Skip to main content

Origins and Consequences of Divergent Private Sector Organization in Puebla and Querétaro

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 146 Accesses

Part of the book series: Latin American Political Economy ((LAPE))

Abstract

Organized business in Puebla and Querétaro exhibited systematic differences in their political and economic preferences beginning in the 1980s. This chapter provides evidence that business associations in Querétaro supported growth-enhancing policies such as economic integration and investments in education and infrastructure, while their counterparts in Puebla tended to demand protection from competition and industry-specific subsidies. Puebla’s peak business chambers also had strong partisan preferences against the PRI, while organized business in Querétaro was non-partisan. These differences arose because Querétaro’s business associations successfully incorporated large, foreign and domestic manufacturing firms into their ranks starting in the 1960s, while in Puebla, large firms opted out of business associations, ensuring these organizations continued to be dominated by local firms in traditional sectors. Differences in the organization and preferences of business associations had major consequences for the pattern of interaction between the public and private sectors in the two states.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This expectation also derives from Olson’s work on collective action (1982) and follows from the intuition that when an association is encompassing, its members benefit more from an improvement in overall welfare than a redistribution of existing wealth to a particular group. Encompassing associations thus mitigate distributional conflict within the business sector (Durand and Silva 1998).

  2. 2.

    Olson (1982) predicted that, for these reasons, encompassing business associations would be rare in practice.

  3. 3.

    In particular, large firms can more easily bear the costs of organizing business associations (see Shadlen 2004).

  4. 4.

    The intuition is that large, internationally integrated firms are more likely to benefit from such policies. However, this expectation may not hold for large firms in sectors such as natural resources and regulated utilities, or for large multinationals that carry out training and technology development in-house (see Schneider 2014). Chapter 2 discusses these issues in more detail.

  5. 5.

    The Díaz regime, or Porfiriato, lasted from 1876 until 1910, although Díaz ruled indirectly through a close ally between 1880 and 1884. See Haber et al. (2003) for a description of the relationship between Díaz and Mexican capitalists.

  6. 6.

    The chambers’ dependence on the government—and resulting limitations on independent, critical postures—derived from several sources. Most fundamentally, the combination of mandatory affiliation and government control over the formation of new chambers meant chambers’ influence and, in fact, their viability depended on the state. In several instances in the 1960s, groups of businesses representing the chemical or automotive sectors sought to break from Canacintra, but the government, which retained the exclusive right to sanction new chambers, refused to recognize them (Schneider 2004).

  7. 7.

    Leaders of the Confederation of Mexican Workers (CTM) and National Peasants Confederation (CNC) generally received a share of PRI nominations for seats in the local and national legislatures.

  8. 8.

    Industry protection relied heavily on import licensing, which excluded the possibility of importing products for which close domestic substitutes existed. The structure of protection had an escalating nature in which downstream production stages received greater protection. Moreno-Brid and Ros (2009) report that effective protection levels reached 85 percent for consumer durables and capital goods by 1960.

  9. 9.

    Shafer (1973) reports that federal officials regularly consulted with business leaders on taxation, price controls, and trade policies, especially when new legislation was under consideration. In light of these relations, Shafer concludes “the fiction is that the Revolution thrust business out of politics” (1973; 133).

  10. 10.

    The CMHN invested heavily in both the CCE and Coparmex during this period. The CCE developed a full-time staff, research capabilities, and a public presence through publications and media outreach (Schneider 2004).

  11. 11.

    Coparmex President Alfredo Sandóval did not obfuscate on this point, asserting that “instead of reacting, we want to participate in the process of making decisions over the long-term” (quoted in Montesinos Carrera 1992).

  12. 12.

    The 1982 default led to a deep recession in 1983, and economic malaise would continue for most of 1980s.

  13. 13.

    Ernesto Ruffo Appel, the victor in Baja California’s landmark 1989 gubernatorial race, had been president of the state’s peak business association before entering politics. Business people-turned-politicians subsequently won governorships for the PAN in Guanajuato in 1995 and Querétaro in 1997. Entrepreneurs were the driving force behind the rise of the PAN in the state of Chihuahua, as documented by Mizrahi (1994).

  14. 14.

    Mexico’s textile exports increased ten-fold between 1940 and 1945 as US, European, and Japanese producers channeled all textile goods to the war effort. Despite a post-war slump, the sector accounted for 19 percent of national manufacturing output in 1955 (Gauss 2010).

  15. 15.

    In 1950 Querétaro had a population of 286,000, compared to 1.6 million for Puebla.

  16. 16.

    The close personal relationships between Bernardo Quintana, the president of ICA, and the queretano political and economic elite thus proved crucial to the state’s initial industrial surge in the 1960s (see Miranda 2005).

  17. 17.

    The motivation for the company’s decision to establish its main production facility in Puebla (the firm had had a small presence in the State of Mexico beginning in 1962) remains subject to debate. Most observers point to the influence of President Gustavo Díaz Ordaz, a native of Puebla, who presumably intervened in favor of his home state.

  18. 18.

    The firms investing in these sectors include Hylsa, part of a Monterrey-based conglomerate, in steel and metal; Alumex, a major aluminum producer; and Polimeros de México in the chemical and plastics sectors.

  19. 19.

    The modifier “modern” or “modernizing” is applied in a relative way. Mexico’s domestic business groups were far from a model of productivity and efficiency, and foreign investors generally did not deploy state-of-the-art technology in Mexico. Still, these firms had by the 1980s developed modern production processes based on advanced (if generally imported) technology. As Mexico reduced trade barriers, links between domestic groups and the global economy brought these firms closer to the technology frontier (Castañeda 2008). Compared with small local business, then, the large firms that arrived en masse in Puebla and Querétaro beginning in the 1960s were indeed modern, and this gap would increase over time.

  20. 20.

    These three firms were among the state’s ten largest exporters in 1986 (Secretaría de Desarrollo Económico de Querétaro 1986).

  21. 21.

    Representatives of ICA also participated in the creation of Coparmex in Querétaro (see Chapter 4).

  22. 22.

    While the state’s first panista governor, Ignacio Loyola Vera, had previously been president of Coparmex, other past leaders such as Alejandro Espinosa Medina, Tonatiuh Salinas Muñoz, and Rafael Rodrigo Tolentino have served in local PRI governments.

  23. 23.

    Notably, the CCE did not take hold in Querétaro because business leaders decided it would compromise the independence of existing groups. Interview with Alejandro Espinosa Medina, 17 March 2016. Querétaro finally saw the establishment of the CCE in 2014, but it remains a marginal actor in the state’s politics.

  24. 24.

    A partial exception is Luis Regordosa Valenciana, CCE president from 2002 to 2005, who ran Grupo Embotellador Bret, which bottled and distributed Pepsi products in four southeastern states, including Puebla. Regordosa took the firm public in 2002, the first public listing of a Puebla firm since the failure of Banco de Oriente in the 1990s. See CNN Expansión: http://expansion.mx/negocios/2008/04/21/las-batallas-de-geusa and El Universal http://archivo.eluniversal.com.mx/finanzas/27810.html.

  25. 25.

    The second and third generations of many traditional textile families often pursued other business activities such as commerce, real estate, and construction (Villavicencio 2013). CCE Presidents José Yitani and Juan José Rodríguez Posada reflect this pattern.

  26. 26.

    As Díaz Aldret (2011) and Miranda (2005) describe, the Club de Industriales , founded in the early 1970s, was envisioned precisely for the purpose of creating a space for the social integration of new business people arriving in Querétaro. See Chapter 4 for more details of this institution.

  27. 27.

    Interview with Volkswagen executive, 26 January 2016.

  28. 28.

    Interview with Alejandro Espinosa Medina, 15 April 2016.

  29. 29.

    The sources used for this exercise are the major local print media in the two states—El Sol de Puebla, Diario de Querétaro, and Noticias de la Mañana (Querétaro). Data were collected for particular date ranges that correspond to major economic and political events such as Mexico’s entry into GATT, the signing of NAFTA, presidential elections, and major policy debates. Each statement of an economic or political position by a representative of a local business organization was identified, recorded, and coded according to the primary view expressed. The resulting dataset includes 634 opinions expressed by 250 local business people representing 54 associations. See Appendix I for a description of the methodology used in this exercise and discussion of issues surrounding bias in local newspapers in Mexico.

  30. 30.

    To test this proposition, the statements included in the dataset were divided into two categories: “political” views such as support for electoral participation, statements of partisan preference, or evaluation of particular officials; and “economic” views addressing trade liberalization, inflation, budgets, and a range of other policy issues.

  31. 31.

    As described above, the periods from which business leaders’ opinions are drawn overlap with either major economic changes such as Mexico’s entry into GATT and the NAFTA negotiations or major political events such as elections. The former are referred to as “economic events” and the latter as “political events.”

  32. 32.

    As opposed to a non-partisan statement, such as calling for “peaceful elections,” or for the vote to be respected, which made up an important part of private sector discourse around elections in both states. By contrast, the Puebla business sector often made comments suggesting that any threat to democracy or social peace emanated from “the party that has refused to accept losses” or “wants to always keep power”—criticizing the PRI without mentioning the party by name. Appendix I provides more examples of the exact language used to identify each class of statement.

  33. 33.

    Diario Cambio, 13 February 1985, “Los empresarios sí aspiran al poder, dice Jorge Ocejo”; emphasis added.

  34. 34.

    See, for example, Diario Cambio 8 March 1986, “Una sociedad libre y democrática no requiere de tanta burocracia: Cabañas” and Diario Cambio 20 December 1984, “En términos reales no hubo mejoría económica: C. Textil.”

  35. 35.

    These statements provoked a sharp rebuke from CTM leaders who called them “a political fiction.” Diario Cambio 1 August 1984, “Se quiere implanter el socialism en el país: empresarios”.

  36. 36.

    Support for domestic competition includes statements in favor of price liberalization and the sentiment that competition, productivity, and quality are key to economic progress. “Active development policies” include support for industrial parks, technical training, and policies to promote domestic supply chains. See Appendix I. As discussed in Chapter 2, in labeling economic integration “broadly growth-enhancing,” I appeal both to classical trade theory and the context of pre-reform Mexico, where trade protection created particular benefits for narrow sub-groups of firms.

  37. 37.

    In this regard, the Querétaro branch of Canacintra is something of an outlier, given the national chamber’s ambivalent views regarding Mexico’s economic reforms, which went against the interests of its main constituents (see Shadlen 2004).

References

  • Alba Vega, Carlos. 1997. “La COECE: un caso de cooperación entre los sectores público y privado en México”. Comercio Exterior 47: 150–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basave, Jorge. 2001. Un siglo de grupos empresariales en México. Mexico City: Miguel Ángel Porrúa.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camp, Roderic A. 1989. Entrepreneurs and Politics in Twentieth-century Mexico. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canacintra-Querétaro. 1984. Directorio Industrial. Querétaro: Canacintra.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castañeda, Gonzalo. 2008. “Evolución de los grupos económicos durante el periodo 1940–2008”. In Historia económica general de México. De la colonia a nuestros días, ed. Sandra Kuntz Ficker. Mexico City: El Colegio de México/Secretaría de Economía.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coparmex-Querétaro. 2013. 35° Aniversario. Querétaro: Centro Empresarial de Querétaro.

    Google Scholar 

  • Díaz Aldret, Ana. 2011. La paz y sus sombras: cultura política en el estado de Querétaro. Querétaro: Universidad Autónoma de Querétaro.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durand, Francisco, and Eduardo Silva. 1998. Organized Business, Economic Change, and Democracy in Latin America. Boulder: Lynne Reinner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gamboa Ojeda, Leticia. 2008. “Empresarios asturianos de la industria textil de Puebla, 1895–1930”. Dimensión Antropológica 44 (septiembre/diciembre): 15–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrido, Celso, and Cristina Puga. 1992. “Transformaciones del empresariado mexicano en la década de los ochenta”. In Los empresarios mexicanos, ayer y hoy, ed. Cristina Puga and Ricardo Tirado. Mexico City: UNAM and Consejo Mexicano de Ciencias Sociales.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gauss, Susan M. 2010. Made in Mexico: Regions, Nation, and the State in the Rise of Mexican Industrialism, 1920s–1940s. College Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haber, Stephen, Armando Razo, and Noel Maurer. 2003. The Politics of Property Rights: Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876–1929. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • King, Timothy. 1970. Mexico: Industrialization and Trade Policies Since 1940. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, Anne. 1974. “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society”. American Economic Review 64 (3): 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxfield, Sylvia, and Ben Ross Schneider. 1997. Business and the State in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miranda Correa, Eduardo. 2005. Del Querétaro Rural al Industrial: 1940–1973. Mexico City: Miguel Ángel Porrua.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizrahi, Yemile. 1994. A New Conservative Opposition: The Politics of Entrepreneurs in Chihuahua 1983–1992. Ph.D. Thesis, University of California, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003. From Martyrdom to Power: The Partido Acción Nacional in Mexico. South Bend: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesinos Carrera, Rafael. 1992. “El discurso empresarial en 1985”. In Los empresarios mexicanos, ayer y hoy, ed. Cristina Puga and Ricardo Tirado. Mexico City: UNAM and Mexican Council of Social Sciences.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos, and Jaime Ros. 2009. Development and Growth in the Mexican Economy: A Historical Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pansters, Wil. 1995. Politics and Power in Puebla: The Political History of a Mexican State, 1937–1987. Amsterdam: CEDLA Latin American Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pastor, Manuel, and Carol Wise. 1994. “The Origins and Sustainability of Mexico’s Free Trade Policy”. International Organization 48 (3): 459–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rettberg, Angelika. 2005. “Business Versus Business? Grupos and Organized Business in Colombia”. Latin American Politics and Society 47 (1): 31–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodríguez, Victoria Elizabeth. 1997. Decentralization in Mexico: From Reforma Municipal to Solidaridad to Nuevo Federalismo. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, Ben Ross. 2004. Business Politics and the State in 20th Century Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Hierarchical Capitalism in Latin America: Business, Labor, and the Challenges of Equitable Development. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Secretaría de Desarrollo Económico de Querétaro. 1986. Anuario Económico.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shadlen, Kenneth. 2004. Democratization Without Representation: The Politics of Small Industry in Mexico. State College: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shafer, Robert Jones. 1973. Mexican Business Organizations: History and Analysis. Syracuse: Syracuse University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Villavicencio, Josué. 2013. Industria y empresarios en Puebla 1940–1970: Una aproximación a la historia económica regional. Puebla: Benemérita Universidad Autónoma de Puebla.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kahn, T. (2019). Origins and Consequences of Divergent Private Sector Organization in Puebla and Querétaro. In: Government-Business Relations and Regional Development in Post-Reform Mexico. Latin American Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-92351-2_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics