Advertisement

Co-evolution of Social Behavior and Spatial Organization

  • Dirk Helbing
Chapter
Part of the Understanding Complex Systems book series (UCS)

Abstract

According to Thomas Hobbes’ Leviathan (1651, English ed.: Touchstone, New York, 2008), “the life of man [is] solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short”, and it would need powerful social institutions to establish social order. In reality, however, social cooperation can also arise spontaneously, based on local interactions rather than centralized control. The self-organization of cooperative behavior is particularly puzzling for social dilemmas related to sharing natural resources or creating common goods. Such situations are often described by the prisoner’s dilemma. Here, we report the sudden outbreak of predominant cooperation in a noisy world dominated by selfishness and defection, when individuals imitate superior strategies and show success-driven migration. In our model, individuals are unrelated, and do not inherit behavioral traits. They defect or cooperate selfishly when the opportunity arises, and they do not know how often they will interact or have interacted with someone else. Moreover, our individuals have no reputation mechanism to form friendship networks, nor do they have the option of voluntary interaction or costly punishment. Therefore, the outbreak of prevailing cooperation, when directed motion is integrated in a game-theoretical model, is remarkable, particularly when random strategy mutations and random relocations challenge the formation and survival of cooperative clusters. Our results suggest that mobility is significant for the evolution of social order, and essential for its stabilization and maintenance.

Keywords

Strategy Mutation Migration Range Altruistic Punishment Average Time Period Payoff Parameter 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Notes

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Christoph Hauert, Heiko Rauhut, Sergi Lozano, Michael Maes, Carlos P. Roca, and Didier Sornette for their comments.

References

  1. 1.
    M.C. Gonzáles, C.A. Hidalgo, A.L. Barabási, Understanding individual human mobility patterns. Nature 453, 779–782 (2008)Google Scholar
  2. 2.
    L. Hufnagel, D. Brockmann, T. Geisel, The scaling laws of human travel. Nature 439, 462–465 (2006)Google Scholar
  3. 3.
    M. Batty, Cities and Complexity (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2005)Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    W. Weidlich, Sociodynamics. A Systematic Approach to Mathematical Modelling in the Social Sciences (Harwood Academic, Amsterdam, 2000)Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    D. Pumain (ed.), Spatial Analysis and Population Dynamics (John Libbey Eurotext, France, 1991)Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    J.V. Neumann, O. Morgenstern, Theory of Games and Economic Behavior (Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, 1944)Google Scholar
  7. 7.
    R. Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (Basic Books, New York, 1984)Google Scholar
  8. 8.
    B. Skyrms, Evolution of The Social Contract (Cambridge University, New York, 1996)Google Scholar
  9. 9.
    A. Flache, R. Hegselmann, Do irregular grids make a difference? Relaxing the spatial regularity assumption in cellular models of social dynamics. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simulat. 4(4) (2001)Google Scholar
  10. 10.
    J.M. Epstein, Zones of cooperation in demographic prisoner’s dilemma. Complexity 4(2), 36–48 (1998)Google Scholar
  11. 11.
    L.A. Dugatkin, D.S. Wilson, ROVER: A strategy for exploiting cooperators in a patchy environment. Am. Naturalist 138(3), 687–701 (1991)Google Scholar
  12. 12.
    M. Enquist, O. Leimar, The evolution of cooperation in mobile organisms. Animal Behav. 45, 747–757 (1993)Google Scholar
  13. 13.
    J.-F. Le Galliard, R. Ferrière, U. Dieckmann, Adaptive evolution of social traits: Origin, trajectories, and correlations of altruism and mobility. Am. Naturalist 165(2), 206–224 (2005)Google Scholar
  14. 14.
    T. Reichenbach, M. Mobilia, E. Frey, Mobility promotes and jeopardizes biodiversity in rock-paper-scissors games. Nature 448, 1046–1049 (2007)Google Scholar
  15. 15.
    C.A. Aktipis, Know when to walk away: contingent movement and the evolution of cooperation. J. Theor. Biol. 231, 249–260 (2004)Google Scholar
  16. 16.
    M.H. Vainstein, A.T.C. Silva, J.J. Arenzon, Does mobility decrease cooperation? J. Theor. Biol. 244, 722–728 (2007)Google Scholar
  17. 17.
    M.A. Nowak, Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science 314, 1560–1563 (2006)Google Scholar
  18. 18.
    A. Traulsen, M.A. Nowak, Evolution of cooperation by multilevel selection. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. (USA) 103, 10952–10955 (2006)Google Scholar
  19. 19.
    E. Fehr, S. Gächter, Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415, 137–140 (2002)Google Scholar
  20. 20.
    R. Boyd, H. Gintis, S. Bowles, P.J. Richerson, The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. (USA) 100, 3531–3535 (2003)Google Scholar
  21. 21.
    M.A. Nowak, R.M. May, Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature 359, 826–829 (1992)Google Scholar
  22. 22.
    G. Szabó, C. Hauert, Phase transitions and volunteering in spatial public goods games. Phys. Rev. Lett. 89, 118101 (2002)Google Scholar
  23. 23.
    C. Hauert, M. Doebeli, Spatial structure often inhibits the evolution of cooperation in the snowdrift game. Nature 428, 643–646 (2004)Google Scholar
  24. 24.
    M.H. Vainstein, J.J. Arenzon, Disordered environments in spatial games. Phys. Rev. E 64, 051905 (2001)Google Scholar
  25. 25.
    D. Helbing, W. Yu, Migration as a mechanism to promote cooperation. Adv. Complex Syst. 11(4), 641–652 (2008)Google Scholar
  26. 26.
    H.P. Young, Individual Strategy and Social Structure: An Evolutionary Theory of Institutions (Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, 1998)Google Scholar
  27. 27.
    N.S. Glance, B.A. Huberman, The outbreak of cooperation. J. Math. Soc. 17(4), 281–302 (1993)Google Scholar
  28. 28.
    C. Hauert, Fundamental clusters in spatial 2 ×2 games. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B 268, 761–769 (2000)Google Scholar
  29. 29.
    T.C. Schelling, Dynamic models of segregation. J. Math. Sociol. 1, 143–186 (1971)Google Scholar
  30. 30.
    J.L. Deneubourg, A. Lioni, C. Detrain, Dynamics of aggregation and emergence of cooperation. Biol. Bull. 202, 262–267 (2002)Google Scholar
  31. 31.
    M.A. Nowak, K. Sigmund, Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature 393, 573–577 (1998)Google Scholar
  32. 32.
    M. Milinski, D. Semmann, H.J. Krambeck, Reputation helps solve the “tragedy of the commons”. Nature 415, 424–426 (2002)Google Scholar
  33. 33.
    B. Rockenbach, M. Milinski, The efficient interaction of indirect reciprocity and costly punishment. Nature 444, 718–723 (2006)Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  • Dirk Helbing
    • 1
  1. 1.CLU E1ETH ZurichZurichSwitzerland

Personalised recommendations