Skip to main content

Pay More Stocks and Options to Directors? Theory and Evidence of Board Compensation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Corporate Governance

Abstract

The compensation of board directors has received much attention, along with the growing debates on corporate governance in recent years, partly due to the ongoing financial crisis. While prior studies including Hall and Liebman (1998) have shown evidence of a dramatic increase in the use of equity-based incentives, resulting in an increase in the sensitivity of executive pay to firm performance, we ask whether it benefits shareholders to offer similar incentive contracts to board directors. This paper suggests that equity-based compensation for board directors is necessary and the level of incentives depends on directors’ effectiveness in monitoring and friendliness in advising CEOs. Using the market competition and pay correlation to proxy for monitoring effectiveness and advisory friendliness, we report empirical evidence supporting our hypotheses.

IBM is cutting off stock option grants to its board of directors but doubling their cash pay, calling the move an improvement in its governance practices. “We think it’s a sound principle of governance,” IBM spokesman John Bukovinsky said. “Less reliance on stock options is conducive to encouraging longer-term strategic decisions.”

– USA Today (December 21, 2006)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It is similar to the debt renegotiation problem with many creditors as analyzed in Bolton and Scharfstein (1996) using an optimal contracting framework.

  2. 2.

    This implies that the control variables and firm fixed effects used in their regressions cannot fully capture the real firm characteristics.

  3. 3.

    The excessive pays of board directors and CEOs are similar to Brick et al. (2006).

  4. 4.

    Competition in banking industry should drive down the incentive pays for directors due to the external monitoring and disciplining by the competitive market. But what we observed is the rising incentive pays for bank directors. This might be due to the global war for financial talents (Chambers et al. 1998) and the rise of hedge funds (Kostovetsky 2009).

  5. 5.

    In some European Union and Asian countries, there are two separate boards: an executive board, also called corporate executive team, for day-to-day business and a supervisory board, also called board of directors (elected by the shareholders) for supervising the executive board. To simply the analysis, this paper considers the boards of directors as a single entity.

  6. 6.

    The ExecuComp database reports detailed information of director compensation from 2006 onwards.

  7. 7.

    Harris and Raviv (2008) studies the optimal condition for inside versus outside directors to control the board, and show that shareholders can sometimes be better off with an insider-controlled board.

  8. 8.

    The extant literature on product market competition, strategic alliances and joint ventures generally uses SIC codes to assess whether two companies are competitors. The approach used in the existing literature (e.g., Grullon et al. 2006) treats two companies as competitors if they have the same 4-digit SIC code. Masulis and Nahata (2009) discuss the pros and cons of this approach.

  9. 9.

    The higher the HHI, the lower the competition, and vice versa.

  10. 10.

    It is consistent with the arguments of Herman (1981), Whisler (1984) and Mace (1986) that individual board members are reluctant to step forward and oppose management, because management’s power to select and eject board members affects the behavior of the board. Therefore, the more friendly a director to the CEO the more likely his advice is accepted by the CEO.

References

  • Adams, R., & Ferreira, D. (2007). A theory of friendly boards. Journal of Finance, 62, 217–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, R., & Ferreira, D. (2008). Do directors perform for pay? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 46, 154–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, R., Hermalin, B., & Weibach, M. (2010). The role of boards of directors in corporate governance: a conceptual framework and survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 48, 58–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist, J., & Krueger, A. (1999). Empirical Strategies in Labor Economics. Handbook of Labor Economics (Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds.) 3A, 1277–1366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blair, M. (1995). Ownership and control: Rethinking corporate governance for the twenty-first century. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., & Scharfstein, D. (1996). Optimal debt structure and the number of creditors. Journal of Political Economy, 104, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, B. (1996). Determinants of U.S. outsider director compensation. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 4, 202–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brick, I., Palmon, O., & Wald, J. (2006). CEO compensation, director compensation, and firm performance: evidence of cronyism? Journal of Corporate Finance, 12, 403–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bryan, S., & Klein, A. (2004). Non-management director options, board characteristics, and future firm investments and performance. NYU Working Paper No. 04–009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chambers, E., Foulon, M., Handfield-Jones, H., Hankin, S., & Michaels, E. (1998). The war for talent. McKinsey Quarterly, 3, 44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixon, W. (1960). Simplified estimation from censored normal samples. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 31, 385–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong, G. (2012). Pay more stocks to directors: Theory of corporate governance and board’s compensation. Rutgers University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economist. (2001). A survey by PWC of British boards. The Economist Newspaper, February 10, 68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, K., Friesen, G., & Hersch, P. (2008). How do firms adjust director compensation? Journal of Corporate Finance, 14, 153–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fich, E., & Shivdasani, A. (2005). The impact of stock-option compensation for outside directors on firm value. Journal of Business, 78, 2229–2254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gao, H. (2010). Optimal compensation contracts when managers can hedge. Journal of Financial Economics, 97, 218–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerhart, B., & Milkovich, G. (1990). Organizational differences in managerial compensation and financial performance. Academy of Management Journal, 33, 663–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grullon, G., Kanatas, G., & Kumar, P. (2006). The impact of capital structure on advertising competition: An empirical study. Journal of Business, 79, 3101–3124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guercio, D., Seery, L., & Woidtke, T. (2008). Do boards pay attention when institutional investor activists just vote no. Journal of Financial Economics, 90, 84–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B., & Liebman, J. (1998). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats? Quarterly Journal of Economics., 103, 653–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1978). Some results on incentive contracts with applications to education, insurance, and law enforcement. American Economic Review, 68, 20–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (2008). A theory of board control and size. Review of Financial Studies, 21, 1797–1832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasings, C., Mosteller, F., Tukey, J., & Winsor, C. (1947). Low moments for small samples: A comparative study of order statistics. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 18, 413–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hempel, P., & Fay, C. (1994). Outside director compensation and firm performance. Human Resource Management, 33, 111–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermalin, B., & Weisbach, M. (1998). Endogenously chosen boards of directors and their monitoring of the CEO. American Economic Review, 88, 96–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hermalin, B., & Weisbach, M. (2003). Boards of directors as an endogenously determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Economic Policy Review, 9, 7–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herman, E. (1981). Corporate control, corporate power. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 74–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55, 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). The theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kostovetsky, L. (2009). Human capital flows and the financial industry. University of Rochester Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, P., & Sivaramakrishnan, K. (2008). Who monitors the monitor? The effect of board independence on executive compensation and firm value. Review of Financial Studies, 21, 1371–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard, J. (1990). Executive pay and firm performance. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, 13–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linn, S., & Park, D. (2005). Outside director compensation policy and the investment opportunity set. Journal of Corporate Finance, 11, 680–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorsch, J. (1989). Pawns or potentates. Cambridge: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mace, M. (1986). Directors, myth and reality. Cambridge: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masulis, R., & Nahata, R. (2009). Financial contracting with strategic investors: evidence from corporate venture capital backed IPOs. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 18, 599–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, B. (1995). Natural and Quasi-experiments in Economics. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 13, 151–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Randøy, T., & Jenssen, J. (2004). Board independence and product market competition in Swedish firms. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 12, 281–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, H., & Wiggins, R. (2004). Who is in whose pocket? Director compensation, board independence, and barriers to effective monitoring. Journal of Financial Economics, 73, 497–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadish, W., Cook, T., & Campbell, D. (2001). Experimental and quasi-experimental designs for generalized causal inference. Wadsworth Publishing. Cengage Learning, New York, USA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52, 737–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song, F., & Thakor, A. (2006). Information control, career concerns, and corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 61, 1845–1896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1986). Hierarchies and bureaucracies, on the role of collusion in organization. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 61, 1845–1896.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1992). Collusion and the theory of organization, advances in economic theory. Advances in economic theory: sixth world congress. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tufano, P., & Sevick, M. (1997). Board structure and fee-setting in the U.S. mutual fund industry. Journal of Financial Economics, 46, 321–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vafeas, N. (1999). Determinants of the adoption of director incentive plans. Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, 14, 453–474.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warther, V. (1998). Board effectiveness and board dissent: a model of the board’s relationship to management and shareholders. Journal of Corporate Finance, 4, 53–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whisler, T. (1984). The rules of the game. Homewood: Dow Jones-Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yermack, D. (2004). Remuneration, retention and reputation incentives for outside directors. Journal of Finance, 59, 2281–2308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

I am grateful to conference participants at SEA (Atlanta), SWFA (San Antonio) and WEA (San Diego). I thank Frederick Bereskin, Ivan Brick, Simi Kedia, Yigitcan Karabulut, Jin-Mo Kim, Peter Klein, Tom Nohel, Darius Palia, Abraham Ravid, Nitish Sinha and Tim Zhou for helpful comments. I acknowledge the research financial support from Rutgers University Graduate School and Rutgers Business School. All errors and omissions remain my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gang Nathan Dong .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

We formally develop a model to provide theoretical support for the hypothesis. This model is a one-principal and two-agents model based on the standard principal-agent problem of Holmstrom and Milgrom (1987). The time sequence of this 2-period game is the following. At time 0, shareholders design one compensation contract \( \{ {\phi_m},{\alpha_m}\} \) for the manager and another compensation contract \( \{ {\phi_d},{\alpha_d}\} \) for the outside director. The sharing rules are restricted to the firm’s total final cash flow: \( {\alpha_m} \in [0,1] \) and \( {\alpha_d} \in [0,1] \). At time 1, the manager exerts effort \( {a_m} \) to make business decisions and the outside director exerts effort \( {a_d} \) to monitor the manager. At Time 2, terminal cashflow \( x \) is realized and all claims are settled.

The manager (agent 1) is risk-averse and works as a CEO for a firm owned by a representative shareholder (principal) who is risk-neutral. The director (agent 2) is also risk-averse and works for the same firm. The firm’s final cash flow or profit is \( x \) after deducting initial investment \( I \), and it is the sum of manager’s effort \( {a_m} \), the director’s effort \( {a_d} \) and a noise \( \varepsilon \) term which is normally distributed with mean zero and variance \( {\sigma^2} \): \( x = {a_m} + \rho {a_d} - I + \varepsilon \). Here, \( \rho \in [0,1] \) is a measure of the monitoring effectiveness by the director, \( \rho = 1 \) being very effective and \( \rho = 0 \) having no impact on firm’s outcome. For simplification purposes, we assume zero initial investment cost: \( I = 0 \), the profit function then can be rewritten as: \( x = {a_m} + \rho {a_d} + \varepsilon \).

The manager has an exponential utility function, which depends on the final wealth, the cost of effort and how friendly the director is to the manager: \( {U_m}({w_m},{a_m},{a_d}) = - {e^{{ - {\gamma_m}\left( {{w_m} - \frac{{{c_m}}}{2}{a_m}^2 + \beta {a_d}} \right)}}} \), where \( {\gamma_m} \) is risk-aversion coefficient, \( {a_m} \) is manager’s effort, \( {c_m} > 0 \) is manager’s cost of effort, \( {a_d} \) is the director’s effort, \( \beta \in [ - 1,1] \) is a measure of cooperation between the manager and the director or how friendly the director is to the manager in terms of exchanging information and providing advices, and \( {w_m} \) is total wealth of the manager including wage \( \phi \) and equity (of both stock and option) compensation. With a linear contract as in Holmstrom and Milgrom (1987), the equity compensation can be modeled as a performance based compensation or as a profit-sharing rule \( {\alpha_m} \): \( {w_m} = {\phi_m} + {\alpha_m}x \). The manager receives \( {\alpha_m} \) fraction of the firm’s profit. The manager’s objective function is his certainty equivalent wealth:

$$ {\phi_m} + {\alpha_m}x - \frac{{{c_m}}}{2}{a_m}^2 + \beta {a_d} - \frac{{{\gamma_m}}}{2}{\alpha_m}{\sigma^2} $$
(1)

The manager (agent 1)’s problem is to choose her effort level \( {a_m} \) to maximize his certainty equivalent wealth minus the cost of effort and unfriendliness from the director:

$$ \mathop{{Max}}\limits_{{{a_m}}} \left( {{\phi_m} + {\alpha_m}x - \frac{{{c_m}}}{2}{a_m}^2 + \beta {a_d} - \frac{{{\gamma_m}}}{2}{\alpha_m}{\sigma^2}} \right) $$
(2)

The director has an exponential utility function, which depends on the final wealth and the cost of effort: \( {U_d}({w_m},{a_d}) = - {e^{{ - {\gamma_d}\left( {{w_d} - \frac{{{c_d}}}{2}{a_d}^2} \right)}}} \), where \( {\gamma_d} \) is risk-aversion coefficient, \( {a_d} \) is the director’s effort, \( {c_d} > 0 \) is the director’s cost of effort, and \( {w_d} \) is total wealth of the director including wage \( \phi \) and equity compensations. With a linear contract the equity compensation can be modeled as: \( {w_d} = {\phi_d} + {\alpha_d}x \). The director receives \( {\alpha_d} \) fraction of the firm’s profit. The director’s objective function is his certainty equivalent wealth:

$$ {\phi_d} + {\alpha_d}x - \frac{{{c_d}}}{2}{a_d}^2 - \frac{{{\gamma_d}}}{2}{\alpha_d}{\sigma^2} $$
(3)

The director (agent 2’s) problem is to choose her effort level \( {a_d} \) to maximize his certainty equivalent wealth minus the cost of effort:

$$ \mathop{{Max}}\limits_{{{a_d}}} \left( {{\phi_d} + {\alpha_d}x - \frac{{{c_d}}}{2}{a_d}^2 - \frac{{{\gamma_d}}}{2}{\alpha_d}{\sigma^2}} \right) $$
(4)

The representative shareholder (principal’s) problem is to choose the manager’s profit-sharing rule \( {\alpha_m} \) and the director’s profit-sharing rule \( {\alpha_d} \) to maximize his final payoff subject to incentive compatibility (IC) and participation constraint (PC):

$$ \mathop{{Max}}\limits_{\alpha } E\left[ {x - \left( {{\phi_m} + {\alpha_m}x + {\phi_d} + {\alpha_d}x} \right)} \right] $$
(5)

s.t. \( {a_m} \in \arg \max \left( {{\phi_m} + {\alpha_m}x - \frac{{{c_m}}}{2}{a_m}^2 + \beta {a_d} - \frac{{{\gamma_m}}}{2}{\alpha_m}{\sigma^2}} \right) \) (IC1)

$$ {a_d} \in \arg \max \left( {{\phi_d} + {\alpha_d}x - \frac{{{c_d}}}{2}{a_d}^2 - \frac{{{\gamma_d}}}{2}{\alpha_d}{\sigma^2}} \right) $$
(IC2)
$$ {\phi_m} + {\alpha_m}x - \frac{{{c_m}}}{2}{a_m}^2 + \beta {a_d} - \frac{{{\gamma_m}}}{2}{\alpha_m}{\sigma^2} \ge \underline {{W_m}} $$
(PC1)
$$ {\phi_d} + {\alpha_d}x - \frac{{{c_d}}}{2}{a_d}^2 - \frac{{{\gamma_d}}}{2}{\alpha_d}{\sigma^2} \ge \underline {{W_d}} $$
(PC2)

where \( \underline {{W_m}} \) and \( \underline {{W_d}} \) are the minimum utility level from outside opportunity for manager and director respectively; these two participation constraints always bound such that the inequality becomes equality.

The solutions, comparative statistics and proofs can be found in Dong (2012), and the optimal contract of directors implies: (1) The board director’s equity-based compensation (modeled as profit sharing rule) is positive related to his effectiveness of monitoring and friendliness in advising the CEO; (2) The relationship between the effectiveness of monitoring and the friendliness in advising is negative and convex. This result is similar to Kumar and Sivaramakrishnan (2008) and Adams and Ferreira (2007) which conclude that shareholders can sometime be better off with a friendly board.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dong, G.N. (2012). Pay More Stocks and Options to Directors? Theory and Evidence of Board Compensation. In: Boubaker, S., Nguyen, B., Nguyen, D. (eds) Corporate Governance. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-31579-4_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics