Skip to main content

Baseline Approaches to the Labor Theory of Value

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Topics in Classical Micro- and Macroeconomics
  • 1068 Accesses

Abstract

The dominant price theory from the perspective of models of general equilibrium is in terms of rigor the Arrow-Debreu General Equilibrium Theory (GET) of so-called (neoclassical) perfect competition. The most developed framework for national accounting is the System of National Accounts (SNA) of the United Nations in its current form. Both approaches towards a classification and analysis of microeconomic structures flourished in the 1960s and 1970s, but lost in importance thereafter, in the first case, due to the internal limitations of GET in the fulfillment of Smith’s conjecture on the working of market economies and, in the second case, due to a dilution of the current SNA as a rigorous and coherent approach to input–output structures within the System of National Accounts as it was originally formulated by Richard Stone and his research group. Moreover, the Arrow-Debreu world pays little attention to the need for a System of National Accounts (though there have been some attempts to combine these two approaches in the study of the “real” magnitudes usable to characterize market economies).1 It is therefore basically a purely “nominal” approach,2 despite the fact that it is in fact solely a theory of relative prices and thus faces the problem of the choice of a numéraire, which however is not supposed to reflect something truly “real”. It therefore seems to suggest that there is nothing “real” behind the “nominal”, not even as a theoretical construction that can help to understand the movement of “nominal” magnitudes. In addition to its pure “surface” orientation, GET pursues a theory of competition that does not reflect any competition at all, since all individuals and firms are isolated utility or profit maximizing price-takers without any interaction with each other.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Fisher and Shell (1972) for a prominent example.

  2. 2.

    The expression “nominal” is here used in contradistinction to the concept of “real” (“quantity”-oriented) magnitudes of national accounting systems.

  3. 3.

    But based on Marxian categories.

  4. 4.

    See Eatwell et al. (1992) for a summary of Marx’s economics.

  5. 5.

    By Morishima, Okishio, Steedman, Wolfstetter, Krause, Holländer, and others.

  6. 6.

    I have to thank Andrew Kliman for detailed comments on this section of the chapter which contributed to improving its presentation. Of course, the usual caveats apply.

  7. 7.

    A, l are the unit input data of standard input–output analysis, see also Chaps. 1/3, that is augmented by workers average consumption data.

  8. 8.

    In contrast to the simultaneous equations approach there are however no linear equation systems to be solved here.

  9. 9.

    See McGlone and Kliman (1996, p. 46). Note that p t is here interpreted in terms of a historically given vector v t .

  10. 10.

    See McGlone and Kliman (1996, p. 46).

  11. 11.

    Constant capital, variable capital and surplus value are thus all given magnitudes when the price-value iteration is started.

  12. 12.

    This seems to be a general problem for the presentations of the TSSI in the literature, since there meanwhile exist numerous examples for its formulation, but by and large no compact, concise definition for general models of production which avoids the various shortcomings of the examples.

  13. 13.

    A possible solution could be found here by using the distinction between individual and market values in the way proposed in Flaschel (1983a) or alternatively of the kind proposed in Duménil and Levy (1989).

  14. 14.

    If at all, a continuous-input continuous-output model type would here be the more appropriate starting point for the modelling of a capitalist economy, see Foley (1986) for a formulation of this type of approach in the context of Marxian economics.

  15. 15.

    Duménil and Levy (2000a,b).

  16. 16.

    See also Foley (2000).

  17. 17.

    See also Mohun (2004) for further remarks on the literature and an outline of some recent approaches to an accounting structure which relates observable prices to Marxian labour values.

  18. 18.

    y = (IA) − 1 x as usual.

  19. 19.

    An interesting non-standard approach to a definition of labor values – which includes capitalists’ consumption basket into the “means of production” in a stationary economy – has been provided recently by Wright (2007).

References

  • Bródy, A. (1970). Proportions, prices and planning. North Holland: Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bródy, A. (1987). Prices and quantities. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), The new Palgrave series: Problems of the planned economy (pp. 218–226). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G. (1983). Beyond the Transformation Riddle: A Labor Theory of Value. Science and Society,47, 427–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G. (1984). The So-Called ‘Transformation Problem’ Revisited: A Brief Comment. Journal of Economic Theory,33, 340–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G., & Levy, D. (1987). Values and Natural Prices Trapped in Joint Production Pitfalls. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie,47, 15–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G., & Levy, D. (1988). Linear joint production models. Prelude to a reassessment of the classical legacy (value, equilibrium, and disequilibrium). Political Economy. Studies in the Surplus Approach,4, 185–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G., & Levy, D. (1989). Labor Values and the Imputation of Labor Contents. Metroeconomica,40, 159–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G., & Levy, D. (1993). The Economics of the profit rate. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G., & Levy, D. (2000a). The conservation of value. A rejoinder to Alan Freeman. Review of Radical Political Economy,32, 119–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duménil, G., & Levy, D. (2000b). Paolo Guissani’s defense of sequential values. Review of Political Economy and Sciences,4, 179–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., & Newman,P. (Eds.). (1992). The new Palgrave series: Marxian economics. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farjoun, E., & Machover, M. (1983). Laws of chaos. London: Verso Editions and NLB.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, F. M., & Shell, K. (1972). The economic theory of price indices. Two essays on the effects of taste, quality, and technological change. New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (1980). The derivation and comparison of employment multipliers and labour productivity indexes using monetary and physical input–output tables. Economics of Planning.16, 118–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (1983a). Actual labor values in a general model of production. Econometrica,51, 435–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (1983b). Marx, Sraffa und Leontief. Kritik und Ansätze zu ihrer Synthese. Europäische Hochschulschriften. Frankfurt/M.: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (1984). The so-called ‘transformation problem’ revisited. A comment. Journal of Economic Theory,33, 349–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (1995). Fixkapital und Profitabilität. Gesamt- und einzelwirtschaftliche Aspekte. Frankfurt/M.: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D. (1982). The value of money, the value of labor power and the Marxian transformation problem. Review of Radical Political Economy,14, 37–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D. (1983). On Marx’s theory of money. Social Change, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D. (1986). Understanding capital. Cambridge, MA.: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D. (1997). Marx and non-equilibrium economics. Eastern Economic Journal,23, 493–496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D. (2000). Recent developments in the labor theory of value. Review of Radical Political Economics,32, 1–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D. (2002). Temporality and value in Marxian economic theory. New School University, mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A., & Carchedi, G. (Eds.). (1996). Marx and non-equilibrium economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A., Kliman, A., & Wells, J. (Eds.). (2004). The new value controversy and the foundations of economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kliman, A., & McGlone, T. (1999). A temporal single-system interpretation of Marx’s value theory. Review of political economy,11, 33–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kliman, A., & Freeman, A. (2006). Replicating Marx: A reply to Mohun. Capital and Class,88, 117–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kliman, A. (2007). Reclaiming Marx’s capital: A refutation of the myth of inconsistency. London: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krause, U. (1980a). Abstract labor in general joint systems. Metroeconomica, XXXII, 115–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krause, U. (1980b). Money and abstract labour: On the analytical foundations of political economy. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krause, U. (1998). Abstract labour and money. In H. D. Kurz & N. Salvadori (Eds.), The Elgar companion to classical economics (pp. 6–10). Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1954). Capital. A critique of political economy (Vol. 1). New York: Lawrence + Wishart.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGlone, T., & Kliman, A. (1996). One system or two? The transformation of values into prices of production vs. the transformation problem. In A. Freeman & G. Carchedi (Eds.), Marx and non-equilibrium economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mavroudeas, S. (1999). Marx and non-equilibrium economics. Capital and Class, 67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohun, S. (1993). A note on Steedman’s ‘joint production and the new solution to the transformation problem’. Indian Economic Review,XXVIII, 241–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohun, S. (1994). A re(in)statement of the labour theory of value. Cambridge Journal of Economics,18, 391–412.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohun, S. (2003). On the TSSI and the exploitation theory of profit. Capital and Class,81, 85–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohun, S. (2004). The labour theory of value as foundation for empirical investigations. Metroeconomica,55, 65–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohun, S. (2005). On measuring the wealth of nations: the U.S. economy, 1964–2001. Cambridge Journal of Economics,29, 799–815.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohun, S., & Veneziani, R. (2007). The incoherence of the TSSI: A reply to Kliman and Freeman. Capital and Class,92, 139–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mongiovi, G. (2002). Vulgar economy in Marxian garb: a critique of temporal single system marxism. Review of Radical Political Economy, 34, 393–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picard, R. (1979). Gibt es ein Transformationsproblem? In: H. G. Backhaus et al. (Eds.), Gesellschaft – Beiträge zur Marxschen Theorie, 13, 54–68. Frankfurt, a.M.: Edition Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowthorn, R. (1974). Skilled labour in the Marxian system. Bulletin of the Conference of Socialist Economists, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1971). Understanding the Marxian notion of exploitation: A summary of the so-called transformation problem between Marxian values and competitive prices. Journal of Economic Literature,9, 399–431.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A., & Tonak, A. (1994). Measuring the Wealth of Nations. The Political Economy of National Accounts. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovits, A., & Steenge, A. (Eds.). (1996). Prices, growth and cycles. Essays in honor of Andras Bródy. Basingstoke: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1977). Marx after Sraffa. London: New Left Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (1968). A system of national accounts. New York: Studies in Methods, Series F, No.2, Rev.3.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (1993). System of national accounts. http://unstats.un.org/unsd/sna1993/handbooks.asp

  • Veneziani, R. (2004). The Temporal Single-system Interpretation of Marx’s Economics: A Critical Evaluation. Metroeconomica,55, 96–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veneziani, R. (2005). Dynamics, disequilibrium, and Marxian economics: A formal analysis of temporal single-system Marxism. Review of Radical Political Economics,37, 517–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, I. (2007). Nonstandard labor values. Milton Keynes: Open University Discussion Papers in Economics.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Flaschel .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Flaschel, P. (2010). Baseline Approaches to the Labor Theory of Value. In: Topics in Classical Micro- and Macroeconomics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-00324-0_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-00324-0_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-00323-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-00324-0

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics