Skip to main content

Gas Storage in Europe: Toward a Market-Oriented Approach

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Economics of Natural Gas Storage

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Due to pressure reasons, the amount of peak capacity guaranteed by storage companies decreases with the total amount of gas stored underground and is therefore typically larger at the beginning of the winter season and smaller towards the end of it, when inventories are lower. The volume of gas needed as a permanent inventory to maintain adequate reservoir pressures and deliverability rates throughout the withdrawal season is called cushion gas.

  2. 2.

    Helmberger and Weaver analyze different stabilization schemes in an intertemporal equilibrium model for a competitive market when costly inventories are held. A price stabilization policy forcing the market price to be higher than the competitive one will create excess storage and therefore will sacrifice economic efficiency. Producers gain from the government policy, while consumers lose. Edward and Hallwood consider a costly buffer stock whose objective is to maximize the joint expected benefits of the trading partners with respect to the intervention rules.

  3. 3.

    An interesting contribution to this debate is Lindsey (1989). He allows for repeated supply disruption of uncertain duration and arbitrary magnitude. With price rationing of world supply in a disruption, production during undisrupted periods should be speeded up unless costs are raising rapidly with cumulative extraction. With quantity rationing, production should also be speeded up unless the domestic economy is currently nearly self-sufficient.

  4. 4.

    Crawford, Sobel, and Takahashi (1984) propose a dynamic bargaining framework in which the relationship between countries is a sequence of short-term negotiated agreements. The equilibrium involves the oil-rich country alone extracting for the first part of the relationship, exporting to smooth production in both countries until parity is reached. At that time, autarchy ensues, with the oil-rich and the oil-poor countries extracting until their stocks are exhausted. Total extraction is slower than the efficient path that would result if countries could organize their trading relationship by a single long term contract.

  5. 5.

    In Devarajan and Weiner (1989), when disruption is expected to persist at the same intensity, each nation prefers the non-cooperative equilibrium to the cooperative one. If the disruption is expected to get worse, the noncooperative solution will lead to too little stockpile drawn down in the first period when compared to the cooperative solution. If several possible states in the oil market are possible (a normal market or a disruption of one or more possible sizes), the gain in free-riding to build oil stockpile are not worth the gamble and an aggressive stockpiling policy is preferable (Hogan, 1983).

  6. 6.

    Deaton and Laroque (1996) and Chambers and Bailey (1996) have improved the adequation of the models to the data by reinforcing serial correlation in the shocks.

References

  • Chambers, M. J., and Bailey, R. E. (1996). Commodity price fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy, 104(5), 924–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CIEP (2006). The European market for seasonal storage, Discussion paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • CIEP (2008). Pricing natural gas: The outlook for the European market, Clingendael Energy Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, V., Sobel, P. -J., and Takayaski, I. (1984). Bargaining, strategic reserves, and International trade in exhaustible resources. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66(4), 472–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A., and Laroque, G. (1992). On the behaviour of commodity prices. Review of Economic Studies, 59, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A., and Laroque, G. (1996). Competitive storage and commodity price dynamics. Journal of Political Economy, 104(5), 897–923.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devarajan, S., and Weiner, R. J. (1989). Dynamic policy coordination: stockpiling for energy security. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 16(1), 9–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edward, R., and Hallwood C. P. (1980). The determination of optimum buffer stock intervention rules. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 156–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • EUROGAS (2006). Annual Report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ford, A. (2004). Simulating the impacts of a strategic fuels reserve in California. Energy Policy, 33(4), 483–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helmberger, P. and Weaver, R. (1977). Welfare implications of commodity storage under Uncertainty. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 59(4), 639–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilman, A. L., and Van Long, N. (1983). Pricing and depletion of an exhaustible resource when there is anticipation of trade disruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(2), 215–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hogan, W. (1983). Oil stockpiling: Help thy neighbor. Energy-Journal, 4(3), 49–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffler, F. and Kluber, M. (2007). Demand for storage of natural gas in northwestern Europe: Trends 2005–30. Energy Policy, 35, 5206–5219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, H. A. J. (1984). Optimal stockpiling in a high-risk commodity market: The case of Copper. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 8(2), 211–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindsey, R. (1989). Import disruptions, exhaustible resources, and intertemporal security of supply. Canadian Journal of Economics, 22(2), 340–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Massel, B. (1969). Price stabilization and welfare. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83, 284–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modjtahedi, B. and Movassagh, N. (2005). Natural-gas futures: Bias, predictive performance, and the theory of storage. Energy Economics, 27, 617–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newbery, D., and Stiglitz, J. E. (1981). The theory of commodity price stabilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nichols, A. and zeckhauser, R. (1977). Stockpiling strategies and cartel prices. The Bell Journal of Economics, 8(1), 66–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oi, W. (1961). The desirability of price instability under perfect competition. Econometrica, 29, 58–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck, R. (2001). The dynamics of commodity spot and future markets: A primer. The Energy Journal, 22(3), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (1977). An economic analysis of the conservation of depletable natural resources. Draft Report, IEA, Section III.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sweeney, J. (1977). Economics of depletable resources: Market forces and intertemporal bias. Review of Economic Studies, 44, 125–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teisberg, T. J. (1981). A dynamic programming model of the U.S. strategic petroleum reserve. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 526–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky, S. J. (1976). The distribution of welfare gains from price stabilization: The case of multiplicative disturbances. International Economic Review, 17, 133–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urìa, R. and Williams, J. (2007). The supply of storage for natural gas in California. The Energy Journal, 28, 31–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waugh, F. V. (1944). Does the consumer benefit from price instability? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 53, 602–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, J. C., and Wright, B. D. (1991). Storage and commodity markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wilman, J. D., and Tolley G. S. (1977). The Foreign dependence question. The Journal of Political Economy, 85(2), 323–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, B. D., and Williams J. C. (1982). The Roles of Public and Private Storage in Managing Oil Import Disruptions. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 341–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anna Cretì .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Cretì, A. (2009). Gas Storage in Europe: Toward a Market-Oriented Approach. In: Cretì, A. (eds) The Economics of Natural Gas Storage. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-79407-3_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-79407-3_1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-79406-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-540-79407-3

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics