Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Springer Finance ((FINANCE))

  • 3775 Accesses

Abstract

The state price deflators introduced in the previous chapter have several weaknesses such as they do not allow for sufficient modeling flexibility in practice and as they do not provide convincing fits to real data. In the present chapter we introduce the Heath–Jarrow–Morton (HJM) framework which is much more flexible and allows for potentially infinite dimensional term structure curves. Crucial in the HJM framework is the no-arbitrage condition which leads to the so-called HJM term that is analyzed in this chapter. We give explicit examples for the HJM framework in terms of the Cairns forward rate model and of the Teichmann–Wüthrich yield curve prediction model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The data are available on the website of the Swiss National Bank (SNB) www.snb.ch.

References

  1. Bernadell C, Coche J, Nyholm K (2005) Yield curve prediction for the strategic investor. European central bank. Working paper series no 472, April 2005

    Google Scholar 

  2. Brigo D, Mercurio F (2006) Interest rate models—theory and practice, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Cairns AJG (2004) Interest rate models: an introduction. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Christensen JHE, Diebold FX, Rudebusch GD (2007) The affine arbitrage-free class of Nelson–Siegel term structure models. Working paper series 2007-20, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  5. Christensen JHE, Diebold FX, Rudebusch GD (2009) An arbitrage-free generalized Nelson–Siegel term structure model. Econom J, R Econ Soc 12(3):C33–C64

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Diebold FX, Li C (2006) Forecasting the term structure of government bond yields. J Econom 130:337–364

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Filipović D (1999) A note on the Nelson–Siegel family. Math Finance 9(4):349–359

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Filipović D (2000) Exponential-polynomial families and the term structure of interest rates. Bernoulli 6(6):1–27

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  9. Filipović D (2009) Term-structure models. A graduate course. Springer, Berlin

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Flesaker B, Hughston L (1996) Positive interest. Risk 9:46–49

    Google Scholar 

  11. Flesaker B, Hughston L (1997) Dynamic models for yield curve evolution. In: Dempster MAH, Pliska SR (eds) Mathematics of derivative securities. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 294–314

    Google Scholar 

  12. Heath D, Jarrow R, Morton A (1992) Bond pricing and the term structure of interest rates: a new methodology for contingent claim valuation. Econometrica 60(1):77–105

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Nelson CR, Siegel AF (1987) Parsimonious modeling of yield curves. J Bus 60(4):473–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Ortega JP, Pullirsch R, Teichmann J, Wergieluk J (2009) A dynamic approach for scenario generation in risk management. Preprint on arXiv

    Google Scholar 

  15. Svensson LEO (1994) Estimating and interpreting forward interest rates: Sweden 1992–1994. NBER working paper series nr 4871

    Google Scholar 

  16. Svensson LEO (1995) Estimating forward interest rates with the extended Nelson & Siegel method. Sver Riksbank Q Rev 3:13–26

    Google Scholar 

  17. Teichmann J, Wüthrich MV (2013) Consistent yield curve prediction. Preprint, ETH Zurich

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Proofs of Chap. 4

Appendix: Proofs of Chap. 4

In this section we prove the statements of Chap. 4. We start with the proof of Theorem 4.1. In a first step we re-express the ZCB price process in terms of the spot rate process .

Lemma 4.13

In the discrete time HJM framework (4.1), we have under the equivalent martingale measure \(\mathbb{P}^{\ast}\) for the ZCB price process

$$ \log P(t,m) =\log P(0,m)+\sum_{s=1}^{t} \Biggl[r_{s-1}+\sum_{u=s+1}^{m}- \alpha(s,u) -\mathbf{v}(s,m)~ \boldsymbol{\varepsilon}^\ast_{s} \Biggr], $$

for 0≤tm.

Proof

The proof is analogous to the continuous time case (see, e.g., Filipović [67], Lemma 7.1.1). The goal essentially is to rearrange the terms such that forward rates are expressed in terms of spot rates. We calculate the logarithm of the ZCB price for 0<tm

Next we use the definition of v and we rewrite the last term (using (4.3))

This proves the lemma. □

Proof of Theorem 4.1

For the bank account numeraire discounted price process Lemma 4.13 provides

$$ B_t^{-1}{P(t,m)} =P(0,m)~\exp \Biggl\{\sum _{s=1}^{t} \Biggl[\sum_{u=s+1}^{m}- \alpha(s,u) -\mathbf{v}(s,m) \boldsymbol{\varepsilon}^\ast_{s} \Biggr] \Biggr\}. $$

Consistency property (4.4) w.r.t. \(\mathbb {P}^{\ast}\) implies that this discounted price process needs to be a \((\mathbb {P}^{\ast},\mathbb{F} )\)-martingale, that is, we require

In view of the above expression for \(B_{t}^{-1}P(t,m)\) this gives under the finiteness assumption in (4.6) the requirement

This means that \(\sum_{u=t+1}^{m}\alpha(t,u)=h(t,m)\) for 0<t<m. For 0<t=m−1 we therefore obtain

$$ \alpha(m-1,m)=h(m-1,m), $$

and for 0<t<m−1

$$ \alpha(t,m)= \sum_{u=t+1}^{m} \alpha(t,u) - \sum_{u=t+1}^{m-1} \alpha(t,u)=h(t,m)-h(t,m-1). $$

Note that h(t,t)=0, proving the claim. □

Next we prove Theorem 4.5. We start with a preliminary lemma.

Lemma 4.14

We have

$$ \sum_{s=t}^{m-1} \sum _{u=1}^s \boldsymbol{\sigma}(u,s+1) \boldsymbol{ \varepsilon}_u^\ast = \sum_{u=1}^t \bigl[\mathbf{v}(u,m)-\mathbf{v}(u,t) \bigr] \boldsymbol{\varepsilon}_u^\ast+ \sum_{u=t+1}^{m-1} \mathbf{v}(u,m) \boldsymbol{ \varepsilon}_u^\ast. $$

Proof

Rearranging the terms provides

This proves the claim. □

Proof of Theorem 4.5

First we rewrite the spot rate. We have because of (4.13) and Lemma 4.14 that

Since the price process of the ZCB needs to be consistent w.r.t. \(\mathbb{P}^{\ast}\), see (4.4), we obtain from Corollary 2.19

The last expected value can be calculated explicitly, providing for an appropriate constant k 3

$$ P(t,m) =\frac{P(0,m)}{P(0,t)} ~ \exp \Biggl\{-k_3- \sum _{u=1}^t \bigl[\mathbf{v}(u,m)-\mathbf{v}(u,t) \bigr] \boldsymbol{\varepsilon}_u^\ast \Biggr\}. $$

So there remains the calculations of the constants k 1,k 2,k 3. We have, see Theorem 4.2,

where in the last equality we define g(u,s)=α(u,s+1) to be the term under the summation. From this we can calculate k 2 similar to Lemma 4.14 and obtain

Moreover, we have

This implies that

$$ k_2= \frac{1}{2}~ \sum_{u=1}^{t} \bigl[ \bigl \Vert \mathbf{v}(u,m)\bigr \Vert ^2 -\bigl \Vert \mathbf{v}(u,t)\bigr \Vert ^2 \bigr] + \frac{1}{2}~\sum _{u=t+1}^{m-1} \bigl \Vert \mathbf{v}(u,m)\bigr \Vert ^2. $$

For k 3, using the independence and multivariate Gaussian distribution of \(\boldsymbol{\varepsilon }_{u}^{\ast}\) (with independent components), we obtain

This implies

$$ k_3=k_2-\frac{1}{2}~ \sum _{u=t+1}^{m-1} \bigl \Vert \mathbf{v}(u,m)\bigr \Vert ^2 =\frac{1}{2}~ \sum_{u=1}^{t} \bigl[ \bigl \Vert \mathbf{v}(u,m)\bigr \Vert ^2 -\bigl \Vert \mathbf{v}(u,t)\bigr \Vert ^2 \bigr]. $$

This proves the theorem. □

Proof of Theorem 4.8

\(\mathbb{P}^{\ast}\)-consistency implies

Solving this requirement and using the Gaussian properties of \(\boldsymbol{\varepsilon}^{\ast}_{t}\) under \(\mathbb{P}^{\ast}\) proves the claim. □

Proof of Theorem 4.12

In the first step we apply the tower property for conditional expectation which decouples the problem into several steps. We have . Thus, we need to calculate the inner conditional expectation of the d×d matrix S (K)(y). We define the auxiliary matrix

$$ \widetilde{C}_{(K)} = \bigl( \bigl[ \varsigma(\mathbf{R}_{\delta k,-})^{-1}~ \boldsymbol{\varUpsilon}_{\delta k} \bigr]_j \bigr)_{j=1,\ldots, d; ~k=1, \ldots, K}\in\mathbb{R}^{d\times K}. $$

This implies that we can rewrite \(C_{(K)}= K^{-1/2}~\widetilde{C}_{(K)}\). Moreover, we rewrite the matrix \(\widetilde{C}_{(K)}\) as follows

$$ \widetilde{C}_{(K)}= \bigl[\widetilde{C}_{(K-1)}, \varsigma( \mathbf{R}_{\delta K,-})^{-1}~ \boldsymbol{\varUpsilon}_{\delta K} \bigr], $$

where \(\widetilde{C}_{(K-1)}\in\mathbb{R}^{d\times(K-1)}\) is -measurable. This gives the following decomposition

This implies for the conditional expectation of S (K)(y)

To calculate the conditional expectation in the last term, we start with the conditional covariance. From Corollary 4.10 we obtain

This implies

Iterating this provides the result. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Wüthrich, M.V., Merz, M. (2013). Stochastic Forward Rate and Yield Curve Modeling. In: Financial Modeling, Actuarial Valuation and Solvency in Insurance. Springer Finance. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-31392-9_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics