Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Latin American Political Economy ((LAPE))

  • 171 Accesses

Abstract

The wave of economic and political transitions across the developing world in the 1980s and 1990s led to divergent outcomes within countries. This chapter reviews the literature on subnational variation in response to national-level economic and political reform and argues that existing research has not fully applied the lens of government-business relations to analyzing economic outcomes at the subnational level. While differences in the pattern of interactions between local authorities and firms are clearly relevant to subnational economic performance, the mechanisms are likely to differ from those at the national level. To underscore this point, this chapter proposes a set of analytical guidelines for understanding subnational government-business relations. The chapter then introduces the book’s argument, which shows how the decisions of large firms shaped the organization of the local private sector in Puebla and Querétaro, leading to different patterns of government-business relations (sometimes also including labor) and, consequently, economic divergence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    An exception is Ibarra del Cueto’s work on subnational development regimes in Mexican states (2017). While Snyder (2001) takes a political economy approach to studying Mexican states, he focuses on the more narrow outcome of re-regulation of the coffee sector rather than economic performance.

  2. 2.

    The literature on subnational authoritarianism includes O’Donnell 1993; Cornelius et al. 1999; Gibson 2005; Behrend 2011; and Giraudy 2015, although some authors dispute the contention that subnational authoritarians can construct distinct local political “regimes,” preferring to speak of “illiberal practices” (see Behrend and Whitehead 2016).

  3. 3.

    Giraudy (2015) shows how subnational authoritarians can, under certain circumstances, maintain their position via political alliances with national democratic leaders, while Gervasoni (2010) emphasizes the importance of fiscal transfers from the center in sustaining undemocratic rentier regimes at the subnational level.

  4. 4.

    See Hecock 2006; Faguet 2009; Diaz-Cayeros et al. 2014; and Kale 2014 for studies of how different political institutions lead to variation in public goods provision across subnational jurisdictions.

  5. 5.

    Such opposition is generally associated with investment in the extractive industries.

  6. 6.

    The basis for this shift is the New Economic Geography, pioneered by Helpman and Krugman (1987), which emphasizes how factors such as increasing returns and imperfect competition can generate imbalanced growth across regions.

  7. 7.

    As discussed in Chapter 1, political institutions are defined broadly to encompass informal practices governing relations among political actors and the organizations through which they act collectively, in addition to formal rules.

  8. 8.

    This view of institutions is associated with the New Institutionalist Economics pioneered by North (1981, 1990). See Williamson (1990) for an articulation of the Washington Consensus, which provided the framework for market reforms in many developing countries during the 1990s.

  9. 9.

    Evans (1995) conceived of these more expansive state functions as “husbandry” and “midwife.” The term “reciprocal control mechanism” is from Amsden (2001) and refers to making subsides and other government support conditional on firms’ meeting performance requirements such as exporting or investing in new technology.

  10. 10.

    The first debate pits what Hausmann et al. (2008) and Sabel (2009) call industrial policy “in the large” versus industrial policy “in the small.” Schneider (2015) distinguishes between “active industrial policy” (changing firm behavior) and “passive industrial policy” (changing government behavior).

  11. 11.

    Hausmann et al., for example, equate “good” industrial policy with “those institutional arrangements and practices that organize this [public-private] collaboration effectively” (2008, 4). This statement finds support in a growing number of studies that identify collaboration between government and business as critical for successful industrial policy, broadly interpreted. See Fernández-Arias et al. (2016), Schneider (2015), Crespi et al. (2014), and Sabel (2012) for recent examples focused on Latin American experiences.

  12. 12.

    Scholars have used a range of terms to describe these functions, such as “consultation” and “credible commitments” (Doner 2009) and “reciprocity” (Amsden 1989; Maxfield and Schneider 1997). Collaboration can also build long-term trust and credibility between government and business and promote norms of compromise (Amsden 1989; Maxfield and Schneider 1997).

  13. 13.

    For example, Krueger (1974) warned that interaction between bureaucrats and firms would inevitably result in rent-seeking.

  14. 14.

    Business associations are not the only lens through which business can be examined. However, business associations are relevant to any analysis of government-business relations, even if they are not the main conduit for firms to engage with officials (see Maxfield and Schneider 1997). In the latter case, the question becomes why did firms opt out of associations.

  15. 15.

    Encompassing business associations generally have a mandate to represent firms across the economy and are therefore “economy wide,” although in practice encompassingness is an empirical question. Sector and even regional associations can function like encompassing associations when their constituencies are sufficiently broad (see Durand and Silva 1998).

  16. 16.

    These “market-supporting activities” are a crucial function of developmental business associations according to Doner and Schneider (2000), although they have been successfully performed by sector-specific associations as well (see fn 15).

  17. 17.

    In fact, Olson (1982) predicted that encompassing associations would be rare and short-lived.

  18. 18.

    Access to decision makers thus constitutes a valuable selective benefit that helps overcome free-riding.

  19. 19.

    Perspectives on MNC participation in collective action are mixed. MNCs may not participate actively in business associations for fear of encroaching on politically sensitive territory or because high turnover among expatriate managers prevents sustained engagement (Schneider 2004), although examples of MNCs playing an active role in public-private councils certainly exist (see Palacios 2008; Moran 2015).

  20. 20.

    Moran (2015), for example, suggests foreign investors care most about the availability of infrastructure and skilled human capital to facilitate integration of local operations into global supply chains and they are disposed to work with governments to create these conditions. On the other hand, Schneider (2014) shows that the focus of large domestic business groups in Latin America on natural resources and heavily regulated utilities tends to undermine such pro-development preferences. Taken together, these findings imply the participation of MNCs in business associations and government-business collaboration is all the more important in the region.

  21. 21.

    Coordination is the defining feature of the “coordinated market economies” of Northern Europe (see Hall and Soskice 2001). While the VoC literature initially focused on advanced industrial economies, Schneider (2014) examines Latin America through the VoC lens, concluding capitalism in the region is defined by hierarchical relations among economic actors, which helps account for the region’s low levels of productivity, skills, and innovation.

  22. 22.

    In the developmental state and business politics literatures, organized labor tends to play a secondary role at best, as the authoritarian contexts in which most of these studies are situated generally limited labor’s scope for independent action.

  23. 23.

    “Standard operating procedures” is Hall’s (1986) phrase to describe ingrained practices not necessarily codified as formal rules. See Helmke and Levitsky (2006) on informal institutions.

  24. 24.

    The relationship between government and business at the local level also has potentially important consequences beyond the economic realm, as recent work on violence in Latin American cities shows (Conger 2014; Moncada 2016).

  25. 25.

    See Schneider (2015) for some discussion of these issues. There are several well-studied examples of government-business collaboration at the subnational level, but research on these cases has generally said little about the underlying local political dynamics (see Palacios 2008; Sabel 2012). McDermott (2007) emphasizes the importance of participatory institutions in successful policies to upgrade in the wine sector in Argentine provinces.

  26. 26.

    As Doner and Schneider (2016) suggest, the literature has only begun to grapple with the implications for government-business relations of current political dynamics in most middle-income countries.

  27. 27.

    See Sinha (2005) on the case of Indian states and Montero (2002) on subnational industrial strategies in Brazil and Spain. McDermott (2007), Palacios (2008), and Devlin and Moguillansky (2011) also discuss cases of successful government-business alliances at the regional level.

  28. 28.

    This idea mirrors Behrend and Whitehead’s (2016) admonition that subnational variation in levels of democracy is more likely to be a question of “practices” rather than formal institutions given the embeddedness of subnational units in a common institutional framework.

  29. 29.

    This is not to imply that factors such as strong leadership and technical capabilities in subnational bureaucracies do not matter. The point is a relative one. Compared to the national level, the relative influence of formal state institutions versus characteristics of the private sector in shaping subnational government-business relations will be more weighted towards the latter.

  30. 30.

    Hall and Soskice (2001) make a similar point, suggesting that important subnational differences may exist within a given variety of capitalism due to the influence of large firms in regional economies.

  31. 31.

    Although large firms, and especially multinationals, face strong incentives to pursue individual strategies instead of collective action, this result is not inevitable and may depend on factors such as industry concentration (see Schneider 2004). The case studies in this book also illustrate the importance of economic concentration in shaping firms’ incentives to engage in collective action.

  32. 32.

    This is a main feature of the neo-corporatist literature on state-labor relations. See Schmitter 1985.

  33. 33.

    It is important to clarify that this statement refers to the position of industrial unions. Public sector unions, such as teachers’ unions, and unions in sectors that continued to be protected from economic competition remained strong. See Murillo (2001) on the evolution of unions in Latin America.

  34. 34.

    See Leftwich (2007) for a review.

  35. 35.

    The patterns of interaction between government and business are not shaped by formal laws or regulations but rather by “socially shared rules” whose formulation and enforcement occurs outside of officially sanctioned channels (Helmke and Levitsky 2006, 5).

  36. 36.

    Coparmex is Mexico’s National Employers’ Association, a voluntary, independent association of mostly small and medium-sized firms. Canacintra, the National Chamber of Manufacturing Industries, was the official chamber of manufacturing firms under Mexico’s state corporatist system. Both organizations maintained local affiliates in states and cities throughout Mexico, and they developed very different profiles in Puebla and Querétaro. See Chapter 3 for a discussion of the evolution of organized business in Mexico.

  37. 37.

    In this way, business chambers in Querétaro acquired the characteristics associated with encompassing associations in the academic literature.

  38. 38.

    As detailed throughout the book, the firm did indeed engage directly with the highest political authorities in the state, who were generally quick to respond to the firm’s preferences. At the same time, other major MNCs and national manufacturing firms in Puebla—such as Hylsa, Grupo Bimbo, Pelican, Chiclets Adams, and a host of MNC auto parts producers—likewise did not actively participate in business associations.

  39. 39.

    Interview, 26 January 2016. See Chapter 3 for more discussion of the firm’s attitude towards local business associations.

  40. 40.

    As Falleti (2010) shows, the underlying motivation for decentralizing policy authority to state governments was to forestall demands for more fundamental political change. In a similar vein, other authors have argued that national officials hoped decentralization would ease pressure on federal budgets, deflect blame for flagging services onto local governments, and reduce the power of public sector unions, especially in the case of education (see Beer 2004 for a review of these arguments).

  41. 41.

    While the initiation of market reforms in 1985 helped win back the support of elite business associations, representatives of smaller firms producing for the domestic market continued to criticize the government over the fast pace of trade liberalization and the recurrent crises that beset the Mexican economy in the 1980s and 1990s (Shadlen 2004; Schneider 2004). See Chapter 3 for more discussion of the political activities of organized business during this period.

  42. 42.

    As Snyder (1999, 2001) illustrates, PRI governors had distinct ideological and policy preferences, which shaped their responses to national reforms. However, they were also constrained in their choices by factors such as economic structure and the presence of viable political allies for their policy projects.

  43. 43.

    Twelve interviews with individuals who participated directly in the Tripartite Commission form the basis for the discussion of this institution and its role in Querétaro’s development.

  44. 44.

    Loyola himself was a businessman who had been the president of Coparmex, a leading business association, before entering politics.

  45. 45.

    The PAN candidate, Ricardo Villa Escalera, was a textile businessman with close links to the local business leadership.

  46. 46.

    This remains the case even though both San Luis Potosí and Zacatecas have experienced faster than average growth for Mexican states over the past decade.

  47. 47.

    The precise relationship between democracy and development remains a matter of debate, however. See Acemoglu et al. 2014.

  48. 48.

    In addition to these local factors, events such as the 1995 economic crisis and an electoral reform passed the following year also contributed to the PRI’s defeat in Querétaro in 1997 (see Chapter 8).

  49. 49.

    This figure includes both untied transfers, called participaciones, and transfers earmarked for particular policy areas that fall under state government responsibility (aportaciones). The source for this data is the Centro de Estudios de las Finanzas Públicas of the Cámara de Diputados (2017).

  50. 50.

    Interviews with business owners in Puebla, 13 November 2015 and 25 January 2015; Interview with Ignacio Loyola Vera, 22 April 2016.

  51. 51.

    The comparison between the 1990s and 2000s suggests that Querétaro did not enjoy especially favorable treatment during the years when both the state governorship and presidency were occupied by the PAN (2000–2009). In fact, Giraudy (2015) and Rebolledo (2012) report that Puebla’s PRI-led governments managed to maintain close alliances with PAN presidents during this period.

  52. 52.

    In the first half of the 1990s, for example, federal transfers made up just over half of the states’ income on average (see Ibarra Salazar et al. 1999).

  53. 53.

    Querétaro ranked 21, while Puebla ranked 30 out of 32 federal entities. Calculations are based on data from Secretaría de Hacienda y Crédito Pública, Estadísticas Oportunas de Finanzas Públicas.

  54. 54.

    Puebla received an average of 1,310 pesos/capita of federal public investment during these years, compared with 3,110 for Querétaro. These calculations are based on data from federal Informe de Gobierno statistical annexes for various years and are based on 2008 prices.

References

  • Acemoglu, Daron, and Melissa Dell. 2010. “Productivity Differences Between and Within Countries”. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 169–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, Daron, Suresh Naidu, Pascual Restrepo, and James A. Robinson. 2014. “Democracy Does Cause Growth”, NBER Working Paper No. 20004. Washington, DC: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amengual, Matthew. 2016. Politicized Enforcement in Argentina: Labor and Environmental Regulation. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Amsden, Alice. 1989. Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2001. The Rise of “The Rest”: Challenges to the West From Late-Industrializing Economies. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Beer, Caroline C. 2004. “Electoral Competition and Fiscal Decentralization in Mexico”. In Decentralization and Democracy in Latin America, ed. Alfred Montero and David Samuels. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrend, Jacqueline. 2011. “The Unevenness of Democracy at the Subnational Level: Provincial Closed Games in Argentina”. Latin American Research Review 46 (1): 150–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrend, Jacqueline, and Matías Bianchi. 2017. “Estructura económica y política subnacional en Argentina”. Caderno CRH 30 (80): 217–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrend, Jacqueline, and Laurence Whitehead, eds. 2016. Illiberal Practices: Territorial Variance Within Large Federal Democracies. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bensusán, Graciela, and Kevin J. Middlebrook. 2010. “Organized Labor and Politics in Mexico”. In The Oxford Handbook of Mexican Politics, ed. Roderic Camp. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breinlich, Holger, Ottaviano Gianmarco, and Jonathan Temple. 2013. “Regional Growth and Regional Decline”, CEP Discussion Papers dp1232. London: Center for Economic Performance, London School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Ling. 2014. “Varieties of Global Capital and the Paradox of Local Upgrading in China”. Politics and Society 42 (2): 223–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conger, Lucy. 2014. “The Private Sector and Public Security: The Cases of Ciudad Juárez and Monterrey”, Working Paper Series on Civic Engagement and Public Security in Mexico. Washington, DC: The Wilson Center Mexico Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornelius, Wayne A., Todd Eisenstadt, and Jane Hindley, eds. 1999. Subnational Politics and Democratization in Mexico. La Jolla: Center for US-Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespi, Gustavo, Eduardo Fernández-Arias, and Ernesto Stein. 2014. Rethinking Productive Development: Sound Policies and Institutions for Economic Transformation. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Devlin, Robert, and Graciela Moguillansky. 2011. Breeding Latin American Tigers: Operational Principles for Rehabilitating Industrial Policies. Santiago: UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Diaz-Cayeros, Alberto. 1997. Political Responses to Regional Inequality, Taxation, and Distribution in Mexico. Ph.D. Thesis, Department of Political Science, Duke University. Raleigh, NC.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. Federalism, Fiscal Authority, and Centralization in Latin America, Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diaz-Cayeros, Alberto, Beatriz Magaloni, and Alexander Ruiz-Euler. 2014. “Traditional Governance, Citizen Engagement, and Local Public Goods: Evidence from Mexico”. World Development 53: 80–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doner, Richard F. 2009. The Politics of Uneven Development: Thailand’s Economic Growth in Comparative Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Doner, Richard F., and Ben Ross Schneider. 2000. “Business Associations and Economic Development: Why Some Associations Contribute More Than Others”. Business and Politics 2 (3): 261–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016. “The Middle-Income Trap: More Politics than Economics”. World Politics 68 (4): 608–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doner, Richard F., Bryan K. Ritchie, and Dan Slater. 2005. “Systemic Vulnerability and the Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast Asia in Comparative Perspective”. International Organization 59 (2): 327–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durand, Francisco, and Eduardo Silva. 1998. Organized Business, Economic Change, and Democracy in Latin America. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durazo Herrmann, Julián. 2016. “Social Heterogeneity, Political Mediation, and Subnational Illiberalism: Oaxaca and Puebla, Mexico”. In Illiberal Practices: Territorial Variance Within Large Federal Democracies, ed. Jacqueline Behrend and Laurence Whitehead. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, Kent. 2010. “Subnational Economic Nationalism? The Contradictory Effects of Decentralization in Peru”. Third World Quarterly 31 (7): 1205–1222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. “Policy Regime Juxtaposition in Latin America”. Colombia Internacional 90: 37–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, Peter. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faguet, Jean-Paul. 2009. “Governance from Below in Bolivia: A Theory of Local Government with Two Empirical Tests”. Latin American Politics and Society 51 (4): 29–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falleti, Tulia. 2010. Decentralization and Subnational Politics in Latin America. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández-Arias, Eduardo, Charles Sabel, Ernesto Stein, and Alberto Trejos, eds. 2016. Two to Tango: Public-Private Collaboration for Productive Development Policies. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervasoni, Carlos. 2010. “A Rentier Theory of Subnational Regimes: Fiscal Federalism, Democracy, and Authoritarianism in the Argentine Provinces”. World Politics 62 (2): 302–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, Edward L. 2005. “Boundary Control: Subnational Authoritarianism in Democratic Countries”. World Politics 58 (1): 101–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giraudy, Agustina. 2015. Democrats and Autocrats. Pathways of Subnational Undemocratic Regime Continuity Within Democratic Countries. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Giraudy, Agustina, Eduardo Moncada, and Richard Snyder, eds. 2019, Forthcoming. Inside Countries: Subnational Research in Comparative Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwald, Bruce, and Joseph Stiglitz. 2014. “Industrial Policies, the Creation of a Learning Society, and Economic Development”. In The Industrial Policy Revolution I: The Role of Government Beyond Ideology, ed. Joseph Stiglitz, Justin Lin, and Ebrahim Patel. Houndmills/New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Peter A. 1986. Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, Ricardo, and Dani Rodrik. 2002. “Economic Development as Self-Discovery”, NBER Working Paper No. 8952. Washington, DC: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, Ricardo, Dani Rodrik, and Charles Sabel. 2008. “Reconfiguring Industrial Policy: A Framework with an Application to South Africa”, Center for International Development Working Paper 168. Cambridge, MA: Center for International Development, Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hecock, R. Douglas. 2006. “Electoral Competition, Globalization, and Subnational Education Spending in Mexico, 1999–2004”. American Journal of Political Science 50 (4): 950–961.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helmke, Gretchen, and Steven Levitsky, eds. 2006. Informal Institutions and Democracy: Lessons from Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, Elhanan, and Paul Krugman. 1987. Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the International Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hernández Rodríguez, Rogelio. 2008. El Centro dividido: La nueva autonomía de los gobernadores. Mexico City: El Colegio de México.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera, Veronica. 2014. “Does Commercialization Undermine the Benefits of Decentralization for Local Services Provision? Evidence from Mexico’s Urban Water and Sanitation Sector”. World Development 56: 16–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibarra del Cueto, Juan Fernando. 2017. “The Political Economy of Divergence: Subnational Development Regimes in Mexico”, Working Paper. Prepared for the Southwest Workshop on Mixed Methods Research University of California, Riverside October 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibarra Salazar, Jorge, Alfredo Sandoval, and Lida Sotres Cervantes. 1999. “México: ingresos estatales y dependencia de las participaciones federales”. Comercio Exterior. May 1999: 438–444.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kale, Sunila. 2014. Electrifying India: Regional Political Economies of Development. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur, Ravi, and Anthony Venables, eds. 2005. Spatial Inequality and Development. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohli, Atul. 2004. State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, Anne. 1974. “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society”. American Economic Review 64 (3): 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuczynski, Pedro-Pablo, and John Williamson. 2003. After the Washington Consensus: Restarting Growth and Reform in Latin America. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lankina, Tomila V., and Lullit Getachew. 2006. “A Geographic Incremental Theory of Democratization: Territory, Aid, and Democracy in Postcommunist Regions”. World Politics 58 (4): 536–582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leftwich, Adrian. 2007. “The Political Approach to Institutional Formation, Maintenance and Change: A Literature Review Essay”. Discussion Paper Series No. 14. IPPG.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxfield, Sylvia, and Ben Ross Schneider. 1997. Business and the State in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McDermott, Gerald A. 2007. “The Politics of Institutional Renovation and Economic Upgrading: Recombining the Vines That Bind in Argentina”. Politics and Society 35 (1): 103–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mizrahi, Yemile. 2003. From Martyrdom to Power: The Partido Acción Nacional in Mexico. South Bend: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moncada, Eduardo. 2016. Cities, Business, and the Politics of Urban Violence in Latin America. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Montero, Alfred P. 2002. Shifting States in Global Markets: Subnational Industrial Policy in Contemporary Brazil and Spain. State College: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montero, Alfred P., and David Samuels. 2004. Decentralization and Democracy in Latin America. South Bend: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morales Garza, Marta Gloria. 2001. “Subversión silenciosa: el papel de los municipios en la derrota priísta en Querétaro”. In Elecciones y partidos políticos en México, 1997, ed. Manuel Larrosa Haro. Mexico City: Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran, Theodore. 2015. “The Role of Industrial Policy as a Development Tool: New Evidence from the Globalization of Trade-and-Investment”, CGD Policy Paper 071. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murillo, Victoria. 2001. Labor Unions, Partisan Coalitions, and Market Reforms in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, Douglass. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell, Guillermo. 1993. “On the State, Democratization and Some Conceptual Problems: A Latin American View with Glances at Some Postcommunist Countries”. World Development 21 (8): 1355–1369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palacios Lara, Juan José. 2008. “Alianzas públicos-privadas y escalamiento industrial: el case del complejo de alta tecnología de Jalisco, México”. Mexico City: CEPAL, Unidad de Comercio Internacional e Industria.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rebolledo Márquez, Juan. 2012. Voting with the Enemy: A Theory of Democratic Support for Subnational Authoritarians. Ph.D. Thesis, Yale University, New Haven, CT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rettberg, Angelika. 2005. “Business Versus Business? Grupos and Organized Business in Colombia”. Latin American Politics and Society 47 (1): 31–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, Charles. 2009. What Industrial Policy Is Becoming: Taiwan, Ireland and Finland as Guides to the Future of Industrial Policy. New York: Colombia Law School.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012. “Self-Discovery as a Coordination Problem”. In Export Pioneers in Latin America, ed. Charles Sabel, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare, Ernesto H. Stein, Ricardo Hausmann, and Eduardo Fernández-Arias. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitter, Philippe. 1985. “Neo-corporatism and the State”. In The Political Economy of Corporatism, ed. Grant Wyn. London: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, Ben Ross. 2004. Business Politics and the State in 20th Century Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Hierarchical Capitalism in Latin America: Business, Labor, and the Challenges of Equitable Development. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015. Designing Industrial Policy in Latin America: Business-State Relations and the New Developmentalism. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shadlen, Kenneth. 2004. Democratization Without Representation: The Politics of Small Industry in Mexico. State College: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinha, Aseema. 2005. The Regional Roots of Developmental Politics in India: A Divided Leviathan. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, Richard. 1999. “After the State Withdraws: Neoliberalism and Subnational Authoritarian Regimes in Mexico”. In Subnational Politics and Democratization in Mexico, ed. Wayne A. Cornelius, Todd A. Eisenstadt, and Jane Hindley. La Jolla: The Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, University of California San Diego.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2001. Politics After Neoliberalism: Reregulation in Mexico. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wade, Robert. 2003. “What Strategies Are Viable for Developing Countries Today? The World Trade Organization and the Shrinking of ‘Development Space’”. The Review of International Political Economy 10 (4): 621–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, Peter M., and Victoria E. Rodríguez. 1999. New Federalism and State Government in Mexico: Bringing the States Back In, U.S.-Mexican Policy Report No. 9. Austin: University of Texas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, John. 1990. The Progress of Policy Reform in Latin America. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kahn, T. (2019). Governing Subnational Economies. In: Government-Business Relations and Regional Development in Post-Reform Mexico. Latin American Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-92351-2_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics