Skip to main content

Productivity Spillovers, Regional Spillovers and the Role of by Multinational Enterprises in the New EU Member States

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Drivers of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Regional Dynamics

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

There is a widely held assumption that multinational enterprises (MNEs) generate benefits that spill over to the host economy, resulting in productivity growth. Several channels foster the diffusion of such spillovers. They include backward and forward linkages with local firms – through which multinational firms may encourage the entry and development of more efficient local suppliers and final goods producing firms (Markusen and Venables 1999), competition and demonstration effects (Wang and Blomstrom 1992; Glass and Saggi 2002), as well as movements of labour force from multinationals to local firms (Fosfuri et al. 2001). The transmission of spillovers from MNEs to domestic firms, however, is not automatic; rather, it is affected by several factors, most of which can be summarized in the concept of distance, broadly defined in order to encompass both the economic and the geographical dimension. Economic distance concerns relative backwardness and absorptive capacity and determines whether and to what extent local firms eventually benefit from Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)-induced spillovers (Findlay 1978; Glass and Saggi 1998).In this paper, Multinational Enterprises (MNEs) and Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) are used as synonymous.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In this paper, Multinational Enterprises (MNEs) and Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) are used as synonymous.

  2. 2.

    In particular, Nicolini and Resmini (2010) found that MNEs operating in traditional labour intensive sectors generate intra-sectoral spillovers that accrue to medium firms in Bulgaria, and small firms in Poland and Romania, while MNEs operating in high-tech manufacturing sectors generate inter-sectoral spillovers accruing to small firms in all the considered countries and large firms in Romania. These results suggest that at aggregate level, FDI induced spillovers depend, on the one hand, on the composition of each manufacturing sector in terms of the average size of indigenous firms, and, on the other hand, on the industry structure of each region, not to mention the regional distribution of high and low tech foreign firms within each host country.

  3. 3.

    Negative effects arise when the entry of a (foreign) firms into the domestic market increases competition, and less competitive indigenous firms leave the market.

  4. 4.

    These data come from Amadeus database published by Bureau Van Djik, which besides standard financial information gives also details on several other qualitative and quantitative variables, such as the structure of the ownership, industry classification, and geographical location within countries. Only firms whose ownership can be properly identified have been included in the sample. To this respect, firms with a share of foreign ownership greater than 10% have been classified as foreign affiliates, while all other firms with a percentage of foreign ownership below 10% have been classified as domestic. Although our sample does not consider the entire population of firms operating in the considered countries over period, its representativeness is fairly good, as it is shown in the Appendix.

  5. 5.

    To this respect, Keller (2002), Coe and Helpman (1995) are exceptions.

  6. 6.

    Very recently, it has been recognized that spatial dependence may play a role as a determinant of MNEs location patterns (Bloningen et al. 2007; Coughlin and Segev 2000; Baltagi et al. 2008).

  7. 7.

    See Blomstrom and Kokko (1997) and more recently Barba Navaretti and Venables (2004) for an in depth discussion about FDI-induced spillovers.

  8. 8.

    Taking advantages of two unique panel-data samples which include information on firm price indexes, Mairesse and Jaumandreu (2005) demonstrate that the elasticities of factors of production included in a simple Cobb-Douglass production function vary more with the estimation procedures than with the particular specification of the production function equation, being the latter a real output function, a revenue function deflated either by individual prices or industry price, and a not deflated revenue function. Therefore, the omitted variable bias claimed by other scholars seems to be negligible.

  9. 9.

    This implies that firms with zero or negative investment can not be considered when estimating input coefficients. Alternatively, Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) suggest that material inputs can be used as a proxy for the firm’s reaction to productivity shocks.

  10. 10.

    Two sectors, namely manufacturing of refined petroleum products (NACE 23) and recycling (NACE 37), were excluded because the small number of firms operating in these sectors made it impossible to apply the Olley and Pakes procedure.

  11. 11.

    In so doing we recover the information on productivity of firms active in period t but with zero investments. In fact, omitting plants with zero investment would have meant omitting plants with low or declining productivity, thus introducing a sample bias in the next steps, i.e. the construction of an aggregate TFP measure and the analysis of the impact of FDI spillovers on it.

  12. 12.

    This approximation is preferred by a number of scholars. See Petrin and Levinshon (2005) for an in-depth discussion of the advantages of this approximation with respect to other possible aggregations available in the literature.

  13. 13.

    Several studies have emphasized that the transition process yields to both regional and sectoral changes. These studies belong to an emerging body of literature focusing on regional performance following transition, i.e. detecting loosing and winning regions (Traistaru et al. 2003).

  14. 14.

    The initial level of TFP, the relative concentration of each manufacturing sector and the average size of firms are drawn from the Amadeus database. Imports, GDPs at sector levels, Production price indexes as well as information on human resources devoted to science and technology at regional level come from Eurostat.

  15. 15.

    We use the latest available national Input–Output tables at two digit level for each country. This strategy implies that supplier and client relationships occur within sectors as well. This is not unrealistic, given the level of aggregation we work with. This concept can be clarified if we consider the following two sub-sectors, i.e. cotton fibres and cotton fabrics. Although they reflect different stages of the same production chain, these two sub-sectors belong to the same two digit manufacturing sector, i.e. textiles (Nace 17). We are aware that this specification did not allow us to fully capture intra-sectoral spillovers, which also stem from foreign activity taking place at the same production stage as domestic firms. These spillovers derive from imitation and/or demonstration effects, as well as from personnel training and mobility. However, it is likely that multinational firms try to minimize them, because they involve the transmission of specific knowledge to their local competitors (Haskel et al. 2007).

  16. 16.

    According to input–output tables, each sector has at the same time both client and supplier relationships with other manufacturing sectors; the degree of intensity of these relationships is often very similar.

  17. 17.

    Residuals, by definition, are the portion of the variation of the dependent variable not explained by the explanatory variables. Thus, in our case, they pick up the effects of FDI not related to the other explanatory variables on changes in TFP proxy.

  18. 18.

    See the appendix for further details.

  19. 19.

    As discussed in Sect. 3, this variable has been included in order to correct possible error measurement in the dependent variable, which relies on nominal values.

  20. 20.

    The insignificance of the coefficients of the openness variable may also be explained by a complementary relationship between trade and FDI. This implies that the degree of openness of a region is already captured by the presence of foreign enterprises. A spurious correlation may also affect the specialization variable and the average size of firms: the larger the size of the firms, the more concentrated is the sector.

  21. 21.

    The poor explanatory power of specification (4) may be explained by the fact that sectoral heterogeneity is already captured by explanatory variables; therefore, adding sectoral fixed effects may generate multicollinearity problems that worsen the goodness of fit of the model.

References

  • Aitken B, Harrison A (1999) Do domestic firms benefit from direct foreign investment? Evidence from Venezuela. Am Econ Rev 89(3):605–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anselin L (2001) Spatial econometrics. In: Baltagi B (ed) A companion to theoretical econometrics. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp 310–330

    Google Scholar 

  • Anselin L (2003) Spatial externalities, spatial multipliers and spatial econometrics. Int Reg Sci Rev 26(2):153–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi B, Egger P, Pfaffermayr M (2008) Estimating regional trade agreement. Effects on FDI in an interdependent word. J Econometrics 145(1–2):194–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barba NG, Venables A (2004) Multinational firms in the world economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman E, Doms M (2000) Understanding productivity: lessons from longitudinal microdata. J Econ Lit 38(3):569–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Spiegel M (1994) The roles of human capital in economic development: evidence from aggregate cross-country data. J Monetary Econ 34:143–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomstrom M, Kokko A (1997) How foreign investment affects host countries, Policy Research Working Paper Series 1745, The World Bank

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloningen B, Davis R, Waddell G, Naughton H (2007) FDI in space: spatial autoregressive relationships in foreign direct investment. Eur Econ Rev 51(5):1303–1325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campos N, Kinoshita Y (2003) Why does FDI go where it goes? New evidence from the transition economies, IMF working paper no. 03/228

    Google Scholar 

  • Coe DT, Helpman H (1995) International R&D spillovers. Eur Econ Rev 39:859–887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin C, Segev E (2000) Foreign direct investment in China: a spatial econometric study. World Econ 23(1):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driffield N (2006) On the search for spillovers from foreign direct investment (FDI) with spatial dependency. Reg Stud 40(1):107–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning J (1977) Trade, location of economic activity and MNE: a search for an eclectic approach. In: Ohlin B, Hesselborn P, Wijkman PM (eds) The international allocation of the economic activity. McMillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning J (1981) International production and multinational enterprise. Geroge Allen and Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Elhorst JP (2003) Specification and estimation of spatial panel data models. Int Reg Sci Rev 26(3):255–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman MP (2003) The locational dynamics of the US biotech industry: knowledge externalities and the anchor hypothesis. Ind Innovat 10(3):311–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay R (1978) Relative backwardness, direct foreign investment, and the transfer of technology: a simple dynamic model. Q J Econ 92(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fosfuri A, Motta M, Ronde T (2001) Foreign direct investment and spillovers through workers’ mobility. J Int Econ 53:205–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A, Saggi K (1998) International technology transfer and the technology gap. J Dev Econ 55:369–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A, Saggi K (2002) Multinational firms and technology transfer. Scand J Econ 104(4):495–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haskel J, Pereira S, Slaughter M (2007) Does inward foreign direct investment boost the productivity of domestic firms? Rev Econ Stat 89(3):482–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV, Shalizi Z, Venables AJ (2001) Geography and Development, Journal of Economic Geography 1(1), pp 81–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Katayama H, Lu S, Tybout J (2009) Firm-level productivity studies: illusions and a solution. Int J Ind Organiz 27(3):403–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller W (2002) Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. Am Econ Rev 92(1):120–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Sage J (1998) The theory and practice of spatial econometrics, mimeo downloadable at: http://www.rri.wvu.edu/WebBook/LeSage/spatial/wbook.pdf

  • Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70:317–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mairesse J, Jaumandreu J (2005) Panel-data estimates of the production function and the revenue function: what difference does it make? Scand J Econ 107(4):651–672

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen J (1995) The boundaries of multinational enterprise and the theory of international trade. J Econ Perspect 9(2):169–189

    Google Scholar 

  • Markusen J, Venables A (1999) Foreign direct investment as a catalyst for industrial development. Eur Econ Rev 43(2):335–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Phelps E (1966) Investment in humans, technology diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 56(1):69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicolini M, Resmini L (2010) FDI spillovers in new EU member states. Which firms create them and which firms really benefit? Econ Transit 18(3):487–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olley S, Pakes A (1996) The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunication equipment industry. Econometrica 64(6):1263–1297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrin A, Levinshon J (2005) Measuring aggregate productivity growth using plant-level data, NBER working paper no. 11887

    Google Scholar 

  • Pusterla F, Resmini L (2007) Where do foreign firms locate in transition countries? An empirical investigation. Ann Reg Sci 41(4):835–856

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Resmini L (2000) The determinants of foreign direct investment into the CEECs: new evidence from sectoral patterns. Econ Transit 8(3):665–689

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tornqvist L (1936) The bank of Finland’s consumption price index. Bank Finland Mon Bull 10:1–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Traistaru I, Njikamp P, Resmini L (eds) (2003) The new emerging geography in transition countries. Ashgate, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang J, Blomstrom M (1992) Foreign direct investment and technology transfer: a simple model. Eur Econ Rev 36:137–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu B (2000) Multinational enterprises, technology diffusion, and host country productivity growth. J Dev Econ 62:477–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu B, Wang J (1999) Capital goods trade and R&D spillovers in the OECD. Can J Econ 32:1179–1192

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Laura Resmini .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Table A.1 Representativeness of the sample: distribution of manufacturing employment
Table A.2 MNEs vs. TFP changes: the reverse regression

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Nicolini, M., Resmini, L. (2011). Productivity Spillovers, Regional Spillovers and the Role of by Multinational Enterprises in the New EU Member States. In: Kourtit, K., Nijkamp, P., Stough, R. (eds) Drivers of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Regional Dynamics. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-17940-2_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-17940-2_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-17939-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-17940-2

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics