Skip to main content

Modelling Supply Functions Using Linear Programming

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 2668 Accesses

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

Abstract

This last chapter provides an example of how to integrate the production economic theory presented in the first ten chapters of this book and the Linear Programming approach presented in the last three chapters. The example shows how is it possible to use Linear Programming to numerically generate the output supply function of the firm. This approach has shown to be a suitable modelling unit in a sector modelling context, in which the supplies from the individual firms are aggregated into the total industry supply.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For further details on the context in which this modeling approach can be used, see Rasmussen (2007).

  2. 2.

    Output other than the main product y.

  3. 3.

    Marginal cost is the shadow price of the restriction y j  = f j (x 1,…, x N , z 1, …, z K ) ≥ Y j in (21.8), which is provided as output from most mathematical programming software.

  4. 4.

    Or rather, expected marginal revenue.

  5. 5.

    For convenience the index for farms j is dropped.

  6. 6.

    In the present example, r(y) = {(x 1, z 1) , …, (x S, z S)}.

  7. 7.

    As defined here, there is only one production process for each netput x n . As with the output y, one could include the possibility of having additional scale specific production plans for production of each netput. To keep things simple this has not been done here. (If needed, the extension is straight forward).

References

  • Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1972). Process analysis and the neoclassical theory of the production function. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 54, 279–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, B., Petersen, B. M., Berntsen, J., Boye, C., Sørensen, C. G., Søgaard, H. T., & Hansen, J. P. (1998). An integrated economic and environmental farm simulation model (FASSET). Copenhagen: Statens Jordbrugs- og Fiskeriøkonomiske Institut.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, S. (2007). Agricultural sector modelling. A micro-based approach based on mathematical programming. FOI Working Paper nr. 10, Institute of Food and Resource Economics, University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, R. E. (2012). GAMS – a user’s guide. Washington, DC, USA: GAMS Development Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Svend Rasmussen .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Rasmussen, S. (2013). Modelling Supply Functions Using Linear Programming. In: Production Economics. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-30200-8_21

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-30200-8_21

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-30199-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-30200-8

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics