Skip to main content

The Location of Industry R&D and the Location of University R&D: How Are They Related?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
New Directions in Regional Economic Development

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

At the same time as we can observe strong tendencies of globalization of R&D (Florida 1997; Cantwell 1998), we also observe strong spatial clustering of R&D and related innovation activities (Audretsch and Feldman 1996). The standard explanation in the literature of the clustering phenomenon is that clustering brings about external knowledge economies, typically in the form of knowledge flows,1 which tend to be spatially bounded (Jaffe et al. 1993). R&D is a typical innovation activity; irrespective of whether it is focused on new products or new processes. Industry – i.e., private firms – and universities are the major performers of R&D. It is well established in the literature that both university and industry R&D have a positive effect on innovation output (often measured by patent applications), but that the effect diminishes with distance because knowledge flows are spatially bound and that clustering is consequently an effective spatial configuration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For reasons given in Sect. 15.2 we use the general term “knowledge flows” instead of the term “knowledge spillovers” commonly used in the literature.

  2. 2.

    Obviously, not all types of university R&D attract industrial R&D. There are reasons to believe that, in particular, university R&D in natural, technical and medical sciences attract industrial R&D but that there are also strong reasons to believe that there are variations between different sectors of industry in terms of how dependent their R&D is on proximity to university R&D. However, although a distinction between different science areas would be interesting, the present paper focuses on the aggregate pattern.

  3. 3.

    Many scholars use very crude measures of physical accessibility. By focusing on physical accessibility and relying on actual travel time distances in the accessibility calculations, we believe that proximity is measured in a coherent fashion, (see also Karlsson and Manduchi 2001; Andersson and Karlsson 2004).

  4. 4.

    Von Hippel (1994) persuasively demonstrates that highly contextual and uncertain knowledge, i.e. what he refers to as “sticky knowledge”, is best transmitted via (preferably frequent) face-to-face interactions. This is in line with the claim by Teece (1998) that knowledge assets are often inherently difficult to copy. Von Hippel’s sticky knowledge is also referred to as tacit knowledge in many studies from the last decade (Kogut and Zander 1992). Tacit knowledge cannot be codified easily in the form of a blueprint or a contract (Mowery and Ziedonis 2001), or a published article (Audretsch and Feldman 1996).

  5. 5.

    Knowledge exchange is defined here as any face-to-face interaction that can contribute to the process of the disclosure, dissemination, transmission, and/or communication of knowledge.

  6. 6.

    In this way face-to-face contacts become a necessary or facilitating condition, though not a sufficient condition, for knowledge transfer.

  7. 7.

    Historically, the transfer/communication of rich information has required proximity and specialized channels to customers, suppliers, and distributors. However, we must acknowledge the possibility that the new developments are undermining the traditional chains and business models, and that new structures – generally less dependent on physical communication channels – might become more and more often an economically viable option (cf. Teece 1998).

  8. 8.

    Interestingly, some authors assume that geography plays no role for the costs of accessing knowledge (Spence 1984; Cohen and Levinthal 1990).

  9. 9.

    Functional regions are delimited based upon the spatial interaction patterns of the economic agents in a country. A functional region is fundamentally characterized by its size, by its density of economic activities, social opportunities and interaction options, and by the frequency of spatial interaction between the actors within the region (Johansson 1997).

  10. 10.

    There is no generally accepted definition of a university. We use the term university here as a collective term for institutions of higher education, whether they are major R&D performers or not. Major R&D performing universities are termed as research universities in this paper.

  11. 11.

    However, there are authors that claim that R&D-intensive and high-tech industries do not necessarily agglomerate (Devereux et al. 1999; Shaver and Flyer (2000); Barrios et al. 2003; Alecke et al., 2003). In her study of Japanese investments in Europe Mariani (2002) found that R&D tends to locate close to production activities.

  12. 12.

    Since p and c are monetary values, \( \alpha \) and \( \sigma \) translate these values to a common preference base (cf. Johansson et al. 2002).

  13. 13.

    This condition is derived in several texts, see inter alia Train (1993).

  14. 14.

    These municipalities are Stockholm, Uppsala, Göteborg, Lund, Umeå, Solna Linköping, Huddinge, Malmö and Luleå.

  15. 15.

    These municipalities are Stockholm, Göteborg, Mölndal, Linköping, Lund, Södertälje, Trollhättan, Malmö, Västerås, Uppsala, Järfälla, Karlstad, Karlskoga, Luleå, Sandviken, Jönköping and Solna.

  16. 16.

    Lagged values are used as instruments.

  17. 17.

    We are grateful to an anonymous referee for emphasizing this point.

References

  • Acs ZJ, Audretsch DB, Feldman MP (1992) Real effects of academic research. Am Econ Rev 82:363–367

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams JD (2001) Comparative localisation of academic and industrial spillovers. NBER Working Paper Series 8292, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A (2002) Technology acquisition strategy for early-stage innovations: measuring the importance of engaging the inventor. Queen’s University (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A, Cockburn IM (2002) University research, industrial R&D and the anchor tenant hypothesis. NBER Working paper 9212, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A, Cockburn IM (2003) The anchor tenant hypothesis: exploring the role of large, local, R&D intensive firms in regional innovation systems. Int J Ind Organ 21:1227–1253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A, Henderson R (2002) Putting patents in context: exploring knowledge transfer from MIT. Manage Sci 48:44–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alecke B et al (2003) New empirical evidence on the geographic concentration of German industries: do high-tech clusters really matter? Ann Reg Sci

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, de Palma A, Thisse J-F (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson M, Karlsson C (2004) The role of accessibility for regional innovation systems. In: Karlsson C, Flensburg P, Hörte SA (eds) Knowledge spillovers and knowledge management. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 283–310

    Google Scholar 

  • Anselin L, Varga A, Acs Z (1997) Local geographical spillovers between university research and high technology innovations. J Urban Econ 42:422–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arundel A, Kabla I (1998) What percentage of innovations are patented? Empirical estimates for European firms. Res Policy 27:127–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Feldman M (1994) Knowledge spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. Discussion Paper 953, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Feldman M (1996) R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. Am Econ Rev 86:630–640

    Google Scholar 

  • Bade FJ, Nerlinger EA (2000) The spatial distribution of new technology-based firms: empirical results for West-Germany. Pap Reg Sci 79:155–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baptista R, Swann P (1998) Do firms in clusters innovate more? Res Policy 27:527–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrios S et al (2003) Agglomeration economies and the location of industries: a comparison of three small European countries. CORE Discussion paper, 2003-67

    Google Scholar 

  • Batten DF, Kobayashi K, Andersson ÅE (1989) Knowledge, nodes and networks: an analytical perspective. In: Andersson ÅE, Batten DF, Karlsson C (eds) Knowledge and industrial organization. Springer, Berlin, pp 31–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Beise M, Stahl H (1999) Public research and industrial innovation in Germany. Res Policy 28:397–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi L, Peri G (2003) Innovation and spillovers in regions: evidence from European patent data. Eur Econ Rev 47:687–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branstetter L (2000) Measuring the link between academic science and industrial innovation: the case of California’s research universities. Paper presented at the NBER Summer Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S (1999) Spatial patterns of innovation: evidence from patent data. In: Gambardella, Malerba (eds) The organization of economic innovation in Europe. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 71–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell J (1998) The globalisation of technology: what remains of the product cycle model? In: Chandler AD, Hagström P, Sölvell O (eds) The dynamic firm: the role of technology, strategy, organization, and regions. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 263–288

    Google Scholar 

  • Cockburn I, Henderson R (1998) Absorptive capacity, coauthoring behaviour and the organisation of research in drug discovery. J Ind Econ XLVI:157–182

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen DW et al (1998) Industry and the academy: uneasy partners in the cause of technological advance. In: Noll (ed) Challenges to research universities. Brooking Institution Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen DW, Levinthal DA (1989) Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D. Econ J 99: 569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen DW, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen DW, Nelson RR, Walsh J (2002) Links and impacts: the influence of public research on industrial R&D. Manage Sci 48:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colyvas J et al (2002) How do university inventions go into practice? Manage Sci 48:61–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes R, Sandler T (1986) The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Devereux MP, Griffith R, Simpson H (1999) The geographic distribution of production activity in the UK. IFS Working Paper W99/26, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Gregorio, Shane S (2000) Why do some universities generate more spillovers than others? University of Maryland, Baltimore (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorfman NS (1983) Route 128: the development of a regional high technology economy. Res Policy 12:299–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Echeverri-Carrol E (2001) Knowledge spillovers in high technology agglomerations: measurement and modelling. In: Fischer, Fröhlich (eds) Knowledge, complexity and innovation systems. Springer, Berlin, pp 146–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Faggian A, McCann P (2006) Human capital flows and regional knowledge assets: a simultaneous equations approach. Oxford Econ Pap 58(3):475–500

    Google Scholar 

  • Felder J, Fier JA, Nerlinger E (1997a) High Tech in den neuen Ländern: Unternehmensgründungen und Standorte. Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsgeographie 41:1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Felder J, Fier JA, Nerlinger E (1997b) Im Osten nichts Neues? Unternehmensgründungen in High-Tech Industrien. In: Harhoff (ed) Unternehmensgründungen – Empirische Analysen für die alten and neuen Bundesländer, vol 7. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 73–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman M (1994a) The geography of innovation. Kluwer, Dordrecht

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman M (1994b) Knowledge complementarity and innovation. Small Bus Econ 6:363–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman M et al (2002) Equity and the technology transfer strategies of American research universities. Manage Sci 48:105–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman MP, Florida R (1994) The geographic sources of innovation: technological infrastructure and product innovation in the United States. Ann Assoc Am Geogr 84:210–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer MM, Johansson B (1994) Networks for process innovation by firms: conjectures from observations in three countries. In: Johansson B, Karlsson C, Westin L (eds) Advances in spatial and network economics series. Springer, Berlin, pp 261–274

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida R (1997) The globalisation of R&D: results from a survey of foreign-affiliated R&D laboratories in the USA. Res Policy 23:85–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florida R, Cohen WM (1999) Engine or infrastructure? The university role in economic development. In: Branscomb LM, Kodama F, Florida R (eds) Industrialising knowledge. University–industry linkages in Japan and the United States. MIT, Cambridge, MA, pp 589–610

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon IR, McCann P, Gordon IR (2000) Industrial clusters: complexes, agglomeration and/or social networks. Urban Stud 37:513–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1979) Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. Bell J Econ 10:92–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D (1997a) Innovation in German manufacturing enterprises: empirical studies on productivity, externalities, corporate finance and tax policy. Universität Mannheim, Mannheim

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D (ed) (1997b) Unternehmensgründungen – Empirische Analysen für die alten and neuen Bundesländer, vol 7. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D (2000) R&D spillovers, technological proximity, and productivity growth – evidence from German panel data. Schmalenbach Bus Rev 52:238–260

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris RG (2001) The knowledge-based economy: intellectual origins and new economic perspectives. Int J Manage Rev 3:21–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson RM, Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M (1994) Numbers up, quality down? Trends in university patenting 1965–1992. Presentation to CEPR/AAAS Conference University Goals, Institutional Mechanisms and the Industrial Transferability of Research, Stanford University, 18–20 March 1994

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson RM, Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M (1998) Universities as a source of commercial technology: a detailed analysis of university patenting, 1965–1988. Rev Econ Stat 80:119–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmberg I, Johansson B, Strömqvist U (2003) A simultaneous model of long-term regional job and population changes. In: Andersson ÅE, Johansson B, Andersson WP (eds), The economics of disappearing distance. Ashgate, Aldershot, pp 153–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Hugosson P, Johansson B (2001) Business trips between functional regions. In: Hugosson P (2001) Interregional business travel and the economics of business interaction. JIBS Dissertation Series No. 009, Jönköping

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB (1989) Real effects of academic research. Am Econ Rev 79:957–970

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R (1993) Geographic localisation of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Q J Econ 108:577–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen R, Thursby M (1998) Proofs and prototypes for sale: the tale of university licensing. NBER Working Paper No. 6698, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B (1997) Regional differentials in the development of economy and population. In: Sörensen (ed) Empirical evidence of regional growth: the centre–periphery discussion. The Expert Committee of the Danish Ministry of the Interior, Copenhagen, pp 107–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B (2005) Parsing the menagerie of agglomeration and network externalities. In: Karlsson C, Johansson B, Stough R (eds) Industrial clusters and inter-firm networks. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 107–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B, Klaesson J, Olsson M (2002) Time distances and labor market integration. Pap Reg Sci 81:305–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson C (1994) From knowledge and technology networks to network technology. In: Johansson B, Karlsson C, Westin L (eds) Advances in spatial and network economics series. Springer, Berlin, pp 207–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson C, Manduchi A (2001) Knowledge spillovers in a spatial context – a critical review and assessment. In: Fischer, Fröhlich (eds) Knowledge, complexity and innovation systems. Springer, Berlin, pp 101–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly M, Hageman A (1999) Marshallian externalities in innovation. J Econ Growth 4:39–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobayashi K (1995) Knowledge network and market structure: an analytical perspective. In: Batten DF, Casti J, Thord R (eds) Networks in action. Communication, economics and human knowledge. Springer, Berlin, pp 127–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Kobayashi K, Andersson ÅE (1994) A Dynamic input–output model with endogenous technical change. In: Johansson B, Karlsson C, Westin L (eds) Advances in spatial and network economics series. Springer, Berlin, pp 243–259

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogut B, Zander U (1992) Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organ Sci 3:383–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liebeskind J et al (1996) Social networks, learning and flexibility: sourcing scientific knowledge in new biotechnology firms. Organ Sci 7:428–443

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim K (2000) The many faces of absorptive capacity: spillovers of copper interconnect technology for semiconductor chips. MIT, Cambridge, MA (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  • Luger M, Goldstein H (1997) What is the role of public universities in regional economic development? In: Bingham R, Mier R (eds) Dilemmas of urban economic development. Issues in theory and practice. Sage, London, pp 104–134

    Google Scholar 

  • MacPherson AD (1998) Academic–industry linkages and small firm innovation: evidence from the scientific instruments sector. Entrepreneurship Reg Dev 10:261–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malo S, Geuna A (2000) Science–technology linkages in an emerging research plattform: the case of combinatorial chemistry and biology. Scientometrics 47:303–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariani M (2002) Next to production or to technological clusters? The economics and management of R&D location. J Manage Gov 6:131–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mills E, Carlino G (1989) Dynamics of county growth. In: Andersson Å et al (eds) Advances in spatial theory and dynamics. Elsevier, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mowery DC, Ziedonis AA (2001) The geographic reach of market and non-market channels of technology transfer: comparing citations and licences of university patents. NBER Working Paper No. 8568, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Narin F, Hamilton KS, Olivastro D (1997) The increasing linkage between U.S. technology and public science. Res Policy 26:317–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (1986) Institutions supporting technical advance in industry. Am Econ Rev 76:186–189

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Nerlinger E (1998) Standorte und Entwicklung junger innovativer Unternehmen: Empirische Ergebnisse für West-Deutschland. ZEW-Schriftenreihe 27. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1934) The theory of economic development. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane S (2002) Selling university technology: patterns from MIT. Manage Sci 48:122–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaver JM, Flyer F (2000) Agglomeration economies, firm heterogeneity, and foreign direct investments in the United States. Strateg Manage J 21:1175–1193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimshoni D (1966) Aspects of scientific entrepreneurship. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel DS, Westhead P, Wright M (2003) Assessing the impact of university science parks on research productivity: exploratory firm-level evidence from the United Kingdom. Int J Ind Organ 21:1357–1369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soete L (2001) The new economy: a European perspective. In: Archibugi D, Lundvall B-Å (eds) The Globalising learning economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 21–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence MA (1984) Cost reduction, competition and industry performance. Econometrica 52: 101–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stuart TE, Shane S (2002) Organisational endowments and the performance of university start-ups. Manage Sci 48:151–170

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (1981) The market for know-how and the efficient international transfer of technology. Ann Am Assoc Polit Soc Sci 458:81–86

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (1998) Capturing value from knowledge assets: the new economy, markets for know-how and intangible assets. Calif Manage Rev 40:55–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teplitz P (1965) Spin-off enterprises from a large government-sponsored laboratory. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Sloan School, MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Thursby J, Thursby M (2002) Who is selling the ivory tower? sources of growth in university licensing. Manage Sci 48:90–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Train K (1993) Qualitative choice analysis – theory econometrics and an application to automobile demand. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Varga A (2000) Local academic knowledge transfers and the concentration of economic activity. J Reg Sci 40:289–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B (1999) Large firms and knowledge flows in the Dutch R&D system: a case study of Philips Electronics. Technol Anal Strateg Manage 11:211–233

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel E (1994) Sticky information and the locus of problem solving: implications for innovation. Manage Sci 40:429–439

    Google Scholar 

  • Wainer HA (1965) The spin-off technology from government-sponsored research laboratories: Lincoln laboratory. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Sloan School, MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziedonis A (1999) Inward technology transfer by firms: the case of university technology licences. University of California, Berkeley (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zucker L, Darby M, Brewer M (1998) Intellectual capital and the birth of US biotechnology enterprises. Am Econ Rev 88:290–306

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Charlie Karlsson .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Karlsson, C., Andersson, M. (2009). The Location of Industry R&D and the Location of University R&D: How Are They Related?. In: Karlsson, C., Andersson, A., Cheshire, P., Stough, R. (eds) New Directions in Regional Economic Development. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01017-0_15

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01017-0_15

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-01016-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-01017-0

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics