Skip to main content

Consistency of Linear Forecasts in a Nonlinear Stochastic Economy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Global Analysis of Dynamic Models in Economics and Finance

Abstract

The notion of consistent expectations equilibrium is extended to economies that are described by a nonlinear stochastic system. Agents in the model do not know the nonlinear law of motion and use a simple linear forecasting rule to form their expectations. Along a stochastic consistent expectations equilibrium (SCEE), these expectations are correct in a linear statistical sense, i.e., the unconditional mean and autocovariances of the actual (but unknown) nonlinear stochastic process coincide with those of the linear stochastic process on which the agents base their beliefs. In general, the linear forecasts do not coincide with the true conditional expectation, but an SCEE is an ‘approximate rational expectations equilibrium’ in the sense that forecasting errors are unbiased and uncorrelated. Adaptive learning of SCEE is studied in an overlapping generations framework.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The model in Grandmont (1985) is deterministic such that REE are actually perfect foresight equilibria.

  2. 2.

    See, e.g., Box, Jenkins, and Reinsel (1994) for a discussion of these definitions.

  3. 3.

    Dynamical systems which are uniformly expanding – such as (4) – typically have ‘nice’ invariant probability measures; see, e.g., Lasota and Mackey (1985).

  4. 4.

    Note that stationarity of the first two moments does not necessarily imply stationarity of the process itself.

  5. 5.

    See also Hommes and Sorger (1998, footnote 2).

  6. 6.

    By ‘non-degenerate’ we mean that it has positive variance.

  7. 7.

    The OLS-estimate for α is identical to (14). The OLS-estimate for β is slightly different from (15), namely \({\beta }_{t-1} = [\sum\limits_{i=0}^{t-2}({p}_{i} -\bar{ {p}}_{t-1}^{-})({p}_{i+1} -\bar{ {p}}_{t-1}^{+})]/[\sum\limits_{i=0}^{t-2}{({p}_{i} -\bar{ {p}}_{t-1}^{-})}^{2}]\) for t ≥ 3, where \(\bar{{p}}_{t-1}^{-} = [1/(t - 1)]\sum\limits_{i=0}^{t-2}{p}_{i}\) and \(\bar{{p}}_{t-1}^{+} = [1/(t - 1)]\sum\limits_{i=1}^{t-1}{p}_{i}\).

  8. 8.

    Here we mean orbital convergence, that is, the existence of a 2-cycle \(\{{p}_{1}^{{_\ast}},{p}_{2}^{{_\ast}}\}\) such that \(\lim_{t\rightarrow +\infty }{p}_{2t} = {p}_{1}^{{_\ast}}\) and \(\lim_{t\rightarrow +\infty }{p}_{2t+1} = {p}_{2}^{{_\ast}}\), or vice versa. Since \({p}_{1}^{{_\ast}}\neq {p}_{2}^{{_\ast}}\) the sequence \({({p}_{t})}_{t=0}^{+\infty }\) is not convergent in the usual sense.

  9. 9.

    The case β = 0 must excluded since for β = 0 there is no dynamics in (11). Sorger (1998) presents an example of an OG-model of a more general form than (8) for which a chaotic CEE with β = 0 exists.

  10. 10.

    Because the model is deterministic, REE are equivalent to perfect foresight equilibria.

  11. 11.

    We have chosen F to be symmetric around 0 but, without loss of generality, we could have chosen F to be symmetric around any fixed point α.

  12. 12.

    See also Medio and Raines (2007) and Gardini, Hommes, Tramontana, and de Vilder (2009) for an extensive discussion and characterization of the forward perfect foresight dynamics in the case of a non-monotonic offer curve.

  13. 13.

    The name ‘noisy 2-cycle’ SCEE captures the feature that price fluctuations look like a noisy 2-cycle. In Sect. 5.3 we will see that the underlying (deterministic) limiting law of motion of this economy has indeed a stable 2-cycle.

  14. 14.

    Note that a steady state SCEE is also an REE.

  15. 15.

    The reader should have a look at the time series of the learning parameters α t and β t in Figs. 6–8 again. In these simulations, in the initial phase of the learning process \(1.8 \leq {\alpha }_{t} \leq 3\), whereas \(-0.6 \leq {\beta }_{t} \leq -0.2\).

  16. 16.

    For example, for the initial state \(({p}_{0},{\alpha }_{0},{\beta }_{0}) = (2.25, 2.25,-1)\) as in the simulation of the ‘noisy 2-cycle’ SCEE in Fig. 8, for different realizations of the random shocks η t we have indeed also observed converge to the steady state SCEE of Fig. 6. OLS-learning in this model exhibits the same type of path dependence.

  17. 17.

    See also Jungeilges (2007) for a similar example in the cobweb framework, where under SAC-learning the first order sample autocorrelation coefficient may converge to its correct value β while higher order sample autocorrelation coefficients need not converge to the correct values βj. In a related paper Tuinstra (2003) shows that, under OLS-learning in an OG-model with money growth and inflation, ‘beliefs equilibria’ may arise where the first order autocorrelation coefficient converges while prices fluctuate on a quasi-periodic or chaotic attractor. A beliefs equilibrium is in fact a first order CEE, where agents have fitted the correct regression line to a quasi-periodic or chaotic attractor.

  18. 18.

    The first order autocorrelation coefficient is significant, but recall that first order autocorrelation can not be exploited, since agents have to make a 2-period ahead forecast.

  19. 19.

    The scatter plot technique works very well for 1-dimensional systems but becomes less informative for higher-dimensional systems. Brock, Hsieh, and LeBaron (1991), Brock and Dechert (1991) and Barnett et al. (1998) contain extensive discussions of the sensitivity to increasing dimension and the sensitivity to noise of nonlinear time series embedding methods.

References

  • Arthur, W. B., Ermoliev. Y. M., & Kaniovski, Y. (1987). Path-dependent processes and the emergence of macro-structure. European Journal of Operational Research,30, 294–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, W. A., Gallant, A. R., Hinich, M. J., Jungeilges, J. A., Kaplan, D. T., & Jensen, M. J. (1998). A single-blind controlled competition among tests for nonlinearity and chaos. Journal of Econometrics,82, 157–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm, V., & Wenzelburger, J. (1999). Expectations, forecasting, and perfect foresight – A dynamical systems approach. Macroeconomic Dynamics,3, 167–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box, G. E. P., Jenkins, G. M., & Reinsel, G. C. (1994). Time series analysis. Forecasting and control (3rd ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch, W., & McGough, B. (2005). Consistent expectations and misspecification in stochastic non-linear economies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,29, 659–676.

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch, W. A. (2006). Restricted perceptions equilibria and learning in macroeconomics. In D. Colander (Ed.), PostWalrasian macroeconomics: Beyond the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 135–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bray, M. M. (1982). Learning, estimation, and the stability of rational expectations. Journal of Economic Theory,26, 318–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bray, M. M., & Savin, N. E. (1986). Rational expectations equilibria, learning, and model specification. Econometrica,54, 1129–1160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., & Dechert, W. D. (1991). Nonlinear dynamical systems: Instability and chaos in economics. In W. Hildenbrand & H. Sonnenschein (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics IV. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., & Hommes, C. H. (1997). A rational route to randomness. Econometrica,65, 1059–1095.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., & Hommes, C. H. (1998). Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,22, 1235–1274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., Hsieh, D.A., & LeBaron, B. (1991). Nonlinear dynamics, chaos and instability: Statistical theory and economic evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullard, J. (1994). Learning equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory,64, 468–485.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullard, J., & Duffy, J. (1998). Learning and the stability of cycles. Macroeconomic Dynamics,2, 22–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullard, J., & Duffy, J. (2001). Learning and excess volatility. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 5(2), 272–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devaney, R. L. (1989). An introduction to chaotic dynamical systems (2nd ed.). Redwood City, NJ: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G. W., & Honkapohja, S. (1994). On the local stability of sunspot equilibria under adaptive learning rules. Journal of Economic Theory,64, 142–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G. W., & Honkapohja, S. (1995). Local convergence of recursive learning to steady states and cycles in stochastic nonlinear models. Econometrica,63, 195–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G. W., & Honkapohja, S. (2001). Learning in macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardini, L., Hommes, C. Tramontana, F., & de Vilder, R. (2009). Forward and backward dynamics in implicitly defined overlapping generations models. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,71, 110–129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grandmont, J.-M. (1985). On endogenous competitive business cycles. Econometrica,53, 995–1045.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grandmont, J.-M. (1998). Expectations formation and stability in large socio-economic systems. Econometrica,66, 741–781.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guesnerie, R. (2001). Assessing rational expectations: Sunspot multiplicity and economic fluctuations. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes, C. H. (1998). On the consistency of backward-looking expectations: The case of the cobweb. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,33, 333–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes, C. H., & Rosser, J. B. (2001). Consistent expectations equilibria and complex dynamics in renewable resource markets. Macroeconomic Dynamics,5, 180–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes, C. H., & Sorger, G. (1998). Consistent expectations equilibria. Macroeconomic Dynamics,2, 287–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes, C. H., & Zhu, M. (2011). Behavioral learning equilibria (Technical Report, CeNDEF Working Paper). University of Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jungeilges, J. (2007). On chaotic consistent expectations equilibria. Analyse and Kritik,29, 269–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, M. (1994). On rational belief equilibria. Economic Theory,4, 859–876.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lasota, A., & Mackey, M. C. (1985). Probabilistic properties of deterministic systems. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lasota, A. & Mackey, M. C. (1994). Applied Mathematical Sciences: Vol. 97. Chaos, fractals and noise. Stochastic aspects of dynamics (2nd ed.). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1971). Econometric testing of the natural rate hypothesis, In O. Eckstein (Ed.), The econometrics of price determination Conference. Washington DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Social Science Research Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marcet, A., & Nicolini, J. P. (2003). Recurrent hyperinflations and learning. American Economic Review,93, 1476–1498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marcet, A., & Sargent, T. J. (1989). Convergence of least squares learning in mechanisms in self referential linear stochastic models. Journal of Economic Theory,48, 337–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marimon, R., Spear, S. E., & Sunder, S. (1993). Expectationally driven market volatility: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Theory,61, 74–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medio, A., & Raines, B. (2007). Backward dynamics in economics. the inverse limit approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,31, 1633–1671.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica,29, 315–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nerlove, M., Grether, D. M., & Carvalho, J. L. (1979). Analysis of economic time series: A sythesis. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sakai, H., & Tokumaru, H. (1980). Autocorrelations of a certain chaos. IEEE Transactions on Acoustics, Speech and Signal Processing,28, 588–590.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J. (1993). Bounded rationality in macroeconomics. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J. (1999). The conquest of American inflation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schönhofer, M. (1999). Chaotic learning equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory,89, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sögner, L., & Mitlöhner, H. (2002). Consistent expectations equilibria and learning in a stock market. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,26, 171–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorger, G. (1998). Imperfect foresight and chaos: An example of a self-fulfilling mistake. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,33, 363–383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N. L., & Lucas, R. E. (1989). Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuinstra, J. (2003). Beliefs equilibria in an overlapping generations model. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,50, 145–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuinstra, J., & Wagener, F. (2007). On learning equilibria. Economic Theory,30, 493–513.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (1990). Learning to believe in sunspots. Econometrica,58, 277–307.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Earlier versions of this paper have been presented at the IFAC symposium Computational Economics, Finance and Engineering, Barcelona, July 6–8, 2000, the CeNDEF workshops on Economic Dynamics, Amsterdam, January 4–6, 2001 and Leiden, June 17–28, 2002, the 8th Viennese workshop on Optimal Control, Dynamic Games and Nonlinear Dynamics, Vienna, May 14–16, 2003 as well as various department seminars. Stimulating discussions with participants are gratefully acknowledged. In particular, we would like to thank Buz Brock, Jim Bullard, George Evans, Jean-Michel Grandmont and Seppo Honkapohja for stimulating discussions. This research has been supported by the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cars Hommes .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hommes, C., Sorger, G., Wagener, F. (2013). Consistency of Linear Forecasts in a Nonlinear Stochastic Economy. In: Bischi, G., Chiarella, C., Sushko, I. (eds) Global Analysis of Dynamic Models in Economics and Finance. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-29503-4_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-29503-4_10

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-29502-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-29503-4

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics