Skip to main content

The Origins of Financial Accounts in the United States and Italy: Copeland, Baffi and the Institutions

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Financial Systems of Industrial Countries

Abstract

The paper analyses the birth of financial accounts in the US and in Italy. We start by looking at Morris A. Copeland, the first scholar who rationalized the account framework. We debate the intellectual environment that influenced Copeland’s work, namely the building of national accounting and the discussion on business cycle measurement. We summarize the Federal Reserve’s intervention that led to the regular presentation of the flow of funds in the 1950s. We then explore the multiple intellectual sources of the “Italian way” to financial accounts, underlining the role of Paolo Baffi, chief economist of the Bank of Italy in the 1950s. The Italian case epitomizes the idea that statistics are not neutral: in their conception and design they reflect the needs of the institutions which implement them. Multiple examples are given of how the rhetorical needs of the Italian central bank shaped the definition of the building blocks of the financial accounts and their presentation. We conclude by describing the later interaction between the evolution of macroeconomic theory and the rise of financial accounts in the 1960s and 1970s, a loss of interest in these statistics in the 1980s and 1990s, and its revival in recent years, mostly influenced by the financial crisis.

The authors wish to thank Franco Cotula, Eugenio Gaiotti, Claire Giordano, Donald D. Hester, and Richard Walton for useful suggestions to previous versions and Elisabetta Loche, of the Bank of Italy’s Historical Archives (hereafter ASBI), for help with research. Giuseppe Acito, Roberto Barbato and Maurizio Castellani prepared the tables. The paper covers the 1940s and 1950s and does not describe in detail the development of financial accounts after the 1960s. All translations of original material in Italian are ours. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not involve the responsibility of the Bank of Italy or of the Eurosystem.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A survey of the origins of national accounts goes beyond the scope of this paper. On the subject see Vanoli (2005).

  2. 2.

    McCloskey’s (1985) challenge should not be forgotten: ‘…the Keynesian revolution in economics would not have happened under the modernist legislation for science. The Keynesian insights were not formulated as statistical propositions until the early 1950s, 15 years after the bulk of younger economists had become persuaded they were true. By the early 1960s the Keynesian notions of liquidity traps and accelerator models of investment, despite repeated failures in their statistical implementations, were taught to students of economics as matters of scientific routine. Modernist methodology would have stopped all this cold in 1936: where was the evidence of an objective, controlled and statistical kind ?’

  3. 3.

    Some defence of Mitchell can be found in Kydland and Prescott (1990). See Della Torre (1993) and (2000) on the links between institutionalism, national accounts developed at the NBER, Mitchell’s work, and theory of the business cycle.

  4. 4.

    Kuhn’s conviction – that scientific revolutions are never brought about by one scholar only – is borne out by Copeland himself, who wrote in the preface to his work: ‘Mention should be made, too, of a study that to some extent parallels the present attempt to organise debt and credit information and relate it to gross national product information, Raymond Goldsmith’s study of saving and capital markets in the United States. Had some of the results of Goldsmith’s study become available a year or so earlier, my task would have been easier.’ Copeland was referring to Goldsmith’s research, which eventually became part of the monumental work, A Study of Saving in the United States. Goldsmith’s use of the balance sheets of institutional sectors and of flow of funds falls outside the scope of our work and merits specific treatment.

  5. 5.

    ‘The Leontief set of measurement resembles the set of moneyflows measurement presented here’, Copeland (1952), 2.

  6. 6.

    In his seminal work of 1935, Hicks said ‘we shall have to draw up a sort of generalised balance sheet, suitable for all individuals and institutions’. Furthermore, ‘monetary theory needs to be based … upon a similar analysis, …, not of an income account, but of a capital account, a balance sheet.’ Hicks’s contribution was fundamental in guiding monetary theory towards an interpretation of money as a store of value instead of a means of exchange. On Hicks, see also Chap. 3 by Massaro.

  7. 7.

    Young (1957) provides an application of US flow of funds to the years 1953–1955. See also Taylor (1958).

  8. 8.

    Sigel (1962) discusses the integration of US flow of funds with the national accounts. For the recent integration of US macroeconomic accounts see Antoniewicz et al. (2005).

  9. 9.

    An early survey on different national approaches may be found in E. Hicks (1957a).

  10. 10.

    W.C. Mitchell, ‘Fenomeni e fattori dei cicli economici’, in Mortara (1932). The text that Baffi translated was the first chapter of Mitchell’s book Business Cycles.

  11. 11.

    It is quite probable, as Della Torre (2006) points out, that the Italian experience with the ‘money circuit’ during the war (an attempt to cancel out, via compulsory saving, the inflationary effects of monetary financing of the State’s expenditure) may have had a role in defining Baffi’s scientific programme. In fact the money circuit functioned in so far it had no leaks: a detailed knowledge of the liquidity situation of the different classes of actors was instrumental in pointing out possible leaks. One could say that the money circuit was (as an intellectual stimulus) the dictatorial counterpart of the inflationary gap discussed in the same period in the US.

  12. 12.

    Banca d'Italia, personal file.

  13. 13.

    See the short biography of Baffi in Gigliobianco (2006).

  14. 14.

    The ‘statistical motivation’, in terms of the 1964 table, emerges clearly in the research paper published by two of its main authors. See Ercolani and Cotula (1969).

  15. 15.

    Both difficulties are well known and were mentioned by Baffi himself, who acknowledged that progress since 1948 had been slow (Baffi 1957, p. 316).

  16. 16.

    Annual Report for the year 1948, Banca d'Italia, pp. 189–192.

  17. 17.

    Archivio Storico della Banca d'Italia (ASBI), Studi, cart. 343, fasc. 1, last page.

  18. 18.

    The final part of the Annual Report, read by the Governor at the Annual Meeting of the Bank, was (and still is) called ‘Concluding Remarks’.

  19. 19.

    Menichella’s ‘Concluding Remarks’ have been reprinted in Cotula, Gelsomino and Gigliobianco (1977), Vol. ii. The original quotation appears on page 24.

  20. 20.

    Cotula, Gelsomino and Gigliobianco (1997), Vol. ii, page 38.

  21. 21.

    Cotula, Gelsomino and Gigliobianco (1997), Vol. ii, p. 21.

  22. 22.

    Baffi (1957), p. 318.

  23. 23.

    See Desrosières (1993) and Tooze (2001).

  24. 24.

    The distinction appears in Annual Report for the year 1960, Table 109 (and in English in the Abridged Version of the Report for the year 1960, Table 34).

  25. 25.

    Baffi (1985), § 11.

  26. 26.

    Baffi (1957), p. 322.

  27. 27.

    Baffi (1957), p. 322.

  28. 28.

    Documents regarding this trip, including correspondence between Menichella and Holtrop, Governor of De Nederlandsche Bank, can be found in ASBI, Studi, cart. 383, fasc. 2, sfasc. 83.

  29. 29.

    The correspondence is in ASBI, Carte Baffi, cart. 346.

  30. 30.

    Holtrop (1957), p.303.

  31. 31.

    Hicks (1957b) in ASBI, Carte Baffi, cart. 346/2.

  32. 32.

    Polak (1959), pp. 1–8.

  33. 33.

    Menichella (1955), p. 589.

  34. 34.

    On the innovations brought about by Carli, see his biography in Gigliobianco (2006), in particular pp. 292–297.

  35. 35.

    Banca d'Italia (1965), pp. 107–125 (the point we are interested in is on p. 122). More information and data can be found in Cotula and Caron (1971).

  36. 36.

    The reference is to the working party that finally produced the ESA70.

  37. 37.

    Banca d'Italia, Annual Report for the year 1964, ‘Considerazioni finali’, p. 493.

  38. 38.

    In the Annual Report for 1967 the first explicit attempt – i.e. not confined to internal memos – was made to link the financial accounts to the capital account.

  39. 39.

    On this point again see Ercolani and Cotula (1969), p. 20.

  40. 40.

    Hester and Tobin (1967a), (1967b) and (1967c) collected the school’s most important contributions in three volumes, published by the Cowles Foundation.

  41. 41.

    ‘The national income analysis had Keynes…[but] the Keynes of flow-of-funds analysis has not yet revealed himself’, Duesenberry (1962).

  42. 42.

    As Buiter (2003) noted, ‘Tobin’s mistrust of the representative agent approach and his relaxed attitude towards micro foundations are consistent with his decision to pursue the empirical implementation of complete systems of portfolio balance and flow-of-funds models using asset demand specifications that were eclectic or ad-hoc as regards the selection of arguments.’

  43. 43.

    The applications were heterogeneous, a feature they shared with the Keynesian macroeconomic models (see Visco 2005).

  44. 44.

    One Italian application is Modigliani and Cotula (1973). Regarding the incorporation in the Bank of Italy’s econometric model see Fazio et al. (1970).

  45. 45.

    Regarding the United States, ‘… we see more and more clearly one of the ways in which everything depends on everything else … as Bob Solow once put it’, Taylor (1963). As far as the United Kingdom is concerned, ‘The whole is reasonable only if the parts are’, Bank of England (1972).

References

  • Antoniewicz R, Hume McIntosh S, Mead CI, Moses K, Moulton BR, Palumbo M, Solomon G, Teplin AM (2005) Integrated macroeconomic accounts for the United States: draft SNA-USA. In: Jorgenson DW, Landefeld JS, Nordhaus WD (eds) A new architecture for the U.S. national accounts. NBER/Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Asso PF, Fiorito L (2001) Waging war against mechanical man. In: Frank H (ed) Knight’s critique of behavioristic psychology. Università degli Studi di Siena, Dipartimento di Economia Politica, Quaderno No. 340, December

    Google Scholar 

  • Baffi P (1957) Monetary analysis in Italy. IMF staff papers, vol 5, February

    Google Scholar 

  • Baffi P (1985) Via Nazionale e gli economisti stranieri, 1944-1953, Rivista di storia economica, 1

    Google Scholar 

  • Bain AD (1973) Surveys in applied economics: flow of funds analysis. Econ J 83:1055–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banca d’Italia (1965) Note metodologiche ad alcune tavole della Relazione della Banca per il 1964, Bollettino Statistico, Jan–Feb

    Google Scholar 

  • Bank of England (1972) An introduction to flow-of-funds accounting: 1952–1970. Bank of England, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (1954) Professor Copeland’s study of moneyflows. Rev Econ Stat 36:102–104, February

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O (2000) What do we know about macroeconomics that Fisher and Wicksell did not? NBER working paper, No. 7550

    Google Scholar 

  • Be Duc L, Le Breton G (2009) Flow-of-funds analysis at the ECB. Framework and applications, European Central Bank, Occasional paper series, vol 105, August

    Google Scholar 

  • Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (1955) Flow of funds in US, 1939–1953, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Brainard WC, Tobin J (1968) Pitfalls in financial model building. Am Econ Rev 58(2):99–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Buiter WWH (2003) James Tobin: an appreciation of his contribution to economics. NBER working paper, No. 9753

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson CS (1975) The history of the United States national income and product accounts: the development of an analytical tool. Rev Income Wealth 2:153–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen J (1972) Copeland’s moneyflows after twenty-five years: a survey. J Econ Lit 10:1–25, March

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland M (1947) Tracing money flows through the United States economy. Am Econ Rev 37:31–49, May

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland M (1952) A study of moneyflows in the United States. NBER, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland M (1961) Trends in government financing. NBER/Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Cotula F, Caron M (1971) I conti finanziari dell’Italia. Dimensioni e struttura della ricchezza e del risparmio finanziario dell’Economia, Banca d’Italia, Bollettino, November–December

    Google Scholar 

  • Cotula F, Gelsomino CO, Gigliobianco A (eds) (1997) Donato Menichella. Stabilità e sviluppo dell’economia italiana 1946–1960, i: Documenti e discorsi; ii: Considerazioni finali all’assemblea della Banca d’Italia, Rome-Bari, Laterza

    Google Scholar 

  • Della Torre G (1993) Teoria economica e conti nazionali. Il National Bureau of Economic Research (1920–1930), Banca Toscana. Studi e informazioni, 1

    Google Scholar 

  • Della Torre G (2000) Le ragioni teoriche della discrasia tra conti nazionali e conti finanziari, Quaderno n.308, Università degli Studi di Siena, Dipartimento di Economia Politica

    Google Scholar 

  • Della Torre G (2006) Discussione del lavoro di De Bonis e Gigliobianco, http://www.bancaditalia.it/studiricerche/convegni/atti/conti_fin/contenuti/sessione1.pdf, accessed on March 2011

  • Desrosières A (1993) La politique des grands nombres. Histoire de la raison statistique, Paris, La Découverte

    Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry JS (1962) A process approach to flow-of-funds analysis. In: The flow-of-funds approach to social accounting. NEBR/Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Ercolani M, Cotula F (1969) I conti finanziari della Banca d’Italia, Ente per gli studi monetari, bancari e finanziari Luigi Einaudi, Quaderni di ricerche, 4

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabricant S (1984) Toward a firmer basis of economic policy: the founding of the National Bureau of Economic Research. www.nber.org, accessed on March 2011

  • Fazio A, Caligiuri G, Cotula F, Savona P (1970) Un modello econometrico dell’economia italiana (M1BI), Settore monetario e finanziario. Banca d’Italia, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Federal Reserve Board (1959) A quarterly presentation of flow of funds, saving and investment. Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol 45, 8

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1935) 100% money. Adelphi Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigliobianco A (2006) Via Nazionale. Banca d’Italia e classe dirigente. Cento anni di storia, Rome, Donzelli

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez-Paramo JM (2009) National accounts for monetary policy making: reflections on the use of the Euro area accounts in the light of the financial crisis, Contribution to the Eurostat conference national account, Brussels, 16 Sept 2009

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurley JG, Shaw E (1960) Money in a theory of finance. Brookings Institution, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen AH (1941) Fiscal policy and business cycles. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hester DD, Tobin J (1967a) Risk aversion and portfolio choice, Cowles foundation for research in economics at Yale University, Monograph 19, Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Hester DD, Tobin J (1967b) Studies of portfolio behavior, Cowles foundation for research in economics at Yale university. Monograph 20, Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Hester DD, Tobin J (1967c) Financial markets and economic activity, Cowles foundation for research in economics at Yale University, Monograph 21, Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks E (1957a) Monetary analyses. IMF staff papers, vol 5, 3

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks E (1957b) The problem of monetary analysis, paper given at the meeting of the money and banking section of the economic society of Belgrade, Belgrade, 20 Nov 1957

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1935) A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money. Economica 2:1–19, February

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1942) The social framework. Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtrop MW (1957) Method of monetary analysis used by De Nederlandesche Bank, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, vol 5, February

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans TC (1947) Measurement without theory. Rev Econ Stat 29(3):161–172, August

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1990) Business cycles: real facts and a monetary myth, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Spring

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendelson M (1955) A structure of moneyflows. Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 50, n. 269, March: 72–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Menichella D (1955) Discorso all’assemblea dell’Associazione fra le casse di risparmio del 25 maggio 1955, In: Cotula F, Gelsomino CO, Gigliobianco A (eds) (1997) Donato Menichella. Stabilità e sviluppo del”economia italiana 1946–1960, in Documenti e discorsi, Rome-Bari, Laterza

    Google Scholar 

  • Millar JR (1990) In Memoriam: Morris A. Copeland, 1895-1989. The American journal of economics and sociology, vol. 49, n. 1, January: 45–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Millar JR (1991) Institutionalist origins. In: Dawson JC (ed) Flow-of-funds analysis. A handbook for practitioners. Sharpe, New York/London/Armonk, 1996

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell WC (1944) The flow of payments. A preliminary survey of concepts and data, Unpublished memo

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey DN (1985) The rhetoric of economics. The Board of the Regents of the University of Wisconsin System, Wisconsin

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Cotula F (1973) Un’analisi empirica dei flussi finanziari e della composizione della ricchezza finanziaria dell’economia, Moneta e credito, vol 102, March–June

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortara G (ed) (1932) Cicli economici, Nuova collana di economisti, 6, Turin, UTET

    Google Scholar 

  • Palumbo MG, Parker JA (2009) The integrated financial and real system of national accounts for the Unites States: does it presage the financial crisis? Am Econ Rev Papers and Proceedings, vol 99, 2, 80–86

    Google Scholar 

  • Papademos LD, Stark J (eds) (2010) Enhancing monetary analysis. European Central Bank, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin D (1982) Anticipations of the General Theory? And other essays on Keynes. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Polak JJ (1959) Financial statistics and financial policy, International monetary fund staff papers, vol 7, 1, April

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritter L (1963) The flow-of-funds accounts: a new approach to financial market analysis – an exposition of the structure of the flow-of-funds accounts. J Financ 18(2):219–230, May

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roe AR (1973) The case for flow of funds and national balance sheet accounts. Econ J 83(330):399–420, June

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford M (2002) Morris A. Copeland: a case study in the history of institutional economics. J Hist Econ Thought 24(3):261–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford M (2003) Who’s afraid of Arthur burns? The NBER and the Foundations, University of Victoria, Typescript

    Google Scholar 

  • Sigel SJ (1962) An approach to the integration of income and product and flow-of-funds national accounting systems: a progress report. In: The flow-of-funds approach to social accounting. NBER/Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone JRN (1966) The social accounts from a consumer’s point of view. An outline and discussion of the revised United Nations system of national accounts. Rev Income Wealth 12(1):1–33, March

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor SP (1958) An analytic summary of the flow-of-funds accounts. Am Econ Rev 48(3):158–170

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor SP (1963) Uses of flow-of-funds accounts in the Federal Reserve System. J Financ 18:249–258, May

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor SP (1991) From moneyflows accounts to flow-of-funds accounts. In: Dawson JC (ed) Flow-of-funds analysis. A handbook for practitioners. Sharpe, New York/London/Armonk, 1996

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1952) Monetary theory. Asset holding and spending decisions. Am Econ Rev Papers and Proceedings, vol 42, May

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1961) Monetary theory: new and old looks. Money, capital and other stores of values. Am Econ Rev Papers and Proceedings, vol 51, May

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1963) Commercial banks as creators of ‘Money’. In: Carson D (ed) Banking and monetary studies. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1969) A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. J Money Credit Bank 1:15–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tooze JA (2001) Statistics and the German state. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanoli A (2005) A history of national accounting. Ios Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Visco I (2005) From theory to practice in macroeconomic models: post keynesian eclecticism. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review 58:67–90, June–September

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh CE (1981) Measurement error and the flow of funds accounts: estimates of household asset demand equations. NBER working paper, No. 732, August

    Google Scholar 

  • Young RA (1957) Federal reserve flow-of-funds accounts. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, vol 5, February

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Riccardo De Bonis .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

De Bonis, R., Gigliobianco, A. (2012). The Origins of Financial Accounts in the United States and Italy: Copeland, Baffi and the Institutions. In: De Bonis, R., Pozzolo, A. (eds) The Financial Systems of Industrial Countries. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-23111-7_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-23111-7_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-23110-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-23111-7

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics