Skip to main content

Product Innovation and Macroeconomic Dynamics

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Complex Systems Modeling and Simulation in Economics and Finance (CEF 2015)

Part of the book series: Springer Proceedings in Complexity ((SPCOM))

Included in the following conference series:

Abstract

We develop an agent-based macroeconomic model in which product innovation is the fundamental driver of growth and business cycle fluctuations. The model builds on a hedonic approach to the product space and product innovation developed in Georges (A hedonic approach to product innovation for agent-based macroeconomic modeling, 2011).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    While we are working with a representative consumer in the present paper for convenience, it is a simple step in the agent-based modeling framework to relax that assumption and allow for idiosyncratic variation of consumer preferences.

  2. 2.

    This is essentially the approach taken by Lancaster, and shares some similarities with others such as [5, 35]. The primary deviation of our approach from that of Lancaster is the construction of our home production function g(q).

  3. 3.

    This vector is associated with good i, and it is convenient to assume that the complementarities are independent across goods (i.e., that the vectors z-compi,k and z-compk,i are independent).

  4. 4.

    Note that if ρ1 = 1, the number of viable products in the economy would be strongly limited by the number of hedonic elements, as in Lancaster, who employs a linear activity analysis to link goods and characteristics.

  5. 5.

    Note that this introduces a (fractional) integer constraint on the consumer’s optimization and search problem. λ > 0 but need not be less than one.

  6. 6.

    This weak form of preferential attachment supports specialization in the hedonic quality space.

  7. 7.

    Each firm’s recent profits and recent R&D activity are (respectively) measured as exponentially weighted moving averages of its past profits and R&D activity.

  8. 8.

    I.e., if πH > πL, then π1 = πH and π2 = πL, and firms with relatively low recent R&D activity switch R&D on with a probability that is greater the larger is the difference between π1 and π2.

  9. 9.

    Process innovation that affects these parameters across firms and over time can easily be introduced.

  10. 10.

    A recent literature argues that the growth of internet retail has allowed niche products that better suit existing consumer preferences to become profitable, eroding the market shares of more broadly popular “superstar” products [8, 9].

  11. 11.

    We exclude other sources of business cycle fluctuations and growth from the model to focus on the role of product innovation .

  12. 12.

    Below, we suppress the latter effect, standardizing productivity across firms in order to focus more directly on product innovation .

  13. 13.

    Intuitively, if some firms or sectors remain large and/or central to the economy, even under highly disaggregated measurement, then idiosyncratic shocks will have aggregate effects. For formalizations, see, for example, [1, 3, 10, 18, 22, 27].

  14. 14.

    The number of firm in this simulation is small (1000), but can easily be scaled up to several million. Similarly the number of hedonic characteristics (50) can be increased easily (though in both cases, of course, at some computational cost).

  15. 15.

    In the representative agent case, the multiplier for output is \({1\over \eta - 1}\), where η is the markup.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., Carvalho, V. M., Ozdaglar, A., & Tahbaz-Selehi, A. (2012). The network origins of aggregate fluctutations. Econometrica, 80(5), 1977–1016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Acemoglu, D., Akcigit, U., Bloom, N., & Kerr, W. R. (2013). Innovation, reallocation and growth. In NBER WP 18933.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Acemoglu, D., Akcigit, U., & Kerr, W. R. (2015). Networks and the macroeconomy: An empirical exploration. In NBER macroeconomic annual (Vol. 30).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Akcigit, U., & Kerr, W. R. (2018). Growth through heterogeneous innovations. Journal of Political Economy, 126(4), 1374–1443. Akcigit, U., & Kerr, W. R. (2018). Growth through heterogeneous innovations. Journal of Political Economy (Vol. 136) No.4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75(299), 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Bernard, A. B., Redding, S. J., & Schott, P. K. (2010). Multi-product firms and product switching. American Economic Review, 100(1), 70–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Broda, C., & Weinstein, D. E. (2010). Product creation and destruction: Evidence and price implications. American Economic Review, 100(3), 691–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Brynjolfsson, E., Hu, Y., & Smith, M. D. (2010). The longer tail: The changing shape of Amazon’s sales distribution curve. Manuscript, MIT Sloan School.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Brynjolfsson, E., Hu, Y., & Simester, D. (2011). Goodbye Pareto principle, hello long tail: The effect of search costs on the concentration of product sales. Management Science, 57(8), 1373–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Carvalho, V. M., & Gabaix, X. (2013). The great diversification and its undoing. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1697–1727.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Chen, S. H., & Chie, B. T. (2005). A functional modularity approach to agent-based modeling of the evolution of technology. In A. Namatame et al. (Eds.), The complex networks of economic interactions: Essays in agent-based economics and econophysics (Vol. 567, pp. 165–178). Heidelberg: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  12. Chen, S. H., & Chie, B. T. (2007). Modularity, product innovation, and consumer satisfaction: An agent-based approach. In International Conference on Intelligent Data Engineering and Automated Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Chiarli, T., Lorentz, A., Savona, M., & Valente, M. (2010). The effect of consumption and production structure on growth and distribution: A micro to macro model. Metroeconomica, 61(1), 180–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Chiarli, T., Lorentz, A., Savona, M., & Valente, M. (2016). The effect of demand-driven structural transformations on growth and technical change. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26(1), 219–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Chie, B. T., & Chen, S. H. (2014). Non-price competition in a modular economy: An agent-based computational model. Manuscript, U. Trento.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Chie, B. T., & Chen, S. H. (2014). Competition in a new industrial economy: Toward an agent-based economic model of modularity. Administrative Sciences, 2014(4), 192–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., van der Hoog, S., & Neugart, M. (2018). Agent-based macroeconomic modeling and policy analysis: The Eurace@Unibi model. In S. H. Chen, M. Kaboudan, & Ye-Rong Du (Eds.), Handbook of computational economics and finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Delli Gatti, D., Gaffeo, E., Gallegati, M., & Giulioni, G. (2008). Emergent macroeconomics: An agent-based approach to business fluctuations. Berlin:Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., & Roventini, A. (2005). An evolutionary model of endogenous business cycles. Computational Economics, 27(1), 3–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Fagiolo, G., & Roventini, A. (2017). Macroeconomic policy in DSGE and agent-based models redux: New developments and challenges ahead. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 20(1).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J. C., & Syverson, C. (2008). Reallocation, firm turnover, and efficiency: Selection on productivity or profitability? American Economic Review, 98(1), 394–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Gabaix, X. (2011). The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 79, 733–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Georges, C. (2011). A hedonic approach to product innovation for agent-based macroeconomic modeling. Manuscript, Hamilton College.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Hidalgo, C. A., Klinger, B., Barabasi, A. L., & Hausmann, R. (2007). The product space conditions the development of nations. Science, 317, 482–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Hommes, C., & Iori, G. (2015). Introduction to special issue crises and complexity. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 50, 1–4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Horvath, M. (2000). Sectoral shocks and aggregate fluctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, 69–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Hottman, C., Redding, S. J., & Weinstein, D. E. (2014). What is ‘firm heterogeneity’ in trade models? The role of quality, scope, markups, and cost. Manuscript, Columbia U.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Jackson, L. F. (1984). Hierarchic demand and the engel curve for variety. Review of Economics and Statistics, 66, 8–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Klette, J., & Kortum, S. (2004). Innovating firms and aggregate innovation. Journal of Political Economy, 112(5), 986–1018.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Lancaster, K. J. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74(2), 132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Lancaster, K. J. (1966). Change and innovation in the technology of consumption. American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 14–23.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Marengo, L., & Valente, M. (2010). Industrial dynamics in complex product spaces: An evolutionary model. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 21(1), 5–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Pintea, M., & Thompson, P. (2007). Technological complexity and economic growth. Review of Economic Dynamics, 10, 276–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Strotz, R. H. (1957). The empirical implications of a utility tree. Econometrica, 25(2), 269–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Sutton, J. (2007) Market share dynamics and the “Persistance of leadership debate. American Ecmomic Review, 97(1), 222–241.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Valente, M. (2012). Evolutionary demand: A model for boundedly rational consumers. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 22, 1029–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Windrum, P., & Birchenhall, C. (1998). Is product life cycle theory a special case? Dominant designs and the emergence of market niches through coevolutionary-learning. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 9(1), 109–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to participants at CEF 2015 and a referee for useful comments, suggestions, and discussions. All errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christophre Georges .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Representative Agent Benchmark

Appendix: Representative Agent Benchmark

Consider the case in which all firms are identical and each starts with a 1/n share of the total market. Suppose further that all firms engage in R&D in every period and experience identical innovations over time.

In this case, the equal individual market shares will persist, since there is no reason for consumers to switch between firms with identical product qualities and identical prices. Further, there is a unique equilibrium for the real production and sales of consumer goods Y at which demand and supply are in balance. At this equilibrium, aggregate real activity depends on the markup η, the per firm overhead labor costs H and R, the wage rate W (for production workers), labor productivity A (for production workers), and the number of firms n. Specifically, at this equilibrium \(Y = ({1\over \eta -1}) \cdot {A\over W}\cdot (H+R) \cdot n\). See below for details. Further, this equilibrium is a steady state of the agent dynamics in the model and is locally stable under those dynamics. If, for example, firms all start with production less than steady state production, then since the markup η > 1, demand will be greater than production for each firm, and production will converge over time to the steady state equilibrium.

We can see this as follows. Since all firms are identical, they produce identical quantities q of their goods. Then total labor income is:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} E=n\cdot \left[{W\over A}\cdot q + H + R\right] {} \end{aligned} $$
(4)

Each firm also charges an identical price p for its good, which is a markup η on marginal cost

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rcl} p = \eta\cdot \text{MC} \\ \text{MC} = {W\over A}{} \end{array} \end{aligned} $$
(5)

and so produces and sells

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} q = {E\over n\cdot p} {} \end{aligned} $$
(6)

units of its good.

These relationships yield the following steady state equilibrium value for (per firm) production.

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} q^* = {(H+R)\cdot {A\over W} \over \eta-1} {} \end{aligned} $$
(7)

We can see that ∂q (H + R) > 0, ∂q ∂A > 0, ∂q ∂W < 0, and ∂q ∂η < 0. These are all demand driven. An increase in the cost of overhead labor (H or R) raises the incomes of overhead workers, raising AD and thus equilibrium output. An increase in labor productivity A will cause firms to lower their prices, raising aggregate demand and equilibrium output. Similarly an increase in the wage rate W of production workers or in the mark-up η will cause firms to raise their prices, lowering AD and equilibrium output.

Further, if in this representative agent case firms follow simple one period adaptive expectations for demand, then firm level output dynamics are given by:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} q_t = {1\over \eta}\cdot q_{t-1} + {1\over \eta}\cdot (H+R)\cdot {A\over W} {} \end{aligned} $$
(8)

Thus, given η > 1, the steady state equilibrium q is asymptotically stable.

Total market output in the steady state equilibrium is just

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rcl} Y^* = n\cdot q^* \\ = {n\cdot (H+R)\cdot {A\over W} \over \eta-1} {} \end{array} \end{aligned} $$
(9)

Clearly, this will be constant as long as there is no change in the parameters H, R, A, W, η and n. If we were to allow them to change, growth in the number of firms n or the productivity of production labor A would cause equilibrium total production Y to grow over time, while balanced growth in production wages W and labor productivity A would have no impact on equilibrium production. Note that, in the full heterogeneous agent model, while all of the parameters above are fixed, the fraction of firms adopting R&D investment varies endogenously, contributing to the disequilibrium dynamics of the model.

Importantly for the present paper, note that the representative agent steady state equilibrium production Y above is entirely independent of product quality . Improvements in product quality will, however, increase consumer utility, or equivalently, the quality adjusted value of total production at this equilibrium. Specifically, given the nested CES formulation of utility, if the magnitudes of all product characteristics grow at rate g due to innovation, then the growth rate of consumer utility will converge in the long run to g. If the magnitudes of different characteristics grow at different rates, the growth rate of utility will converge to the rate of growth of the fastest growing characteristic. All else equal, the long run growth path of utility will be lower in the latter case than in the former case.

It is also worth noting that, at the representative agent steady state equilibrium above, firms make zero profit. Revenues net of the cost of production labor are just great enough to cover all overhead labor costs. Once we move to the heterogeneous firm case, in the comparable steady state equilibrium, profits are distributed around zero across firms. Firms will vary as to R&D investment status, with firms who are not engaging in R&D investment saving overhead cost R per period. Firms will also vary with respect to demand shares (driven by product qualities which are themselves related to past investments in R&D ), and firms with relatively high demand shares are able to spread overhead cost over greater sales. Thus, for two firms with the same overhead cost (i.e., the same current R&D investment status), the firm with greater demand for its product will have higher profit, while for two firms with the same product demand shares, the one with the lower overhead cost (lower current R&D investment) will have higher profit. Firms that face chronic losses will eventually fail and be replaced.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Georges, C. (2018). Product Innovation and Macroeconomic Dynamics. In: Chen, SH., Kao, YF., Venkatachalam, R., Du, YR. (eds) Complex Systems Modeling and Simulation in Economics and Finance. CEF 2015. Springer Proceedings in Complexity. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-99624-0_11

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics