we focus on a “protagonist of management science,” i.e. Xenophon, who developed explicitly the first principles and imperatives of managerial actions.

Anastassios D. Karayiannis

Author is Deceased

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a detailed analysis of these arrangements as well as an extensive bibliography from which they derive, see Bitros and Karayiannis (2006, 2008, 2010) and Kyriazis and Karayiannis (2011).

  2. 2.

    Athenians regarded that the protection of the private property except being under a “statute law” was also a kind of “natural law” (Demosthenes, Against Aristocrates, 61). By adopting the institution of private property, the middle class grew significantly and this development helped the establishment of democracy (Aristotle, Politics, 1295b, 30–40).

  3. 3.

    For the extensive description of the judicial arrangements through which Athenians enforced fairness in business, see Kyriazis and Karayiannis (2011).

  4. 4.

    Isocrates (Antidosis); Demosthenes (Against Phaenippus).

  5. 5.

    For the Athenian system of paideia see Bitros and Karayiannis (2011).

  6. 6.

    For the high wealth level of the Athenian economy see Ober (2011).

  7. 7.

    An example in this regard is that of freedman Alcias (Lysias, On the Olive Stump, 10).

  8. 8.

    Aristophanes, in his comedies, mentions many small-scale industrial and trade occupations (see e.g. Birds, 488495; Peace, 445450, 543–550, 200–205, 1220–1225, 1240).

  9. 9.

    For examples on how demand and supply determined the prices of goods, see e.g. Aristophanes (Acharnians, 755–760, 60–65; Knights, 645–652); Engen (2001, 183); Harris (2002, 76).

  10. 10.

    See Lysias (Against the Corn Dealers); Aristotle (The Athenian Constitution, LI).

  11. 11.

    Aristotle (Nicomachean Ethics, 1133a–b) discusses the qualities of silver in the function of money in much detail.

  12. 12.

    For a detailed analysis of these banking activities see Isager and Hansen (1975), 90–98) and Cohen (1992, Chap. 5).

  13. 13.

    Isager and Hansen (1975, 76–81) and Cohen (1990) analyze the maritime risks and the insurance policies that were adopted at the time.

  14. 14.

    Engen (2001, 186–202) finds epigraphic evidence showing that import–export activities were conducted much like in our times and that the Athenians paid special tributes to traders for their services to the city.

  15. 15.

    See the descriptions of Andocides (On the Mysteries, 38); Aeschines (Against Timarchus, 124).

  16. 16.

    Demosthenes (Against Stephanus I, 31–34; Against Stephanus II, 17) gives an example from the sector of banking.

  17. 17.

    See e.g. Aeschines (Against Timarchus, 153); Hyperides (In Defense of Euxenippus, 36); Demosthenes (For Phormio, 8–9; Against Nausimachus, 25–26).

  18. 18.

    See Isocrates (Areopagiticus, 44–45; To Demonicus, 45; To Nicokles, 18; Antidosis, 159–160).

  19. 19.

    See e.g. Antiphon (Tetralogy I, b 12–13); Demosthenes (To Nausimachus, 25–27); Lycurgus (Against Leocratus, 139–140).

  20. 20.

    Plato and Aristotle were rather hostile toward the profit seeking activities of individuals which they considered to be a source of economic injustice and social destruction (see Karayiannis 1990, 21, 28–29).

  21. 21.

    It seems that the majority of metics who acted as entrepreneurs preferred activities with moveable assets such as bankers, shopkeepers and traders, because they did not have the right to be proprietors of agricultural land (see Humphreys 1978, 148).

  22. 22.

    Christesen (2003) presents evidence for the existence of income-maximizing economic rationalism in fourth century Athens with emphasis on silver mining and other risky undertakings with borrowed funds.

  23. 23.

    As Xenophon comments: “In other states [except Sparta], I suppose, all men make as much money as they can. One is a farmer, another ship-owner, another a merchant and others live by different handicrafts” (Constitution of the Lacedaemonians, vii.1; brackets added).

  24. 24.

    For an extensive analysis see Karayiannis (2003).

  25. 25.

    Xenophon, also noticed (Memorabilia, II.vii. 11–12) the useful services of those offering loanable funds (with or without interest) for the establishment of enterprise.

  26. 26.

    Xenophon draws the main similarities between the coordinating role of the entrepreneur-manager and that of the governor (e.g. Cyrus the Great) and the general in army (Cyropaedia, VI.ii, VIII.i.9–15; Oeconomicus, iv.5–7).

  27. 27.

    The role of entrepreneur as manager was not exercised exclusively by the owner. From available records it turns out that frequently owners of enterprises trained their slaves for this purpose; see e.g. Isocrates (Trapeziticus, 12); Demosthenes (Against Stephanus, 1–2). A well-known example, as we indicated previously, is the slave Phormio who managed the bank of Passion (Demosthenes, Against Stephanus I, 33, 36, 71).

  28. 28.

    Another means of undertaking risky activities, namely to increase the searching investments for the discovery of new silver ore, suggested by Xenophon (Ways and Means, iv.30–31), was through the establishment of a public enterprise. However, he questioned the efficiency of such a scheme by commenting: “what may well excite surprise is that the state, being aware that many private individuals are making money out of her [i.e. land] does not imitate them” (Ways and Means, iv.14; brackets added).

  29. 29.

    Such an entrepreneurial function was also described by Demosthenes (Against Dionysodorus, 9–10).

References

  • Aeschines (1919). In Against Timarchus (trans: Adams, C. D.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aeschylus. (1926). Persians (trans: Smyth, H. W.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amemiya, T. (2007). Economy and economics of ancient Greece. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Andocides. (1968). On the mysteries. Minor Attic Orators (trans: Maidment, K. J.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreades, A. M. (1933). A history of Greek public finance. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antiphon. (1968). Tetralogy. Minor attic orators (trans: Maidment, K. J.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristophanes. (1978a). Acharnians. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristophanes. (1978b). Birds. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristophanes. (1978c). Knights. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristophanes. (1978d). Peace. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle. (1892). Nicomachean ethics (trans: Welldon, J. E. C.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle. (1944). Politics (trans: Rackham, H.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle. (1952). The Athenian constitution (trans: Rackham, H.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitros, G. C., & Karayiannis, A. D. (2006). The liberating power of entrepreneurship in ancient Athens. In Y. Cassis & I. Pepelasis-Minoglou (Eds.), Country studies in entrepreneurship: a historical perspective (pp. 11–24). London: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitros, G. C., & Karayiannis, A. D. (2008). Values and institutions as determinants of entrepreneurship in ancient Athens. Journal of Institutional Economics, 4, 205–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitros, G. C., & Karayiannis, A. D. (2010). Morality, institutions and the wealth of nations: Some lessons from ancient Greece. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 68–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitros, G. C., & Karayiannis, A. D. (2011). Character, knowledge and skills in ancient Greek Paideia: some lessons for today’s policy makers. Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 8(1), 193–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christesen, P. (2003). Economic rationalism in fourth-century BCE Athens. Greece & Rome, 50(1), 31–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, E. (1990). Commercial lending by athenian banks: cliometric fallacies and forensic methodology. Classical Philology, 85(3), 177–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, E. (1992). Athenian economy & society. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demosthenes. (1939). Orations and Speeches (trans: Murray, A. T.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engen, D. T. (2001). Trade, traders, and the economy of Athens in the fourth century BC. In D. Tandy (Ed.), Prehistory and history: ethnicity, class, and political economy (pp. 179–202). Montreal: Black Rose.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engen, D. T. (2005). Ancient greenbacks: Athenian owls, the law of Nikophron, and the Greek economy. Historia, 54(4), 359–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, E. M. (2002). Workshop, marketplace and household. In P. Cartledge, E. E. Cohen, & L. Foxhall (Eds.), Money, labour and land (pp. 67–99). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herodotus. (1920). The histories (trans: Godley, A. D.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphreys, S. C. (1978). Anthropology and the Greeks. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyperides. (1958). Speeches. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Isager, S., & Hansen, M. (1975). Aspects of Athenian society in the fourth century BC. Odense: Odense University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Isocrates. (1980). Orations and speeches (trans: Norlin, G.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, A. D. (1990). The platonic ethico-economic structure of society. Quaderni di Storia dell’ EconomiaPolitica, VIII(1), 3–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, A. D. (1992a). Entrepreneurship in classical Greek literature. South African Journal of Economics, 60(1), 67–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, A. D. (1992b). Rowland Hamilton’s neglected contribution on risk, uncertainty and profit. Ιn S. Todd Lowry (Ed.), Perspectives in the History of Economic Thought: Contributions to the History of Economics (vol. VIII, pp. 80–89). Aldershot: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, A. D. (2003). Entrepreneurial functions and characteristics in a proto-capitalist economy. The Xenophonian entrepreneur. WirtschaftspolitischeBlatter, 4, 553–563.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, A. D. (2008). Basic elements of entrepreneurship: Ideas from the past. Storia del Pensiero Economico, 2, 91–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, A. D. (2009). The Marshallian entrepreneur. History of Economic Ideas, 17(3), 75–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karayiannis, Α. D., & Hatzis, Α. (2011). Morality, social norms and the rule of law as transaction cost-saving devices: The case of ancient Athens. European Journal of Law and Economics, DOI 10.1007/s10657-010-9150-6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kyriazis, N., & Karayiannis, A. D. (2011). Democracy, institutional changes and economic development: the case of ancient Athens. Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 8(1), 61–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loomis, W. T. (1998). Wages, welfare costs and inflation in classical Athens. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lycurgus. (1962). Against Leocrates. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lysias. (1930). Orations and speeches (trans: Lamb, W. R. M.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ober, J. (2011). Wealthy Hellas. Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 8(1), 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plato. (1963). Laws. In E. Hamilton & H. Cairns (Eds.), The collected dialogues of Plato Laws (trans: Taylor, A. E.). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plutarch. (1939). Solon. Athens: Papyrus (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaps, D. M. (2004). The invention of coinage and the monetization of ancient Greece. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thucydides. (1928). The Peloponnesian war (trans: Smith, C. F.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xenophon. (1961). Cyropaedia (trans: Miler, W.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xenophon. (1968a). Constitution of the Lacedaemonians (trans: Marchant, E. C.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xenophon. (1968b). Cyrus’s anabasis (trans: Brownson, C. L.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xenophon. (1968c). Memorabilia (trnas: Marchant, E. C.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xenophon. (1968d). Oeconomicus (trans: Marchant, E. C.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xenophon. (1968e). Ways and means (trans: Marchant, E. C.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George C. Bitros .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bitros, G.C., Karayiannis, A.D. (2012). The City-State of Ancient Athens as a Prototype for an Entrepreneurial and Managerial Society. In: Prastacos, G., Wang, F., Soderquist, K. (eds) Leadership through the Classics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-32445-1_19

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics