Skip to main content

New Coordination Mechanisms

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Supply Chain Coordination Mechanisms

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 628))

  • 1373 Accesses

Abstract

Apart from the identification of improved solutions within an acceptable number of iterations, a further requirement for practicable coordination schemes is their applicability by rational, self-interested parties, which implies that the schemes can be embedded into suitable coordination mechanisms.

In the following sections, we outline three contractual frameworks that form building blocks for the resulting mechanisms in combination with the schemes proposed in Chap. 4. All frameworks rely on compensation payments among parties as incentives for the implementation of coordinated solutions. First, these payments are necessary for ensuring individual rationality in the mechanisms. Often, the implementation of coordinated solutions involves cost increases for at least one party. Such increases necessarily occur if a party acts as the leader and unilaterally determines the allocation of the central resources in the default solution.1 Unless several optimal solutions exist for the leader’s problem, the implementation of a coordinated proposal will force the leader to deviate from his individually optimal solution, and, hence, to implement a solution with increased costs. Second, such payments are a straightforward way to align parties’ incentives with the actions required by the schemes.2

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    An example for this is upstream planning with forced compliance (see p. 31), where the buyer acts as the leader.

  2. 2.

    A renunciation of such payments – as sporadically advocated in the literature, e.g., by Gjerdrum et al. (2002, p. 592) – might only be an option if no party incurs any losses from implementing a coordinated proposal. This may occur to a limited extent in voluntary compliance settings, as indicated by our computational tests of Sect. 6.4. Even then, however, it seems difficult to ensure that parties will actually follow the rules of the underlying scheme. The main problem is that – depending on the rule for determining the proposal implemented – parties will have incentives not to accept proposals with small own savings in order to increase the probability of the acceptance of proposals that are more lucrative for these parties (though less advantageous for the other parties). If all parties pursued this strategy, the overall coordination performance would suffer strongly since a great number of favorable proposals would be declined then.

  3. 3.

    We omit the index i when we consider a single cost-reporting party.

  4. 4.

    Note that this possibility has been mentioned by Dudek and Stadtler (2007, p. 478).

  5. 5.

    See Kahneman et al. (1986, p. 728).

  6. 6.

    See, e.g., Kagel and Roth (1995, p. 256) and Camerer (2003, p. 59).

  7. 7.

    See Camerer (2003, p. 113).

  8. 8.

    This theory has been developed by Fehr and Schmidt (1999, p. 817) and been applied to supply chain coordination by Cui et al. (2007, p. 1303). For more information about behavioral theories explaining these phenomena, see Camerer (2003, p. 101).

  9. 9.

    This game has initially been proposed Berg et al. (1995, p. 122) and extensively investigated in the literature afterwards. For variants of this game recently examined, see, e.g., Bracht and Feltovich (2008, p. 39) and Falk (2007, p. 1501).

  10. 10.

    Repeated trust games have first been investigated by Camerer and Weigelt (1988, p. 1) and recently by Engle-Warnick and Slonim (2004, p. 553) and Engle-Warnick and Slonim (2006, p. 603).

  11. 11.

    As an illustration for the effects of distorted reporting of cost changes, see Example 5.2 in the next section.

  12. 12.

    A discussion of potential learning effects with a repeated application of the mechanism is provided at the end of this section.

  13. 13.

    See e.g., Aviv (2001, p. 1327).

  14. 14.

    A Stackelberg game is a dynamic game in which one party is the (Stackelberg) leader and moves before the follower, see, e.g., Myerson (1991, p. 187).

  15. 15.

    See Assumption 5.1. We discuss an alternative assumption about the information status of the RP below.

  16. 16.

    This assumption is natural since most standard probability distributions, e.g., normal, uniform, gamma, and Weibull distributions, show this property, see Lariviere and Porteus (2001, p. 296).

  17. 17.

    An IGFR for f(S) means that \(Lf(L)/{\int \nolimits \nolimits }_{L}^{\infty }f(S)dS\) is increasing in L. Since \({\int \nolimits \nolimits }_{L}^{\infty }f\left (S\right )dS\) is decreasing in L, \({\int \nolimits \nolimits }_{L}^{\infty }f\left (S\right )dS - Lf\left (L\right )\) also decreases then, provided that \({\int \nolimits \nolimits }_{L}^{\infty }f\left (S\right )dS - Lf\left (L\right ) > 0\).

  18. 18.

    A potential increase of the RHS of (5.2) for ranges where the RHS takes negative values does not affect the optimality of L . The best value for L within such a range is the lower bound of this range, which either corresponds to a or to the upper bound of the adjacent positive range.

  19. 19.

    Values of L > b can be excluded since the gains of RP become zero there.

  20. 20.

    This assumption is often used within mechanism design, see, e.g., Chatterjee and Samuelson (1983, p. 842) and Baldenius (2000, p. 32), if – as it is the case here – otherwise no meaningful analytical results can be derived.

  21. 21.

    For a risk-averse RP, L is lower. Risk averseness can be modeled straightforwardly here, e.g., analogously to the modeling by Chatterjee and Samuelson (1983, p. 848) for their sealed bid double auction.

  22. 22.

    See e.g., Rapoport et al. (1998, p. 221) and Seale et al. (2001, p. 187).

  23. 23.

    We provide an example for such a setting below (Example 5.5).

  24. 24.

    See, e.g., Camerer et al. (2002, p. 137). For a survey of learning theories and associated experimental results, see Camerer (2003), Chap. 6.

  25. 25.

    See also Sect. 3.3.1.

  26. 26.

    See, e.g., Rapoport et al. (1998, p. 226) and Seale et al. (2001, p. 192).

  27. 27.

    See Brandts and Holt (1992, p. 1350) as a reference for a seminal paper on this topic and Sect. 8 of Camerer (2003).

  28. 28.

    See Sect. 3.3.1.

  29. 29.

    See Sect. 4.1.2.

  30. 30.

    Note that, like in the other mechanisms presented in this work, we assume the existence of a default solution, which is implemented without coordination.

  31. 31.

    Note that these “savings” can also take negative values if the implementation of a proposal involves a cost increase for a party. For ease of exposition, however, we keep this terminology also in this case.

  32. 32.

    Such markdowns are always chosen by rational parties under mild conditions. This result has been proven by Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983, p. 265) for the bilateral trade mechanism and is directly valid for the setting considered here if | Π | = 1.

  33. 33.

    In contrast to the previous section, a more detailed prior knowledge (i.e., for each proposal) is natural here since parties submit bids about the savings for all proposals within the auction, and these bids will become globally known afterwards.

  34. 34.

    E.g., Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983, p. 265).

  35. 35.

    See Sect. 3.3.1 for more details on this mechanism.

  36. 36.

    These problems correspond to (5.4) with only one proposal generated and the reservation value of the buyer (seller) as the (negative) savings of these parties. See Chatterjee and Samuelson (1983, p. 838).

  37. 37.

    See Sect. 4.1.2.

  38. 38.

    See also Sect. 3.3.1.

  39. 39.

    For the definition of the set packing problem and an analysis of its properties, see, e.g., Balas and Padberg (1976, p. 710).

  40. 40.

    See, e.g., Andersson et al. (2000, p. 6).

  41. 41.

    Analogously to Theorem 5.2, with constant markups chosen by parties, the lower bound is \(1 -\sum\limits_{i\in P}E[{L}^{i}]/(4{S}^{sys})\) of the systemwide surplus. Further note that the sum of parties’ leeways may exceed S sys or go below L sys, depending on the complementarities of the central resource use in coordinated solutions; for an analogous discussion, see Sect. 5.2.

  42. 42.

    For literature on learning and signaling strategies, see the corresponding discussion of the preceding section.

  43. 43.

    For experimental studies of learning in repeated (anonymous, i.e., without signaling effects) sealed bid double auctions under the standard assumption of common knowledge about the distributions of parties’ reservation values, see Rapoport et al. (1998, p. 221), Seale et al. (2001, p. 177), and Daniel et al. (1998, p. 133).

  44. 44.

    See also our computational tests of Sect. 6.1, p. 168.

  45. 45.

    See e.g., Elmaghraby (2004, p. 214) for examples of auctions in B2B marketplaces and Hohner et al. (2003, p. 23) for a case study about the use of procurement auctions at Mars.

  46. 46.

    See, Agndal and Nilsson (2008, p. 154) for a compilation of approaches for open-book accounting in supply chains.

  47. 47.

    See our computational results of Sect. 6.1.

  48. 48.

    See also Sect. 2.1.2.

  49. 49.

    Such leeway is often specified by a flexibility range, e.g., Tsay (1999, p. 1341).

  50. 50.

    Of course, such conflicts only arise if the supplier holds too little inventory to fulfill the buyer’s orders without a significant increase in his costs. Hence, a further interpretation of the mechanisms proposed is that of instruments to reduce inventory at decentralized parties.

  51. 51.

    For ease of exposition, the existence of a frozen horizon is omitted here.

  52. 52.

    See Dudek (2004, p. 116).

  53. 53.

    See Dudek (2004, p. 120).

  54. 54.

    See Sect. 4.4.3.

References

  • Agndal, H. and Nilsson, U. (2008). Supply chain decision-making supported by an open books policy. International Journal of Production Economics, 116(1):154–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aviv, Y. (2001). The effect of collaborative forecasting on supply chain performance. Management Science, 47(10):1326–1343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balas, E. and Padberg, M. W. (1976). Set partitioning: A survey. Siam Review, 18(4):710–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldenius, T. (2000). Intrafirm trade, bargaining power, and specific investments. Review of Accounting Studies, 5(1):27–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., and McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10:122–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bracht, J. and Feltovich, N. (2008). Efficiency in the trust game: An experimental study of precommitment. International Journal of Game Theory, 37(1):39–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, J. and Holt, C. A. (1992). An experimental test of equilibrium dominance in signaling games. American Economic Review, 82(5):1350–1365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. and Weigelt, K. (1988). Experimental tests of a sequential equilibrium reputation model. Econometrica, 56(1):1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., Ho, T.-H., and Chong, J.-K. (2002). Sophisticated experience-weighted attraction learning and strategic teaching in repeated games. Journal of Economic Theory, 104(1): 137–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, K. and Samuelson, W. (1983). Bargaining under incomplete information. Operations Research, 31(5):835–851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cui, T. H., Raju, J. S., and Zhang, Z. J. (2007). Fairness and channel coordination. Management Science, 53(8):1303–1314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniel, T., Seale, D., and Rapoport, A. (1998). Strategic play and adaptive learning in the sealed-bid bargaining mechanism. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42(2–3):133–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dudek, G. (2004). Collaborative Planning in Supply Chains – A Negotiation-Based Approach. Springer, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dudek, G. and Stadtler, H. (2007). Negotiation-based collaborative planning in divergent two-tier supply chains. International Journal of Production Research, 45(2):465–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle-Warnick, J. and Slonim, R. (2006). Inferring repeated-game strategies from actions: Evidence from trust game experiments. Economic Theory, 28(3):603–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle-Warnick, J. and Slonim, R. L. (2004). The evolution of strategies in a repeated trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(4):553–573.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A. (2007). Gift exchange in the field. Econometrica, 75(5):1501–1511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3):817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gjerdrum, J., Shah, N., and Papageorgiou, L. G. (2002). Fair transfer price and inventory holding policies in two-enterprise supply chains. European Journal of Operational Research, 143(3):582–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hohner, G., Rich, J., Ng, E., Reid, G., Davenport, A. J., Kalagnanam, J. R., Lee, H. S., and An, C. (2003). Combinatorial and quantity-discount procurement auctions benefit Mars, incorporated and its suppliers. Interfaces, 33(1):23–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., and Thaler, R. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76(4):728 –741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lariviere, M. A. and Porteus, E. L. (2001). Selling to the newsvendor: An analysis of price-only contracts. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 3(4):293–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1991). Game Theory – Analysis of Conflict. Havard University Press, Cambridge, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. and Satterthwaite, M. A. (1983). Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. Journal of Economic Theory, 29(2):265–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, A., Daniel, T. E., and Seale, D. A. (1998). Reinforcement-based adaptive learning in asymmetric two-person bargaining with incomplete information. Experimental Economics, 1(3):221–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seale, D. A., Daniel, T. A., and Rapoport, A. (2001). The information advantage in two-person bargaining with incomplete information. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 44(2):177–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, A. A. (1999). The quantity flexibility contract and supplier-customer incentives. Management Science, 45(10):1339–1358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin Albrecht .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Albrecht, M. (2010). New Coordination Mechanisms. In: Supply Chain Coordination Mechanisms. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 628. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-02833-5_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics