Skip to main content

Recent Results on Implementation with Complete Information

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Social Design

Part of the book series: Studies in Economic Design ((DESI))

Abstract

The origins of the theory of mechanism design can be traced back to the debate on the relative merits of centralized planning and free markets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Although published in 1999, drafts of the paper have been in circulation since 1978.

  2. 2.

    See, for instance, Bull and Watson (2007), Kartik and Tercieux (2012) on implementation with evidence, Dutta and Sen (2012), Matsushima (2008a,b), Ortner (2015), Saporiti (2014) and Lombardi and Yoshihara (2011), for the case when some individuals have a “small” preference for honesty, and Lee and Sabourian (2011), Mezzetti and Renou (2017) for repeated Nash implementation.

  3. 3.

    Note that in the one-stage implementation problem, utility can be ordinal.

  4. 4.

    The reader is referred to Jackson (2001) and Maskin and Sjostrom (2002) for very comprehensive surveys of the literature.

  5. 5.

    Matsushima (2008a,b), Kartik and Tercieux (2012), Lombardi and Yoshihara (2011), Ortner (2015) also assume that some individuals have a “small” preference for honesty.

  6. 6.

    Kartik and Tercieux (2012) also prove essentially the same result in a cardinal framework.

  7. 7.

    A mechanism is bounded if any weakly dominated strategy is weakly dominated by a strategy which is itself undominated. Jackson et al. (1994) characterize the class of social choice correspondences that are implemented in undominated Nash equilibrium by bounded mechanisms.

  8. 8.

    Their result goes through even if there is just one partially honest individual. But, then the construction of the mechanism would depend upon the identity of this individual and so the result will not be detail-free.

  9. 9.

    See, for instance, Manzini and Mariotti (2007).

References

  • Bull, J., & Watson, J. (2007). Hard evidence and mechanism design. Games and Economic Behavior, 58, 75–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Clippel, G. (2014). Behavioral implementation. American Economic Review, 104, 2975–3002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, B., & Sen, A. (1991). A necessary and sufficient condition for two-person Nash implementation. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 121–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, B., & Sen, A. (2012). Nash implementation with partially honest individuals. Games and Economic Behavior, 74, 154–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliaz, K. (2002). Fault tolerant implementation. Review of Economic Studies, 69, 589–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holden, R., Kartik, N., & Tercieux, O. (2014). Games and Economic Behavior, 83, 284–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L. (1960). Optimality and informational efficiency in resource allocation processes. In K. Arrow, S. Karlin, & P. Suppes (Eds.), Mathematical methods in social sciences (pp. 27–46). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L. (1972). On Informationally decentralized systems. In C. McGuire & R. Radner, (Eds.), Decision and Organization (pp. 297–336). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. O. (1992). Implementation in undominated.strategies: A look at bounded mechanisms. Review of Economic Studies, 59, 757–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. O. (2001). A crash course in implementation theory. Social Choice and Welfare, 18, 655–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. O., Palfrey, T. R., & Srivastava, S. (1994). Undominated Nash implementation in bounded mechanisms. Games and Economic Behavior, 6, 474– 501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kandori, M., Mailath, G., & Rob, R. (1993). Learning, mutations and long run equilibria in games. Econometrica, 61, 29–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kartik, N., & Tercieux, O. (2012). Implementation with evidence? Theoretical Economics, 7, 323–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lombardi, M., & Yoshihara, N. (2011). Partially-honest Nash implementation: Characterization results. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1759924

    Google Scholar 

  • Lange, O. (1936). On the economic theory of socialism. Review of Economic Studies, 4, 53–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., & Sabourian, H. (2011). Efficient repeated implementation. Econometrica, 79, 1967–1994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, A. (1944). The economics of control. New York: McMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manzini, P., & Mariotti, M. (2007). Sequentially rationalizable choice. American Economic Review, 97, 1824–1839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E. (1999). Nash equilibrium and welfare optimality. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 23–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., & Sjostrom, T. (2002). Implementation theory. In K. J. Arrow, A. K. Sen, & K. Suzumura (Eds.), Handbook of social choice and welfare (pp. 237–288). North Holland, Amsterdam.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima, H. (2008a). Behavioral aspects of implementation theory. Economics Letters, 100, 161–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima, H. (2008b). Role of honesty in full implementation. Journal of Economic Theory, 139, 353–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mezzetti, C., & Renou, L. (2017). Repeated Nash implementation. Theoretical Economics, 12, 249–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, J., & Repullo, R. (1990). Nash implementation: A full characterization. Econometrica, 58, 1083– 1099.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ortner, J. (2015). Direct implementation with minimally honest individuals. Games and Economic Behavior, 90, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saporiti, A. (2014). Securely implementable social choice rules with partially honest agents. Journal of Economic Theory, 154, 216–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hayek, F. (1944). The road to serfdom. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1935). Die Wirtschaftsrechnung im Sozialistischen Gemeinwesen. In F. von Hayek (Ed.), Collectivist economic planning. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, P. (1993). The evolution of conventions. Econometrica, 61, 57–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bhaskar Dutta .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Dutta, B. (2019). Recent Results on Implementation with Complete Information. In: Trockel, W. (eds) Social Design. Studies in Economic Design. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93809-7_15

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics