Skip to main content

The Commercializing of Spillovers: A Case Study of Swedish Aircraft Industry

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Catching Up, Spillovers and Innovation Networks in a Schumpeterian Perspective

Abstract

Advanced product development distinguishes itself by being surrounded by a “cloud of technology spillovers” available to external users in proportion to their competence to commercialize them. This “double product” is particularly important when it comes to public procurement of advanced products. Government then acts in the double customer role of being both concerned about the product and the additional social value created for society from the spillover cloud. Marketing the double product, therefore, involves the ability of the supplier to present a credible case also for the economic value to society of the spillovers, and to find a way of charging for them. This means designing a mutually beneficial contract that makes both parties to the deal winners. I use cases to illustrate, and demonstrate the existence of the social value of the cloud, organizing the presentation around the competence bloc categories of the companion paper Eliasson (2011). The cases are downstream industrial business formation around Swedish military aircraft industry. The case studies show this cloud to have been a great commercial opportunity for the Swedish economy. They also suggest that the value of the cloud would have been much greater if the local commercial environment had been more entrepreneurial.

This paper draws directly on Eliasson (1995), the industrial policy discussion in Eliasson (2000) and later complementary interviews and case analyses.

Earlier versions of parts of this paper have been discussed at a Ratio Institute seminar in Stockholm, at SNF in Bergen, in my seminar at the Rio Conference of the Joseph A. Schumpeter Society 2008 and in a seminar at Case Western Reserve University, Cleveland in 2009. Very useful comments from Carl- Henrik Arvidsson, Ole Bjerrefjord, Pontus Braunerhjelm, Bo Carlsson, Richard Day, Billy Fredriksson, Per Heum, Dan Johansson, Nils Karlson and Lennart Källqvist are acknowledged.

This is a revised and shortened version of paper presented at the 12th International conference of the Joseph A. Schumpeter Society in

Rio de Janerio, 2–5 July 2008. The theoretical part of that paper has already been published as Eliasson (2011).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    To avoid confusion I mention already here the terminology used. Production covers all value added creation in a firm, including product development. Manufacturing is the term used for factory production. Technology, furthermore, is used in the original Greek meaning of knowledge about techniques.

  2. 2.

    In Eliasson (2006) I mention such an advanced work environment as one of the few remaining competitive advantages of the industrial economies over the emerging low wage industrial economies.

  3. 3.

    As argued by Day (1986) this latter interdependence of demand and supply poses difficult methodological problems in economic theory.

  4. 4.

    This technical definition of the innovator has its origin in von Mises (1949). On this I prefer to think in terms of innovations as being generated by a technology system ( Carlsson 1995) or a technology production function (Griliches 1979, 1984, 1986).

  5. 5.

    They are France, the UK, the US, China and Russia and Sweden. Brazil, Canada, Germany and Italy have to be added if we include small civilian aircraft.

  6. 6.

    An additional reason was that regional jets were becoming competitive. However, this would have been no reason for Saab to shut down its civilian aircraft activity had it had an opportunity to sell its turbo prop aircraft ( when turbo prop machines were competitive) for a profit to finance the further development of a regional jet. Jet propulsion was not a new technology to Saab.

  7. 7.

    Celsius was formed by the Swedish government in 1977 on the ruins of the collapsed Swedish shipyard indsutry. In 1986 the government took the opportunity to have some problem companies merged with Bofors. Celsius acquired a troubled Bofors in 1982.

  8. 8.

    I am currently involved in a separate study on the spillover multiplier around that particular competence bloc.

  9. 9.

    More recent research by the authors support this interpretation (Telephone contact by the author). For a discussion of these results see Eliasson 1997: 241 f. Also see Hall et al. 2010.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors (pp. 609–626). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braunerhjelm, P., & Feldman, M. (2006). Cluster genesis – the origin and emergence of technology-based economic development. London: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, B. (Ed.). (1995). Technological systems and economic performance: the case of factory automation. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 128–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day, R. H. (1986). On endogenous preferences and adaptive economizing. In R. H. Day & G. Eliasson (Eds.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1986). Kunskap, information och tjänster – en studie av svenska industriföretag (Knowledge, Information and Service Production – a study of Swedish manufacturing firms). Stockholm: IUI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1990). The firm as a competent team. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 13(3), 275–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1991). The international firm: A vehicle for overcoming barriers to trade and a global intelligence organization diffusing the notion of a nation. In L. G. Mattson, & B. Stymne (Eds.), Corporate and industry strategies for Europe. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1995). En teknologigenerator eller ett nationellt prestigeprojekt? ─ svensk flygindustri (A technology generator or a national prestige project? Swedish aircraft industry). Stockholm: City University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1996a). The firm, its objectives, its controls and its organization. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1996b). Spillovers, integrated production and the theory of the firm. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 6, 125–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1997). General purpose technologies, industrial competence blocs and economic growth. In B. Carlsson (Ed.), Technological systems; cases, analyses, comparisons. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1998). Svensk datorindustri – en kompetensblocksanalys av dess framväxt och försvinnande (Swedish Computer Industry – a competence bloc analysis of its emergence and disappearance). In P. Heum (Ed.), Kompetense og Verdiskapning. SNFs Årsbok 1998. Bergen: Fagboksforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2000). Industrial policy, competence blocs and the role of science in the economic development. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10, 217–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (Ed.). (2005a). The birth, the life and the death of firms – the role of entreprenurship, creative destruction and conservative institutions in a growing and experimentally organized economy. Stockholm: The Ratio Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2005b). The nature of economic change and management in a new lnowledge based information economy. Information Economics and Policy, 17, 428–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2005c). Insourcing of production from foreign subsidiaries or subcontractors – an empirical study of Swedish firms. Report prepared for Invest in Sweden Agency (ISA) Stockholm. Can be downloaded at http://www.isa.se/kostnadellerkompetens.

  • Eliasson, G. (2006). From employment to entrepreneurship. Journal of Industrial Relations, 48(5), 633–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2010). Advanced Public Procurement as Industrial Policy – Aircraft industry as technical university, New York, Dordrecht, Heidelberg, London:Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2011). Advanced Purching, spillovers and innovative discovery. J Evol Econ, 21.1-4:121–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2010). Advanced purchasing, spillovers and innovative discovery, revised version of paper presented to the 12th International conference of the Joseph A. Schumpeter Society, Rio de Janerio, 2–5 July 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. & Eliasson, Å. (1996). The biotechnological competence bloc. Revue d’Economie Industrielle, 78-40, Trimestre.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, Å. (2005). The Theory of the firm and the markets for strategic acquisitions. In U. Cantner, E. Dinopoulos, & R. F. Lanzilotti (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, the new economy and public policy. Berlin, Heidelberg, New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, Å. (2009). Competence and learning in the experimentally organized economy. In Bjuggren & Mueller (Eds.), The modern firm, corporate governance and investment. Elgars.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G., & Wihlborg, C. (2003). On the macroeconomic effects of establishing tradability in weak property rights. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13, 607–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M., & Lichtenberg, F. (1997). The impact and organization of publicly- funded research and development in the European community. NBER Working Paper Nr 6040. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, B. (1994). Systems engineering – a holistic approach to product development. Griffin 94/95 (Nov).

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenstein, S. M., & Spiller, P. T. (1996). Estimating the welfare effects of digital infrastructure. NBER Working Paper Nr 5770 (Sept). Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1969). Capital – skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics, LI, 465–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of R&D to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics (Spring), 10(1), 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1984). R&D patents, and productivity. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1986). Productivity, R&D and basic research at the firm level in the 1970s. American Economic Review, 76(1), 143–154.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunnarsson, G., Mellander, E., Savvidou, E. (2004). Human capital is the key to the IT productivity paradox. Uppsala: IFAU Working paper 2004:13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B., Jacques M., & Pirre M. (2010). Measuring the return to R&D. In Hall & Rosenberg (Eds). Handbook of Economics and Technical Change, Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. I. (1995). R&D based models of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 103(4), 759–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. I., & Williams, J. C. (1998). Measuring the social returns to R&D. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1119–1135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller, W. (2001) International technology diffusion. NBER Working Paper No. 8573 (Oct). Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klenow, P. J., & Rodriguez, C. A. (2004). Externalities and growth. NBER Working Paper Nr 11009. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg, F. R. (1993). The output contributions of computer equipment and personnel: a firm level analysis. NBER Working paper Nr. 4540 (Nov). Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mamuneas, T. P., & Nadiri, M. I. (1995). Public R&D policies and cost behavior of the US manufacturing industries. NBER Working Paper No. 5059. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohnen, P. (1996). R&D externalities and productivity growth. OECD Science and Technology Review (STI), Nr 18:39–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mun, S. -B., & Nadiri, M. I. (2002) Information technology externalities: Empirical evidence from 42 U.S Industries. NBER Working Paper No. 9272 (Oct). Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nadiri, I. (1978). A dynamic model of research and development expenditure. In B. Carlsson, G. Eliasson, I. Nadiri (Eds.), The importance of technology and the permanence of structure in industrial growth. IUI Conference Reports, 1978:2, Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nadiri, I. (1993). Innovations and technological spillovers. Working Paper No. 4423. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nadiri, M. I., & Mamuneas, T. P. (1994). Infrastructure and public R&D investments, and the growth of factor productivity in US manufacturing industries. NBER Working Paper No. 4845. (Aug), Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1911). Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. In Dunker und Humblot, Jena. English (Ed.), 1934, The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest and the business cycle (Vol. XLVI). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1949). Human action. Chicago: Contemporary Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gunnar Eliasson .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this paper

Cite this paper

Eliasson, G. (2011). The Commercializing of Spillovers: A Case Study of Swedish Aircraft Industry. In: Pyka, A., Derengowski Fonseca, M. (eds) Catching Up, Spillovers and Innovation Networks in a Schumpeterian Perspective. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-15886-5_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-15886-5_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-15885-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-15886-5

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics