Skip to main content

Pathogen Information Is the Basic Problem for Economic Incentives

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1096 Accesses

Part of the book series: Food Microbiology and Food Safety ((PRACT))

Abstract

For the private marketplace to operate efficiently, buyers and sellers require information on products being bought or sold. The information problem for food safety is that pathogens in the food items for sale are not visible to the naked eye. Buyers in the food supply chain, from the farm to the restaurant or supermarket, do not have the “facts” of the current pathogen load of the product. Sellers may also be ignorant, unless they have exerted effort via pathogen testing of their inputs, control of their production/processing processes, and/or sampling and testing their finished food products. The inability to link 999/1,000 cases of US foodborne illness to the causative pathogen, food, and company causes weak incentives for companies to produce safe food. However, public or private actions can create pathogen data in the food supply chain and this data can be used to reward or punish companies for their food safety performance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   149.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Abbreviations

CDC:

Centers for Disease Control and Prevention

CIDT:

Culture-independent diagnostic tests

DNA:

Deoxyribonucleic acid

ERS:

Economic Research Service/USDA

FDA:

Food and Drug Administration

FSIS:

Food Safety and Inspection Service/USDA

FWW:

Food and Water Watch

HACCP:

Hazard Analysis Critical Control Points

IOM:

Institute of Medicine/NAS

LTHO:

Long term health outcome

MRC:

Mechanically separated chicken

MRSA:

Methicillin resistant Staphylococcus aureus

NAS:

National Academy of Sciences

NRC:

National Research Council/NAS

NSLP:

National School Lunch Program

USDA:

United States Department of Agriculture

UTI:

Urinary tract infection

WGS:

Whole-genome sequencing

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tanya Roberts .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: A Model of Optimal Deterrence

Appendix: A Model of Optimal Deterrence

The effect of information problems on industry incentives can be illustrated using a simple deterrence model. In the case of foodborne illness, optimal deterrence for a risk neutral business is achieved when the expected penalty for exposing people to an unknown/unnegotiated risk equals the cost of illnesses incurred as a result of the risk, as demonstrated in Eq. (1):

$$ {P}_{\mathrm{i}}\times {\mathrm{Penalty}}_{\mathrm{i}}={U}_{\mathrm{i}}\times {\mathrm{ConsumerCost}}_{\mathrm{i}} $$
(1)

where P i is the probability a firm producing illness-causing food is caught, Penaltyi is the penalty the firm faces if caught, U i is the unnegotiated level of risk that consumers face (number of excess illnesses), and ConsumerCosti is the average economic loss experienced by consumers (including quality of life losses) for each illness.

The penalty for exposing consumers to unnegotiated risk is composed primarily of two parts, litigation costs and reputation costs. In many cases, reputation cost, being primarily an information-based sanction, is the greater of the two. Many Chipotle customers who read that people were made sick from the chain’s food, for example, reassessed their risk perceptions associated with Chipotle and, as a result, chose to dine elsewhere. The loss of profits associated with this behavior is a significant penalty.

It is instructive to look at a number of hypotheticals to illustrate the issues involved in deterrence of risky industry food safety behavior. First, if all risks are anticipated and consumers can choose risk levels in a market (U i = 0), no penalties will be necessary since the market will incorporate the cost of risk into prices paid by consumers. As Akerlof’s lemons model demonstrates, however, this is not the case. Consumers typically do not have the ability to choose risk levels due to information problems. This is not to say that consumers are completely powerless in the market. Consumers can buy products such as pasteurized eggs for a premium and avoid risky foods (oysters out of season, pink burgers, etc.). The actual value of U i is unclear. Next, if the penalty (Penaltyi) to firm i is set to be equal to the cost to consumers (ConsumerCosti) and the probability a firm providing unanticipated risky food is penalized is 100%, optimal deterrence will occur. This is consistent with litigation that fully compensates for consumer losses. Given that 99.9% of illnesses are not linked to a specific product, this is not a realistic scenario. It is also unclear what the actual value of P i is because some portion of these unlinked illnesses are caused by cross contamination at home. A third possibility for optimal deterrence is that the penalties that are imposed in a given instance exceed consumer costs by an amount sufficient to deter unnegotiated risk, as shown in Eq. (2):

$$ {\mathrm{Penalty}}_{\mathrm{i}}\ge \left({U}_{\mathrm{i}}\times {\mathrm{ConsumerCost}}_{\mathrm{i}}\right)/{P}_{\mathrm{i}}. $$
(2)

Hypothetically, if 90% of risk is unnegotiated (U i = 0.9) and 99% of illnesses due to the food firm are not discovered (P i = 0.01), the penalty needed to assure optimal deterrence would be 90 × ConsumerCosti. This is not as implausible as it may seem. If company A can allow a contaminated lot to slip through and 100 people are made ill as a result (at an average cost of $5000 each), the company would only have to expect to be penalized $45 million to induce optimal food safety behavior. Though litigation alone is unlikely to reach this level of penalty, reputation costs (especially for large companies) may easily reach this number in some cases. Though high-profile cases such as the Chipotle and PCA may have reached these thresholds, it is unlikely that they have been met in the many lower-profile outbreaks that garner less media attention. Furthermore, many outbreaks occur as a result of bad practices by smaller firms, which have limited assets, exposing them to maximum penalties that are suboptimal to deter risky behavior (the firms are judgment proof). Research is needed to determine the level of deterrence in industry, as a whole.

Abbreviations used in this chapter.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Roberts, T., Scharff, R.L. (2018). Pathogen Information Is the Basic Problem for Economic Incentives. In: Roberts, T. (eds) Food Safety Economics. Food Microbiology and Food Safety(). Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-92138-9_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics