Skip to main content

Dynamics of Innovation Fields with Endogenous Heterogeneity of People

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
New Directions in Regional Economic Development

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

According to Lester Thurow at MIT, advanced countries are shifting from capitalism based on mass production of commodities to the brain power society in which creation of knowledge and information using brain power plays the central role (Thurow 1996). The concept of brain power society is essentially the same as that of the C-society advocated by Åke Andersson who maintains that advanced countries are leaving the industrial society (with its reliance on simplicity of production and products and the heavy use of natural resources and energy) and entering the C-society with and increasing reliance on creativity, communication capacity, and complexity of products (Andersson 1985). In this paper, the term “brain power society” is synonymous with the “C-society” of Åke Andersson. The ultimate concern of this paper is the further development of the New Economic Geography (NEG) towards a more comprehensive theory of geographical economics in the age of brain power society, in which the dynamics of the spatial economy arise from the dual linkages in the economic and knowledge fields. Before elaborating this ultimate objective, let me explain briefly what is the so-called the New Economic Geography.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Fujita et al. (1999) for a comprehensive manifestation of this approach. See also Fujita and Thisse (2002) and Baldwin et al. (2003) for the recent development of the NEG. For an overview of the NEG, see Fujita and Krugman (2004), Fujita (2005), Fujita and Mori (2005).

  2. 2.

    This hypothesis is not entirely new, of course. For, e.g., Zipf (1949) conjectured that the changing spatial configuration of economic activities was the outcome of the two sets of centripetal (unifying) and centrifugal (diversifying) forces.

  3. 3.

    See those articles reviewed in Fujita and Mori (2005).

  4. 4.

    Here, “common knowledge” represents simply the short expression of “the knowledge in common” or “mutual knowledge”. It is not the term used in game theory.

  5. 5.

    See Berliant and Fujita (2007) for the further elaboration of the following model.

  6. 6.

    For simplicity, we employ a deterministic framework. It seems possible to add stochastic elements to the model, but at the cost of complexity. It should also be possible to employ the law of large numbers to a more basic stochastic framework to obtain equivalent results.

  7. 7.

    In an earlier version of this paper, Berliant and Fujita (2004, available at http://econpapers.hhs.se/paper/wpawuwpga/0401004.htm), we have worked out the details of the model with both knowledge creation and transfer when there are only two persons, and found no essential difference in the results. However, in the N person case, it is necessary to keep track of more details of who knows which ideas, and thus the model becomes very complex. This extension is left to future work.

  8. 8.

    See Berliant and Fujita (2007, Sect. 4.6) for a more general form of joint knowledge creation.

  9. 9.

    Given that the focus of this paper is on knowledge creation rather than production, we use the simplest possible form for the production function.

  10. 10.

    For details of the analyses in the rest of this paper, see Berliant and Fujita (2007).

  11. 11.

    For the determination \( \hat{m} \), see Berliant and Fujita (2007).

  12. 12.

    Here, it is natural ask why the optimal group size in knowledge production is four. Actually, using a more general functional form of joint knowledge production, Berliant and Fujita (2007) shown that when differential knowledge is relatively more important than common knowledge in knowledge production, the optimal group size is larger.

References

  • Andersson ÅE (1985) Kreativitet: storstadens framtid. Prisma, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Forslid R, Martin P, Ottaviano G, Robert-Nicoud F (2003) Economic geography and public policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Berliant M, Fujita M (2007) Knowledge creation as a square dance on the Hilbert cube. Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University, Kyoto (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M (2005) Spatial economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P (2004) The new economic geography: past, present and the future. Pap Reg Sci 83:149–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Mori T (2005) Frontiers of the new economic geography. Pap Reg Sci 84(3):377–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Thisse J-F (2002) Economics of agglomeration: cities, industrial location, and regional growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P, Venables AJ (1999) The spatial economy: cities, regions and international trade. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs J (1969) The economy of cities. Random House, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE Jr (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:2–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1890) Principles of economics. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME (1998) On competition. A Harvard business review book. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Thurow LC (1996) The future of capitalism. Leighco, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zipf G (1949) Human behavior and the principle of least effort. Addison-Wesley, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author is grateful to the three anonymous referees and to David Batten, Åke Andersson and other participants in the workshop on “Innovation, Dynamic Regions and Regional Dynamics” for valuable comments on the earlier drafts of this paper. The author is also grateful for Grants Aid for Scientific Research Grants S 13851002 and A 18203016 from the Japanese Ministry of Education and Science.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masahisa Fujita .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Fujita, M. (2009). Dynamics of Innovation Fields with Endogenous Heterogeneity of People. In: Karlsson, C., Andersson, A., Cheshire, P., Stough, R. (eds) New Directions in Regional Economic Development. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01017-0_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01017-0_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-01016-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-01017-0

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics