Skip to main content

Data and Fiscal Institutions of the Surveyed Countries

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Tax Progression in OECD Countries

Abstract

This chapter describes the data base and provides a detailed survey of the fiscal and social institutions of the countries examined in this book. It is explained how the authors dealt with the LIS microdata and how they rearranged the original data sets to make them suitable for computations. In order to make the relatively complex computations feasible and efficient, while preserving the required level of precision, the data was grouped into 5 percent quantiles. A pre-requisite for embarking on the data analysis is a thorough review of the fiscal and social institutions in the 13 surveyed countries (Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Israel, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, Taiwan, the United Kingdom, and the United States), which is given in the second section of the chapter.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For more information about the LIS database see Smeeding et al. (1985), Smeeding (2004), and Atkinson (2004). For illustrative examples of applications of the LIS database see, e.g., Allegrezza et al. (2004), Bardasi (2004), Bronchetti and Sullivan (2003), Gornick (2004), Förster and Vleminckx (2004), and Mahler and Jesuit (2006). For our purposes, the LIS data provide the most accurate information. Concerning comparisons with other data sets, the differences, for instance with respect to the calculation of Gini coefficients, are only minor; see OECD, Growing Unequal (2008, pp. 39 and 52). As of 2003, LIS has been complemented by the Luxembourg Wealth Study (LWS); see Sierminska et al. (2006). Note that the LWS contains also income data; for instance, Japanese income data are only found under this heading.

  2. 2.

    Wave VII is currently under construction. Thus, more or less complete data are only available up to Wave VI, but these data are subject to repeated revisions. This explains why we decided to work with the data of Wave V. Moreover, even these data experience revisions from time to time. Hence, we had to settle on a particular deadline for available LIS data, which was September 2010. After this date, there were minor data revisions for Canada Wave V (November 2010) and the United States Wave V (February 2011), which did not affect variables important to us. For Germany, there was a major data revision in December 2010. To take account of this change, we re-computed all results involving Germany using the revised data set, so that they are based on the most recent German data revision.

  3. 3.

    According to the title of this study, we ought to have included only OECD member countries. Israel became a member of OECD in 2010. The member status does not strictly apply to Taiwan; Taiwan gained an OECD observer status in 2002. We included Taiwan because she represents an economy largely different from the other countries considered, and because full data sets are available only for few countries. Moreover, Taiwan is remarkable because she has a low-tax and high-progression direct tax schedule and a low-progression schedule for direct taxes plus payroll taxes.

  4. 4.

    This means that taxes include so-calledclawbacks. i.e., taxes which return to government part of the transfer. Prasad and Deng (2009, p. 439) remark: “This means that where transfers are high, taxes on transfers may be high, but this is not ‘true’ tax, simply a reduction in the amount of transfer given. To achieve a measure of true tax paid, then, the amount of clawbacks should be subtracted from the total tax paid.” (See also Verbist 2005.) However, we opine that clawbacks are an integral part of the tax system. In contrast to Prasad and Deng (2009) we also do not consider indirect taxes in our investigations.

  5. 5.

    For the delineation of taxes and social security contributions with respect to Australia and Denmark see also Footnotes 20 and 33 in this Chapter.

  6. 6.

    Some data sets are censored in the way that negative incomes (mainly losses of certain income sources and losses carried forward from past years) are reported as zeros. Hence, we decided to leave out all entries which are nonpositive with respect to either GI or DPI or both. Moreover, inclusion of losses would have diluted the analysis of tax progression.

  7. 7.

    Recall that Israel became an OECD member only in 2010, Taiwan became an OECD observer in 2002. Hence, both countries are not covered by OECD, Growing Unequal (2008).

  8. 8.

    This does not mean that there are no social security subsidies present, but that they are paid as an aggregate to respective institutions rather than directly to individuals. For instance, about one third of the expenses for German old age pensions comes from federal funds, but it is paid to the respective authority rather than directly to individuals.

  9. 9.

    Taking the example of a Belgian income tax reform in 1988, Decoster and van Camp (1998) investigated the differences of taking the administrative definition of the fiscal units on the one hand and the families on the other. Although they found some deviations, the basic results were robust with respect to the unit of observation.

  10. 10.

    Perhaps this might explain why Peichl and Schäfer (2008, p. 16) (using the Suits measure of tax progression) did not find major differences between statutory and effective tax progression for gross incomes.

  11. 11.

    As compared to other empirical work, this is a rather fine grid. Sala-i-Martin (2006, pp. 355 and 357), for instance, had to work with quintiles and had to resort to widespread data interpolations for carrying out his ambitious study. Bishop et al. (1991a, p. 464) worked with deciles for their construction of Lorenz curves, arguing that “increasing the number of quantiles does not necessarily improve the quality of the overall test” (p. 476, Footnote 5). A completely different approach was used by Duncan and Sabirianova Peter (2008) and by Sabirianova Peter et al. (2010). Since they did not find a way to disentangle the influence of the income distribution on tax revenue, they largely relied on the tax schedule alone. To capture the distribution of taxable incomes, they used the interval from zero to the fourfold per-capita GDP of the respective countries, and divided it by 100. Then the tax was calculated for each income corresponding to the resulting percentiles. This approach suffers from the fact that per-capita GDP multiples do not form representative income tax bases.

  12. 12.

    Recall from p. 54 that by this procedure we excludere-ranking resulting from the application of equivalence scales.

  13. 13.

    By q-curves [p-curves] we mean the discrete analogues of the curves defined by (4.35)–(4.37) [(4.38)–(4.39)].

  14. 14.

    See Gastwirth and Glauberman (1976) for errors in estimating Lorenz curves when grouped data are used instead of individual data.

  15. 15.

    Anderson et al. (2008, p. 3) report that in 2007, CEOs of S&P 500 firms pocketed on average 344 times the pay of an average American worker. Furthermore, they argue that the gap between CEOs and minimum wage workers runs even wider. In 2007, CEOs averaged 866 times as much as minimum wage employees. See also the extensive list of CEO remuneration by Executive Paywatch, downloadable from http://www.aflcio.org/corporatewatch/paywatch/ceou/database.cfm. label ceo

  16. 16.

    In their comprehensive study of 143 countries from 1981 to 2005, Duncan and Sabirianova Peter (2008) observed decreasing Gini coefficients from 1981 to the mid-nineties, and decreasing Gini coefficients in the last decade to 2005; in their study comprising 189 countries from 1981 to 2005, Sabirianova Peter et al. (2010) observed considerably decreasing income tax progression throughout taking an average over all countries. Note, however, that their analyses did not take into account the income distribution.

  17. 17.

    Israel is not included in Table 5.3 because she became an OECD member only in 2010, and Taiwan has only the status of an OECD observer since 2002.

  18. 18.

    Using OECD data, Tachibanaki (1981) provided also largely implausible results for tax progression for ten OECD countries.

  19. 19.

    This means that married couples pay taxes twice the tax on the half household income, which implies a significant attenuation of tax progression as compared to taxation of individuals.

  20. 20.

    In Australia, there is a Medical Care Levy amounting to 1.5 percent of taxable income, which is, however, collected along with the income tax and is treated as a separate part of the income tax by the LIS data, akin to the German Solidaritätszuschlag of the income tax. In Denmark there is a flat rate contribution for the supplementary pension scheme amounting to DKK 894/year in 1999 [about € 10/month] and a small flat contribution for the unemployment insurance.

  21. 21.

    The conversion of household data into equivalized data occurs through division by \({m}^{\alpha } \geq 1\). Hence, when household data are nondecreasing in \(m\), then the household data for \(m > 1\) are divided by a divisor which is greater than one. This means that household data are relatively more diminished the greater they are. They move closer together, which causes their distributions to become more equal. However, if household data are on average decreasing functions of household size \(m\), then smaller data are divided by divisors greater than one, and the respective distribution of equivalized data becomes more unequal. This may be the case of substantial tax benefits for bigger families (recall that we re-ordered all equivalized data according to equivalized gross incomes), which may in exceptional cases carry over to equivalized data of net incomes. It may also be the case if households with high incomes have substantially less children than households with small incomes, which causes a more unequal distribution of gross equivalized incomes, which may carry over to other equivalized data as well. Note, however, that most commonly household data are nondecreasing functions of \(m\).

  22. 22.

    Tables tec00018 and tec00019.

  23. 23.

    See also Cnossen (2000), Sørensen (2010), and Kleinbard (2010).

  24. 24.

    Trabandt and Uhlig (2010) showed that additional taxation of labor yields much higher relative increase in tax revenue than additional taxation of capital.

  25. 25.

    Note that international competition enforced this move also from the fiscal policy of countries which did not adopt a DIT. Starting from 1986, Corneo (2005, p. 181) noticed for Germany a gradual shift of the factor incidence of income taxation from capital to labor.

  26. 26.

    This can be accomplished either under the gross-asset method mainly adopted by Norway, or under the net-asset method mainly adopted by Finland and Sweden. For details see Sørensen (2010, pp. 12–16).

  27. 27.

    It may sound strange that, on the one hand, it is argued that there are no mandatory employer social security contributions, whereas, on the other hand, there are mandatory superannuation contributions. According to Australian legislation, superannuation contributions are considered to be “private savings generated through compulsory contributions,” since these contributions accrue as individual claims of employees for retirement rather than as contributions to public funds. Hence, the legal character of superannuation is an additional mandatory part of wages or salaries which has to be put aside for later supplementing old age pensions.

  28. 28.

    Whiteford (2010, p. 531) demonstrated that Australia is leading in income-tested cash transfers among 30 countries.

  29. 29.

    The Medicare Levy had developed originally from an employee’s mandatory social security contribution; later on it was shifted to the central government income tax category.

  30. 30.

    According to LIS Data Information of Wave V for Australia, the data collection period extended from July 2000 to July 2001. This means that the LIS data for Wave V of Australia are based on the New Tax System.

  31. 31.

    In Australia, the term Commonwealth refers to the Federal Government.

  32. 32.

    The Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) publishes Gini coefficients only for equivalized disposable incomes and the figures in column 3 of Table 5.3 do not seem reliable. Saunders (2003) based his computations on unpublished ABS data.

  33. 33.

    Note that OECD, Taxing Wages (2001, p. 258) correctly considers this impost as a social security contribution, although the Danish Revenue Statistics classifies it as part of the income tax. LIS, however, follows the Danish Revenue Statistics and counts it as part of the income tax.

  34. 34.

    The OECD, Tax Policy Reform (2010, pp. 111–3), report is enthusiastic about the ongoing Danish tax reform launched in 2010. It aims at a substantial reduction of the top marginal tax rates and a moderate reduction of the marginal tax rates of the bottom income strata. This reform is to be financed by broadening the tax base, in particular by substantially reducing tax deductability of interest for the personal income tax exceeding DKK 50,000 (DKK 100,000 for married couples).

  35. 35.

    This means that this allowance does not apply to pensions and social security benefits.

  36. 36.

    Until 2004 Statistics Finland used the ‘old’ OECDequivalence scales, viz. the weight 1 for the first adult in a household, 0.7 for further adults, and 0.5 for children aged between 0 and 17 years.

  37. 37.

    The German income tax schedules for the period 1958–2005 are downloadable as “Tarifgeschichte” from the website of the German Bundesministerium der Finanzen.

  38. 38.

    For the sake of comparability the figures are given in terms of euros.

  39. 39.

    For a comprehensive survey of the German income tax based on the statutory tax schedules for the time from 1958 to 2005 see Corneo (2005).

  40. 40.

    Bach et al. (2009, p. 311, Table 2) report that, out of 45.16 million of potential tax units in 2001, only 29.1 million filed tax returns. This means that only 64.4 percent of potential tax units actually filed tax returns, leaving an estimated 35.6 percent of non-filers. Social security old age pensions enjoyed preferential tax treatment. This preferential tax treatment of old age pensions was changed as of 2005. Since 2005 old age pensions are subject to taxation, however, with long transitional provisions allowing for lower taxation for old age pensioners in accordance with the starting year of their old age pension. The pensions of civil servants were ever fully taxable.

  41. 41.

    This status was later changed effective from 2005.

  42. 42.

    The term “new countries” refers to the area of the former German Democratic Republic and the term “old countries” refers to the area of the former Federal Republic of Germany.

  43. 43.

    As we did not find a clear-cut report of the Israeli tax and social security system prevailing in 2001, we had to compile it from various sources. Moreover, note that the Israeli tax system was thoroughly reformed as of January \({1}^{\mathrm{st}}\), 2003.

  44. 44.

    The regular rate of employees (4.9 percent) is split among the different branches of National Insurance in the following way: 2.7 percent for old-age and survivors, 1.3 percent for disability, 0.1 percent for long-term care, 0.6 percent for maternity, 0.15 percent for unemployment, and 0.05 percent for accident injury; similar breakdowns apply to all other rates.

  45. 45.

    Note that the Dutch government had launched a major tax reform effective of 2001. See the OECD Report on Netherlands for 2000, pp. 44–51, and the OECD Report on Netherlands for 2002, pp. 45–8.

  46. 46.

    The OECD Report on Netherlands for 2000, p. 49, specifies: “In the Dutch tax system the owner-occupier is fully taxed on the imputed rents (huurwaardeforfait) after deduction of expenses, such as mortgage interest. However, in practice, imputed rents—in most cases 1.25 percent of the property’s value—are well below market rents, whereas interest deductions are allowed at the actual rates, thus providing homeowners with a substantial benefit. As a result, in 1998, homeowners deducted around € 13 billion from their taxable income for mortgage interest, reducing their tax liabilities by about € 6.5 billion, whereas they paid only around € 2 billion in taxes on their imputed rent.”

  47. 47.

    According to the OECD Report on Netherlands for 2000, pp. 82–3, only about 60 percent of the population is covered by this insurance; 30 percent of the population has private health insurance, and civil servants are statutory insured.

  48. 48.

    The low average tax rates are caused by generous tax allowances; see also Footnote 46 in CChap. 5.

  49. 49.

    For an excellent survey of the Norwegian tax system see Kleinbard (2010, pp. 53–83); for a survey of the contemporary Norwegian tax system see http://www.kpmg.no/arch/_img/9484126.pdf.

  50. 50.

    On housing only 50 percent of the capital gains are taxable, and this can be deferred in case of purchase of an equivalent property within 12 months. Sale of other private real estate is taxable only if the profit is more than SEK 50,000.

  51. 51.

    For the self-employed the rate is so high because they have also to pay the majority of employer social security contributions which cover basically the same items but are a bit higher, viz. 32.52 percent, in addition to the payroll tax of 24.25 percent (16.16 percent for persons older than 65 years).

  52. 52.

    In their analysis for Australia, Canada, Sweden, and the United States, Bishop et al. (1990, Appendix, Fig. 3) showed that Sweden had the least progressive tax and transfer system assuming the conditional postfisc progressivity orderings of all four countries under investigation. For their approach see Footnote 2 in Chap.1.

  53. 53.

    The Institutional Information for 2000 on Taiwan’s income tax régime as given by the LIS Database is wrong. There it is assured that the tax schedule presented in the Institutional Information should apply to 2003. However, the tax schedule given there did not even hold in 2000. We are indebted to Wei Yu-lun of the Taxation Agency, Ministry of Finance, Taiwan, for information on the correct tax schedule. We are also indebted to Mrs. Julia Scherpp of Baker & McKenzie who allowed us access to a copy of Investitionsführer Taiwan (2000).

  54. 54.

    In 1999, private pensions from two schemes were concerned. First, the so-called Retirement Annuity Contracts (RAC). These contracts could be taken only before July 1\({}^{\mathrm{st}}\), 1988, when the current form of the Personal Pension Plan (PPP) was introduced. After July 1\({}^{\mathrm{st}}\), 1988, no new RACs could be taken out, but those with such contracts were able to continue contributing to them. From April 6\({}^{\mathrm{th}}\), 2006, under the new rules introduced by HM Revenue & Customs, RACs were put on the same basis as PPPs and almost all of their special features no longer apply. Before April 5\({}^{\mathrm{th}}\), 2006, retirement annuities were taxed at basic rate of 22 percent by the annuity providers paying them. Since April 6\({}^{\mathrm{th}}\), 2006, they are taxed under the personal income tax schedule.

  55. 55.

    The married couple’s allowance was abolished as of April 6\({}^{\mathrm{th}}\), 2000. Since this date it is only effective for couples or partnerships where one spouse was born before April 6\({}^{\mathrm{th}}\), 1935.

  56. 56.

    The Tax Foundation provides a comprehensive list of the U.S. Federal Individual Income Tax History, 1913–2011, which gives a detailed list of all federal income tax schedules that held in the time periods from 1913 to 2011. See www.taxfoundation.org/taxdata/show/151.html.

  57. 57.

    The income of children with sufficient income who are also claimed as dependents by their parents are taxed at their parents’ top marginal tax rate for incomes exceeding their itemized deductions plus the standard allowance of USD 700 (850) to prevent transfers of income-producing property from parents to children.

  58. 58.

    Allowable itemized deductions are reduced by 3 percent of the amount by which income exceeds USD 128,950. However, the reduction is limited to 80 percent of the total of otherwise allowable itemized deductions other than the allowable itemized deductions for medical expenses, investment interest, theft and casualty losses, and gambling losses.

  59. 59.

    For a detailed account of the history of EITC parameters see Tax Policy Center, Urban Institute and Brookings Institution, Tax Facts, Historical EITC Parameters, downloadable under http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/taxfacts/displayafact.cfm?DocID=36&Topic2id=40&Topic3id=42

  60. 60.

    The website of The Tax Foundation explains: “The original role of the Alternative Minimum Tax, introduced in 1969, was to prevent a small group of high-income taxpayers from combining so many deductions and exemptions that they owed little or no income tax. The AMT identifies taxpayers who have taken ‘excessive’ advantage of legal tax breaks and forces them to re-calculate their income tax. They must add back in some of the previously untaxed income, take a special AMT exemption and pay tax on this new definition of taxable income at different rates. In theory, the AMT serves as a tax backstop, taxing income that would have escaped taxation.” This website also informs that in 2000 there were 1,304,198 returns subject to AMT with an additional AMT liability of USD 9.6 billion. For further details on the AMT see Chamberlin and Fleenor, www.taxfoundation.org/publications/show/498.html.

  61. 61.

    The Tax Foundation provides a comprehensive list of the U.S. State Income Tax History, 2000–2010, which gives a detailed list of all state income tax schedules which had held in the years from 2000 to 2010. See www.taxfoundation.org/taxdata/show/228.html.

  62. 62.

    Elder (1992) studied the influence of limitation laws of expenditure and/or taxes on state fiscal policy. He found limitation laws in 19 states. Elder (1992, p. 60) observed that “growth of tax burdens has been significantly reduced in those states that have used expenditure limitations. In contrast, in states that have sought to constrain revenue growth directly the limitation laws have been ineffective.” Such legislation may explain the differences in the states’ fiscal policy. With respect to business impost (corporate income tax rate, investment tax credit rate, capital apportionment weight, and average corporate tax rate), Chirinko and Wilson (2010) observed widespread business campaign contributions aiming at tax reductions in the respective states. Conversely, campaign contributions affect tax competition among states. They found that contributions have a significant direct effect on tax policy, the economic value of a USD 1 business campaign contribution is nearly USD 4. This explains differences in the states’ business taxation, which is not of concern in this book, although it deserves to be mentioned.

References

  • Aaberge R and Melby I 1998, ‘The sensitivity of income inequality to choice of equivalence scales’, The Review of Income and Wealth, vol. 44, pp. 565–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allegrezza S, Heinrich G and Jesuit D 2004, ‘Poverty and income inequality in Luxembourg and the Grande Région in comparative perspective’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 263–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alstadsæter A 2006, The Achilles heel of the dual income tax: the Norwegian case, Research Department Discussion Paper No. 474, Oslo: Statistics Norway.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson S, Cavanagh J, Collins C, Pizzigati S and Lapham M 2008, Executive excess 2008. How average taxpayers subsidize runaway pay, Washington DC and Boston: IPS-DG.ORG and FAIRECONOMY.ORG.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson AB 2004, ‘The Luxembourg Income Study (LIS): past, present and future’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 165–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson AB 1970, ‘On the measurement of inequality’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 2, pp. 244–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bach S, Corneo G and Steiner V 2009, ‘From bottom to top: the entire income distribution in Germany, 1992 - 2003’, Review of Income and Wealth, vol. 55, pp. 303–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks J and Johnson P 1994, ‘Equivalence scales relativities revisited’, The Economic Journal, vol. 104, p. 883–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardasi E 2004, ‘The Luxembourg Income Study and the Luxembourg Employment Study as resources for labor market research’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 239–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beach CM and Davidson R 1983, ‘Distribution-free statistical inference with Lorenz curves and income shares’, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 50, pp. 723–735.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beach CM and Kaliski SF 1986, ‘Lorenz curve inference with sample weights: an application to the distribution of unemployment experience’, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series C (Applied Statistics), vol. 35, pp. 38–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berge C 1963, Topological spaces, Mineola NY: Dover Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop JA, Chakraborti S and Thistle PD 1989, ‘Asymptotically distribution-free statistical inference for generalized Lorenz curves’, Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 71, pp. 725–727.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop JA, Formby JP and Thistle PD 1990, International comparisons of tax and transfer progressivity: new evidence from the Luxembourg Income Study, Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper No. 52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop JA, Formby JP and Smith WJ 1991a, ‘International comparisons of income inequality: tests for Lorenz dominance across nine countries’, Economica, vol. 58, pp. 461–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop JA, Formby JP and Smith WJ 1991b, ‘Lorenz dominance and welfare: changes in the U.S. distribution of income, 1967–1986’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 73, pp. 134–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjorvatn K and Cappelen AW 2003, ‘Inequality, segregation, and redistribution’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 87, pp. 1657–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackorby C and Donaldson D 1983, ‘Adult equivalence scales and its implementation of interpersonal comparisons of well-being’, Social Choice and Welfare, vol. 10, pp. 335–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackorby C and Donaldson D 1984, ‘Ethical social index numbers and the measurement of effective tax/benefit progressivity’, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 17, pp. 683–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blum WJ and Kalven H 1953, The uneasy case for progressive taxation, Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bös D and Genser B 1977, ‘Steuertariflehre’, in W Albers et al. (eds.), Handwörterbuch der Wirtschaftswissenschaft, vol. 7, Stuttgart etc.: Vandenhoek & Ruprecht, pp. 412–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bräuer K 1927, Umrise und Untersuchungen zu einer Lehre vom Steuertarif , Jena: Gustav Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronchetti ET and Sullivan DH 2004, ‘Income packages of households with children: a cross-national correlation analysis’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 315–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buhmann B, Rainwater L, Schmaus G and Smeeding GM 1988, ‘Equivalence scales, well-being, inequality, and poverty: sensitivity estimates across ten countries using the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) database’, Review of Income and Wealth, vol. 34, pp. 115–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundesministerium für Arbeit und Soziales 2008, Lebenslagen in Deutschland, Der 3. Armuts- und Reichtumsbericht der Bundesregierung, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassel KG 1901, ‘The theory of progressive taxation’, The Economic Journal, vol. 11, pp. 481–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Champernowne DG 1952, ‘The graduation of income distributions’, Econometrica, vol. 20, pp. 591–615.

    Google Scholar 

  • Champernowne DG 1974, ‘A comparison of measures of inequality of income distribution’, The Economic Journal, vol. 84, pp. 787–816.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheng PCR, Chu CYC and Lin C 2008, ‘Detecting possible taxation loopholes in developing countries: the case of Taiwan’, Academia Economic Papers, vol. 36, no. 3, pp. 317–337.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chirinko RS and Wilson DJ 2010, Can lower tax rates be bought? Business rent-seeking and tax competiton among U.S. states, Barcelona: Documents de Treball de l’IEB 2010/2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cnossen S 2000, ‘Taxing capital income in the Nordic countries: a model for the European Union?’, in S Cnossen (ed.), Taxing capital income in the European Union: issues and options for reform, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 180–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen-Stuart AJ 1889, Bijdrage tot de theorie der progressieve inkomstenbelastning, Den Haag: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G 2005, ‘The rise and likely fall of the German income tax, 1958–2005’, CESifo Econmic Studies, vol. 51/1, pp. 159–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coulter FAE, Cowell F and Jenkins SP 1992, ‘Equivalence scale relativities and the extent of inequality and poverty’, The Economic Journal, vol. 102, pp. 1067–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowell FA and Mercader-Prats M 1999, ‘Equivalence scales and inequality’, in J Silber (ed.), Handbook of income inequality measurement, Boston-Dordrecht-London: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 405–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton H 1920, ‘Measurement of the inequality of incomes’, The Economic Journal, vol. 30, pp. 348–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton H 1922/1954, Principles of public finance, fourth edition 1954, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dancelli L 1990, ‘On the behaviour of the Z p concentration curve’, in C Dagum and M Zenga (eds.), Income and wealth distribution, inequality and poverty, Berlin etc.: Springer-Verlag, pp. 111–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dardanoni V and Forcina A 1999, ‘Inference for Lorenz curve orderings’, Econometrics Journal, vol. 2, pp. 49–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dardanoni V and Lambert PJ 2002, ‘Progressivity comparisons’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 86, pp. 99–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, Sen AK and Starrett D 1973, ‘Notes on the measurement of inequality’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 6, pp. 180–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Decoster A and van Camp G 1998, ‘The unit of analysis in microsimulation models for personal income taxes: fiscal unit or household?’, University of Leuven, Center for Economic Stadies, Discussion Paper 98.33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson D and Weymark JA 1980, ‘A single parameter generalization of the Gini indices of income inequality’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 22, pp. 67–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duncan D and Sabirianova Peter K 2008, Tax progressivity and income inequality, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies Working Paper No. 08–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebert U and Moyes P 2003, ‘Equivalence Scales Reconsidered’, Econometrica, vol. 71, pp. 319–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth FY 1897, ‘The pure theory of taxation’, The Economic Journal, vol. 7, pp. 46–70, 226–38, and 550–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichhorn W, Funke H and Richter W 1984, ‘Tax progression and inequality of income distribution’, Journal of Mathematical Economics, vol. 13, pp. 127–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elder HW 1992, ‘Exploring the tax revolt: an analysis of the effects of state tax and expenditure limitation laws’, Public Finance Quarterly, vol. 20, pp. 47–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faik J 1995, Äquivalenzskalen: Theoretische Erörterungen, empirische Ermittlung und verteilungsbezogene Anwendung für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fechner GT 1860, Elemente der Psychophysik, Leipzig: Breitkopf und Härtel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M 1976, ‘On the theory of tax reform’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 6, pp. 77–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fellman J 1976, ‘The effect of transformations on Lorenz curves’, Econometrica, vol. 44, pp. 823–4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folliet P 1947, Tarifs d’impôts: essai de mathématiques fiscales, Lausanne: Librairie Payot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Formby JP, Seaks TG and Smith WJ 1981, ‘A comparison of two new measures of tax progressivity’, The Economic Journal, vol. 91, pp. 1015–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Förster MF and Vleminckx K 2004, ‘International comparisons of income inequality and poverty: findings from the Luxembourg Income Study’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 191–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gastwirth J and Glauberman M 1976, ‘The interpolation of the Lorenz curve and Gini index from grouped data’, Econometrica, vol. 44, pp. 479–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genser B 1980, Lorenzgerechte Besteuerung. Ein normatives Konzept für einen neuen Steuertarif , Vienna: Verlag der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glewwe P 1991, ‘Household equivalence scales and the measurement of inequality: transfers from the poor to the rich could decrease inequality’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 44, pp. 211–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gornick JC 2004, ‘Women’s economic outcomes, gender inequality and public policy: findings from the Luxembourg Income Study’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 213–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greselin F, Pasquazzi L and Zitikis R 2010, ‘Zenga’s new index of economic inequality, its estimation, and an analysis of incomes in Italy’, Journal of Probability and Statistics, vol. 2010, Article ID 718905.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haller H 1970, Probleme der progressiven Besteuerung, Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).

    Google Scholar 

  • Haveman R and Wolfe B 2010, ‘US health care reform: a primer and an assessment’, CESifo-Dice Report, Journal for International Comparisons, vol. 8/3, pp. 53–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA 1952, ‘Die Ungerechtigkeit der Steuerprogression’, Schweizer Monatshefte, vol. 32, pp. 508–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA 1956, ‘Progressive taxation reconsidered’, in M Sennholz (ed.), On freedom and free rnterprise: Essays in honor of Ludwig von Mises, Princeton: D. van Nostrand Co., pp. 265–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hemming R and Keen MJ 1983, ‘Single-crossing conditions in comparisons of tax progressivity’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 20, pp. 373–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Investitionsführer Taiwan 2000, Frankfurt/Main and Taipeh: Baker & McKenzie, F.A.Z. Institut für Management-, Markt- und Medieninformationen GmbH, Ministry of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jakobsson U 1976, ‘On the measurement of the degree of progression’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 5, pp. 161–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP 1988, ‘Reranking and the analysis of income redistribution’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 35, pp. 65–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, SP and Cowell FA 1994, ‘Parametric equivalence scales and scale relativities’, The Economic Journal, vol. 104, pp. 891–900.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinaka M and Pereira RM, 2006, A new measurement of tax progressivity, International University of Japan, Graduate School of International Relations Working Paper EDP06-7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani NC 1977a, ‘Applications of Lorenz curves in economic analysis’, Econometrica, vol. 45, pp. 719–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani NC 1977b, ‘Measurement of tax progressivity: an international comparison’, The Economic Journal, vol. 87, pp. 71–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani NC 1987, ‘Measures of tax progressivity and redistribution effect: a comment’, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, vol. 42, pp. 431–4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen M, Papapanagos H and Shorrocks A 2000, ‘Tax reform and progressivity’, The Economic Journal, vol. 110, pp. 50–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khetan CP and Poddar SN 1976, ‘Measurement of income tax progression in a growing economy: the Canadian experience’, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 9, pp. 613–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiefer DW 1984, ‘Distributional tax progressivity indexes’, National Tax Journal, vol. 37, pp. 497–513.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kipke W 1931, Beiträge zur Lehre vom Steuertarif , Jena: Gustav Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleiber C and Kotz S 2003, Statistical size distributions in economics and actuarial sciences, Hoboken NJ: Wiley-Interscience.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein T 1986, Äquivalenzskalen – ein Literatursurvey, Discussion Paper No. 195, Frankfurt/Main and Mannheim: SFB 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinbard ED 2010, ‘An American dual income tax: Nordic precedents’, Northwestern Journal of Law and Social Policy, vol. 5, pp. 41–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolm S-C 1969, ‘The optimal production of social justice’, in J Margolis and H Guitton (eds.), Public economics, London: Macmillan, pp. 145–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert PJ 1985a, Tax progressivity: a survey of the literature, Working Paper 56, London: Institute for Fiscal Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert PJ 1985b, ‘Social welfare and the Gini coefficient revisited’, Mathematical Social Sciences, vol. 9, pp. 19–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert PJ 1988, ‘Net fiscal incidence progressivity: some approaches to measurement’, in W Eichhorn (ed.), Measurement in economics: theory and application of economic indices, Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag, pp. 519–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert PJ 1993, The distribution and redistribution of income: a mathematical analysis, second edition, Manchester and New York: Manchester University Press. (First edition 1989, Cambridge MA and Oxford: Basil Blackwell.)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert PJ and Pfähler W 1987, ‘Intersecting tax concentration curves and the measurement of tax progressivity: a rejoinder’, National Tax Journal, vol. 40, pp. 635–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lasso de la Vega MC and Urrutia AM 2008, ‘The ‘extended’ Atkinson family: the class of multiplicatively decomposable inequality measures, and some new graphical procedures for analysts’, Journal of Economic Inequality, vol. 6, pp. 211–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu P-W 1984, ‘A note on two summary measures of tax progressivity’, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, vol. 39, pp. 412–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz MO 1905, ‘Methods of measuring concentration of wealth’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 9, pp. 209–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce RD 1959, ‘On the possible psychophysical laws’, The Psychological Review, vol. 66, pp. 81–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luxembourg Income Study Database (LIS) 2011, www.lisdatacenter.org (multiple countries; accessed June 2011). Luxembourg: LIS.

  • Mahalanobis PC 1960, ‘A method of fractile graphical analysis’, Econometrica, vol. 28, pp. 325–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahler VA and Jesuit DK 2006, ‘Fiscal redistribution in the developed countries: new insights from the Luxembourg Income Study’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 4, pp. 483–511.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill JS 1848, The principles of political economy: with some of their applications to social philosophy, 2 volumes, London: Parker.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muliere P and Scarsini M 1989, ‘A note on stochastic dominance and inequality measures’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 49, pp. 314–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave RA and Thin T 1948, ‘Income tax progression, 1929–48’, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 56, pp. 498–514.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD 2001, Taxing wages 2000–2001, Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD 2008, Growing unequal? Income distribution and poverty in OECD countries, Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD 2010, Tax expenditures in OECD countries, Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD 2010, Tax policy reform and economic growth, Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD 2011, Divided we stand: why inequality keeps rising, Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okner BA 1975, ‘Individual taxes and the distribution of income’, in JD Smith (ed.), The personal distribution of income and wealth, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 45–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pechman JO and Okner BA 1974, Who bears the tax burden? Washington DC: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peichl A, Pestel N and Schneider H 2009a, Demografie und Ungleichheit: Der Einfluss von Veränderungen der Haushaltsstruktur auf die Einkommensverteilung in Deutschland, IZA Discussion Paper No. 4197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peichl A, Pestel N and Schneider H 2009b, Mehr Ungleichheit durch kleinere Haushalte? Der Einfluss von Veränderungen der Haushaltsstruktur auf die Einkommensverteilung in Deutschland, IZA Standpunkte No. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peichl A and Schäfer T 2008, Wie progressiv ist Deutschland? Das Steuer- und Transfersystem im europäischen Vergleich, EUROMOD Working Paper No. EM 01/08.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfähler W 1982, ‘Zur Messung der Progression und Umverteilungswirkung der Steuern’, Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, vol. 102, pp. 77–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfähler W 1987, ‘Redistributive effects of tax progressivity: evaluating a general class of aggregate measures’, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, vol. 42, pp. 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfähler W 1991, ‘A general class of aggregate progressivity measures revisited: reply’, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, vol. 46, pp. 161–2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfähler W and Lambert PJ 1991/92, ‘Die Messung von Progressionswirkungen’, Finanzarchiv N.F., vol. 49, pp. 281–374.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfingsten A 1985, ‘Distributionally-neutral tax changes for different inequality concepts’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 30, pp. 385–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfingsten A 1986, Measurement of tax progression, Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfingsten A 1987, ‘Axiomatically based local measures of tax progression’, Bulletin of Economic Research, vol. 39, pp. 211–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pietra G 1915, ‘Delle relazioni fra indici di variabilità, note I e II’, Atti del Reale Instituto Veneto di Science, Lettere ed Arti, vol. 74, pp. 775–804.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou AC 1928, A study in public finance, London, Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T 2003, ‘Income inequality in France, 1901–1998’, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 111, pp. 1004–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T and Saez E 2003, ‘Income inequality in the United States, 1913–1998’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 18, pp. 1–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plotnik R 1981, ‘A measure of horizontal inequity’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 63, pp. 283–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak H 1980, ‘Steuertarife’, in F Neumark, N Andel and H Haller (eds.), Handbuch der Finanzwissenschaft, vol. 2, Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), pp. 239–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba J 2007, ‘Income inequality and income taxation’, Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 29, pp. 623–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasad M and Deng Y 2009, ‘Taxation and the worlds of welfare’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 7, pp. 432–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds M and Smolensky E 1977, ‘Post-fisc distributions of income in 1950, 1961, and 1970’, Public Finance Quarterly, vol. 5, pp. 419–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rohlf FJ and Sokal RR 1994, Statistical tables, 3rd ed., San Francisco: WH Freemann and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild M and Stiglitz JE 1970, ‘Increasing risk I: a definition’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 2, pp. 225–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy J, Chakravarty IM and Laha R 1959, A study of concentration curves as description of consumer pattern, Calcutta: Studies of Consumer Behaviour, Indian Statistical Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabirianova Peter K, Buttrick S and Duncan D 2010, ‘Global reform of personal income taxation, 1981–2005: evidence from 189 countries’, National Tax Journal, vol. 63, pp. 447–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin X 2006, ‘The world distribution of income: falling poverty and convergence, period’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 121, pp. 351–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saunders P 2003, Examining recent changes in income distribution in Australia, SPRC (Social Policy Research Centre) Discussion Paper No. 130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Savin NE 1984, ‘Multiple hypothesis testing’, in: Z Griliches and MD Intriligator (eds.), Handbook of econometrics, vol. 2, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 828–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt K 1960, Die Steuerprogression, Basel and Tübingen: Kyklos and J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).

    Google Scholar 

  • Schröder C 2004, Variable income equivalence scales, Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwarze J 1995, Simulating German income and social security tax payments using the GSOEP, Cross-national studies in aging, Program Project Paper No. 19, New York: Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schutz RR 1951, ‘On the measurement of income inequality’, The American Economic Review, vol. 41, pp. 107–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl C 1994, ‘Measurement of tax progression with nonconstant income distributions’, in W Eichhorn (ed.),Models and measurement of welfare and inequality, Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 337–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl C 2006, ‘Eine umfassende Steuer- und Abgabenreform für Deutschland: Eine flat tax mit Sozialkomponente’, in C Seidl and J Jickeli (eds.), Steuern und Soziale Sicherung in Deutschland: Reformvorschläge und deren finanzielle Auswirkungen, Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag, pp. 177–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl C and Kaletha K 1987, ‘Ein analytischer Vergleich der Einkommensteuertarife 1986 und 1990’, WiSt - Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, vol. 16, pp. 379–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl C and Schmidt G 1988, ‘Die numerische Ermittlung der Parameter von Steuertarifen aus Opfergleichheitsprinzipien aufgrund vorgegebener Steueraufkommenserfordernisse’, in C Seidl (ed.), Steuern, Steuerreform und Einkommensverteilung, Berlin etc.: Springer-Verlag, pp. 49–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl C, Topritzhofer E and Grafendorfer W 1970, ‘An outline of a theory of progressive individual income-tax functions’, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, vol. 30, pp. 407–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl C and Traub S 1997, ‘Was bringt die Steuerreform?’ Betriebs-Berater, vol. 52, pp. 861–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seligman ER 1908, Progressive taxation in theory and practice, 2nd ed., Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A 1974, ‘Informational bases of alterntive welfare appoaches: aggregation and income distribution’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 3, pp. 387–403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks AF 1980, ‘The class of additively decomposable inequality measures’, Econometrica, vol. 48, pp. 613–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks AF 1983, ‘Ranking income distributions’, Economica vol. 50, pp. 3–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidgwick H 1883, Principles of political economy, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sierminska E, Brandolini A and Smeeding TM 2006, ‘The Luxembourg Wealth Study—a cross-country comparable database for household wealth research’, Journal of Economic Inequality, vol. 4, pp. 375–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn H-W 1995, ‘A theory of the welfare state’, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, vol. 94, pp. 495–526.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slitor RE 1948, ‘The measurement of progressivity and built-in flexibility’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 62, pp. 309–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smeeding TM 2004, ‘Twenty years of research on income inequality, poverty, and redistribution in the developed world: introduction and overview’, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 2, pp. 149–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smeeding TM, Schmaus G and Allegreza S 1985, Introduction to LIS, LIS-CEPS Working Paper #1, Walferdange, Luxembourg: LIS/CEPS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen PB 1993, From the global income tax to the dual income tax: recent tax reforms in the Nordic countries, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen: Copenhagen; downloadable http://www.econ.ku.dk/epru/files/wp/wp-93-07.pdf

  • Sørensen PB 2010, ‘Dual income taxes: a Nordic tax system’, in I Claus, N Gemell, M Harding and D White (eds.), Tax reform in open economies: international and country perspectives, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, pp. 78–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Canada 2004, Analysis of income in Canada 2002, Catalogue No. 75-203-XIE, Ottawa: Minister of Industry.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens SS 1975, Psychophysics: introduction to its perceptual, neural, and social prospects, New York etc.: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stroup MD 2005, ‘An index for measuring tax progressivity’, Economics Letters, vol. 86, pp. 205–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suits DB 1977, ‘Measurement of tax progressivity’, The American Economic Review, vol. 67, pp. 747–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan MA 2009, ‘Is the income tax really progressive?’, Tax Notes, Dec. 14, 2009, p. 1135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tachibanaki T 1981, ‘A note on the impact of tax on income redistribution’, The Review of Income and Wealth, vol. 27, pp. 327–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarsitano A 1990, ‘The Bonferroni index of income inequality’, in C Dagum and M Zenga (eds.), Income and wealth distribution, inequality and poverty, Berlin etc.: Springer-Verlag, pp. 228–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thistle PD 1988, ‘Uniform progressivity, residual progression, and single-crossing’, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 37, pp. 121–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timpe A 1934, Einführung in die Finanz- und Wirtschaftsmathematik, Berlin: Julius Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trabandt M and Uhlig H 2010, How far are we from the slippery slope? The Laffer curve revisited, European Central Bank Working Paper No. 1174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tran NB 1991, ‘A general class of aggregate progressivity measures revisited’, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, vol. 46, pp. 157–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbist G 2005, Replacement incomes and taxes: a distributional analysis for the EU-15 countries, EUROMOD Working Paper No. EM2/05.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickrey W 1947, Agenda for progressive taxation, New York: The Ronald Press Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt A 1912, Mathematische Theorie des Tarifwesens, Jena: Gustav Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagstaff A and van Doorslaer E 2001, ‘What makes the personal income tax progressive? A comparative analysis for fifteen OECD countries’, International Tax and Public Finance, vol. 8, pp. 299–315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber EH 1834, De pulsu, resorptione, auditu et tactu. Annotationes anatomicae et physiologicae, Leipzig: Koehler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whiteford P 2010, ‘The Australian tax-transfer system: architecture and outcomes’, Economic Record, vol. 86, pp. 528–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki S 1983, ‘On an extension of the Gini index’, International Economic Review, vol. 24, pp. 617–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young HP 1988, ‘Distributive justice in taxation’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 44, pp. 321–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zandvakili S 1994, ‘Income distribution and redistribution through taxation: an international comparison’, Empirical Economics, vol. 19, pp. 473–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zenga M 1984, ‘Proposta per un indice di concentrazione basato sui rapporti fra quantili di popolazione e quantili reddito’, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, vol. 48, pp. 301–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zenga M 1990, ‘Concentration curves and concentration indexes derived from them’, in C Dagum and M Zenga (eds.), Income and wealth distribution, inequality and poverty, Berlin etc.: Springer-Verlag, pp. 94–110.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zenga M 2007, ‘Inequality curve and inequality index based on the ratios between lower and upper arithmetic means’, Statistica & Applicazioni, vol. 5, pp. 3–27.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Seidl, C., Pogorelskiy, K., Traub, S. (2013). Data and Fiscal Institutions of the Surveyed Countries. In: Tax Progression in OECD Countries. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-28317-8_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-28317-8_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-28316-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-28317-8

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics