Skip to main content

The German Historical School of Economics and the Foundations and Development of the Austrian School of Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Hayek: A Collaborative Biography

Part of the book series: Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics ((AIEE))

Abstract

Despite its status as the world’s leading school of economics during the second half of the nineteenth century, it is now generally accepted that within the contemporary mainstream, the GHSE has the ‘worst reputation’ of all the research programmes in the history of economic thought. This view has been largely shaped by Austrian School theorists. The Austrian School of Economics was originally founded on the basis of Carl Menger’s critiques of the supposed weaknesses and flaws of the German Historical School of Economics: this chapter examines how criticisms of the fundamental principles of the—as expressed by ASE theorists—influenced the formation and development of the ASE’s own fundamental principles. In addition to disputes over methodological collectivism or methodological individualism, the deductive versus the inductive method, ethical values and state intervention and the nature of ‘knowledge,’ there were emotional issues: Menger—who was truly upset by the severe criticisms directed against him and his book by GHSE theorists and their labelling of him as an ‘Austrian’ economist—went from having a high opinion of the GHSE to having a low opinion of its theorists.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Hayek’s interest in economics began with Menger’s Principles of Economics—he regularly referred to Menger’s writings in his own works.

  2. 2.

    Hayek was not the only prominent scholar to hold a negative view of the GHSE. For example, in ‘Economic History and Economics,’ Robert M. Solow (1985) stated: ‘After all, no one would remember the old German Historical School if it were not for the famous Methodenstreit. Actually, no one remembers them anyway.’ Mises was also highly critical of the GHSE—condemning them ‘in McCarthyist tones—principally for its alleged socialism’ (Hodgson 2001, 91).

  3. 3.

    The GHSE was also critical of neo-classical economics and Marxian economics, which was still an emerging economic theory at the end of the nineteenth century.

  4. 4.

    Von Justi was accepted as one of the most important theorists of cameralism in the eighteenth century (Spicer 1998, 150; Wakefield 2009, 3). He argued that a ‘republic or state is a unification of a multitude of people under a supreme power, for the ultimate purpose of their happiness’ (Spicer 1998, 151).

  5. 5.

    Cameralism originated from the term Kammer, which refers to ‘a physical space, a chamber where fiscal officials met to discuss the most secret affairs of the prince’ in the German principalities. ‘By the seventeenth century most German territories. Large and small, had developed Kammer to manage the intimate affairs of princes, dukes, kings, and emperors. By the second half of the seventeenth century, members of the Kammer began to be recognized as a distinct group. People start calling them cameralists.’ Academic cameralists argued that it was not necessary ‘to seek out riches in distant lands, because the key to wealth was right at home, in local fields, forests, mines and manufactories.’ Cameralism was ‘intimately and ineluctably tied to the sciences of nature’ (Wakefield 2005, 319; 2009, 17, 20).

  6. 6.

    Politzei involves ‘a form of economic management’ and a ‘good organization of civil life’ (Tribe 1998, 63, 75).

  7. 7.

    According to Wakefield (2005, 314), however, there is no consensus that cameralism was actually the German mercantilism; it is also sometimes viewed as ‘a subset of German mercantilism.’

  8. 8.

    Schmoller argued that Roscher was ‘the true founder of the historical school of German economics’ (Caldwell 2004, 51).

  9. 9.

    List’s works have also been associated with historical economics (Tribe 2002, 1), which led him to him being regarded as among ‘the forerunners of the Historical School’ (Senn 2005, 186). However, he was neither an advocate of the historical tradition nor did he support the inductive approach. In reality, List’s views pertaining to the role of the state were primarily influenced by his personal observations while living in the United States between 1825 and 1832 as opposed to the situation that prevailed in Germany during this time. Tribe (2002, 7; 2007) confirms this notion, explaining that List’s criticisms of classical economics, including his views on Adam Smith, were not really related to the ‘German intellectual tradition’ or the ideas of German economists of the early nineteenth century; instead, he suggests that List’s criticisms appeared to be largely based on American economic debates. Hildebrand, an important GHSE promoter, was also critical of List’s views, arguing that his explanation of the ‘stages of economic development’ was primarily influenced by British history. This chapter does not discuss List’s contributions to the development of the discipline of economics because he was not a true theorist of the methodologies and ideals of the GHSE.

  10. 10.

    The fact that that Menger’s Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre was not translated into English for almost 80 years has been called ‘a mystery’ (Dingwall and Hoselitz 2007, 38).

  11. 11.

    ‘The circle of thinkers around Ludwig von Mises who did most to establish the characteristic methods and insights of the Austrian School’ (Grassl and Smith 1986, viii).

  12. 12.

    This chapter does not discuss the details of the important individual contributions that each of these theorists made to the development of the ASE.

  13. 13.

    Menger’s (2007 [1871]) Principles of Economics is ‘not a work in empirical science at all but entirely a work of philosophy’ (Haller 2004, 7).

  14. 14.

    Böhm-Bawerk, Wieser, Weber, E.R.A. Seligman, Richard T. Ely, and John Bates Clark were among Menger’s well-known students at University of Heidelberg (Bateman and Papadopoulos 2011, 23; Tribe 2002, 8).

  15. 15.

    ‘Marginal utility…states that under certain conditions of exchange (e.g. both parties know their best interests) the price of a product varies in direct proportion to need’ (Beiser 2011, 523). Menger, Jevons, and Walras are known as the ‘founders of the marginal revolution.’ However, of these three theorists, Menger has been accepted as ‘the least marginalist’—this relates to his lack of ‘adequate mathematical training to handle marginalism properly’ (Caldwell 2004, 30, 31). ‘The German economist viewed use-value as a result of people’s individual preferences for the satisfaction of human desires. This notion of use-value as a subjective conception reaches to the crux of neoclassical economics and Menger’s theory’ (Bateman and Papadopoulos 2011, 31).

  16. 16.

    The older German Historical School was ‘associated with the writing of Wilhelm Roscher, Knies and Bruno Hildebrand,’ whereas the Younger School was primarily associated with Schmoller (Tribe 2002, 1).

  17. 17.

    Schmoller’s methodological views played a major role in the development of Alfred Marshall’s (1842–1924) methodology in economics. Marshall, who is accepted as the founder of the neoclassical school of economics, was able to use his advanced knowledge in mathematics to formalise economics in his well-known 1890 Principles of Economics, which became the leading textbook. Marshall was ‘fluent in German’ and, like many international academics and students of his time, ‘he went to Germany to study under the tutelage of members of the historical school.’ In fact, he was in ‘contact with several German economists, including Wilhelm Roscher’ (Hodgson 2001, 97). Contrary to the negative, disrespectful and derogative comments that Hayek and Mises directed at the GHSE, Marshall’s work conveyed a positive view of the GHSE. In the 1890s, Marshall praised the achievements of the GHSE, stating that ‘on the whole the most important economic work that has been done on the Continent in recent times is that of Germany’ (Senn 1989, 257).

  18. 18.

    Alter (1990, 328) claimed that methodological individualism was related to the ‘Austrian interpretation of Leibniz’s Monadology.’ In other words, Austrians had ‘an atomistic reinterpretation of the Leibnizian monad,’ which ‘made the integration of romantic-historicist and rationalist elements of thought possible’ in their methodological individualism.

  19. 19.

    There are different versions of methodological individualism within the disciplines of philosophy and economics. For example, the ASE and Classical economics have different version of the methodological individualism.

  20. 20.

    ‘Hufeland’s 1807 Neue Grundlegung der Staatswirthschaftskunst is one of the first attempts to link a theory of subjective evaluations and methodological individualism’ (Milford 1995, 29).

  21. 21.

    Menger did not use the term ‘methodological individualism’ in his writings.

  22. 22.

    Roscher was critical of deductive methods of classical economics.

  23. 23.

    ‘In his view, it is due to this epistemic situation that laws of historical development are the only kind of social knowledge that is strictly universal and empirical and he concludes that the social sciences are not sciences sui generis but the theory of history, and thus belong to history. Among the positive sciences one may distinguish between science and history only’ (Milford 1995, 31).

  24. 24.

    Roscher (1972 [1887], 87) defined political economy as ‘the science which has to do with the laws of the development of the economy of a nation, or with its economic national life.’

  25. 25.

    According to the GHSE, historical change occurred in ‘stages from village economy to city economy to territorial economy to national economy.’ These dissimilar manners of organizing society are strongly related to the different types of relationships that exist between individuals, such as ‘kinship,’ ‘sympathy,’ ‘love,’ law, contract, etc. This form of ‘stage theory was concerned with the evolution of institutions brought about by the interactions between ethics and economy, between spiritual-social and natural-technical factors’ (Shionoya 2000, 28).

  26. 26.

    Despite their defence of social justice, they did not necessarily support socialism. According to the GHSE, ‘socialism’ was not the solution for the problems that prevailed in Germany at that time; in fact, they regarded it as a ‘false remedy’ (Caldwell 2004, 55). They viewed ‘socialism as the factual and logical result of capitalism.’ They also accepted socialism as ‘the denial of individual freedom and private property’ (Kobayasi 2000, 65).

  27. 27.

    Schmoller was very optimistic when it came to the achievement of distributive justice, as he believed that the future would bring improvements in terms of achieving distributive justice based on the progress of social institutions, which themselves are results of historical patterns and trends (Haller 2004, 11).

  28. 28.

    Like Schmoller, Roscher attempted to achieve justice and harmonious relationships within society through a more equitable distribution of income via state intervention. Roscher’s defence of justice sought ‘the activation of “love” for the weaker members of society’ so as to minimize the ‘potential causes of a socialist revolution’ (Giouras 1995, 111, 113).

  29. 29.

    Hayek (2007, 18) argued that choice and scarcity are the main dilemmas of the discipline of economics and humanity in general; and that ‘Menger was the first to base the distinction between free and economic goods on the idea of scarcity.’ He also explained that even though all of ‘Menger’s analysis is grounded on the idea of scarcity,’ he did not use the term ‘scarcity’; instead, he used ‘Insufficient quantity’ or ‘das ökonomische Mengenverhältnis.’

Bibliography

  • Alter, M. (1990). What Do We Know About Menger? In B. J. Caldwell (Ed.), Carl Menger and His Legacy in Economics. Annual Supplement to Volume 22, History of Political Economy. Durham: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bateman, B. W., & Papadopoulos, K. (2011). Karl Knies and the Prehistory of Neoclassical Economics: Understanding the Importance of ‘Die Nationaloekonomische Lehre vom Werth’ (1855). Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 33(1), 19–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beiser, F. C. (2011). The German Historicist Tradition. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2004). Hayek’s Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2006). Popper and Hayek: Who Influenced Whom? In I. C. Jarvie, K. Milford, & D. W. Miller (Eds.), Karl Popper: A Centenary Assessment (Vol. I, pp. 111–124). Burlington: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardoso, J. L., & Psalidopous, M. (2016). The German Historical School and European Economic Thought. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupek, G. (2016). The Impact of the German Historical School on the Evolution of Economic Thought in Austria. In J. L. Cardoso & M. Psalidopous (Eds.), The German Historical School and European Economic Thought (pp. 22–41). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dingwall, J., & B. F. Hoselitz. (2007 [1976]). Translator’s Preface. In C. Menger, Principles of Economics (J. Dingwall & B. F. Hoselitz, Trans., pp. 37–40). Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giouras, T. (1995). Wilhelm Roscher: The Historical Method in the Social Sciences Critical Observations for a Contemporary Evaluation. Journal of Economic Studies, 22(3/4/5), 106–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gloria-Palermo, S. (1999). The Evolution of Austrian Economics from Menger to Lachmann. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grassl, W., & Smith, B. (1986). Austrian Economics: Historical and Philosophical Background. London: Helm Croom.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hacohen, M. H. (2000). Karl Popper: The Formative Years, 1902–1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haller, M. (2004). Mixing Economics and Ethics: Carl Menger vs. Gustav von Schmoller. Social Science Information, 43(1), 5–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1935). Prices and Production. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1944). The Road to Serfdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1964 [1952]). The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the Abuse of Reason. London: Free Press of Glencoe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1967). Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. London: Routledge & K. Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1976). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 2: The Mirage of Social Justice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1983). Knowledge, Evolution, and Society. London: Adam Smith Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1988). The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1994 [1944]). The Road to Serfdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2007 [1976]). Introduction. In C. Menger, Principles of Economics (J. Dingwall & B. F. Hoselitz, Trans., pp. 11–36). Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2011 [1960]). The Constitution of Liberty: The Definitive Edition (R. Hamowy, Ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2013). Law, Legislation and Liberty: A New Statement of the Liberal Principles of Justice and Political Economy. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Herbener, J. M. (1991). Ludwig von Mises and the Austrian School of Economics. The Review of Austrian Economics, 5(2), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2001). How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ingram, J. K. (1967). A History of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kobayasi, J. (2000). Karl Knies’s Conception of Political Economy: The Logical Status of Analogie and Sitte. In Y. Shionoya (Ed.), German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics (pp. 54–71). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Louzek, M. (2011). The Battle of Methods in Economics: The Classical Methodenstreit: Menger vs. Schmoller. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 70(2), 439–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (1963 [1883]). Problems of Economics and Sociology. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (1985 [1883]). Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences with Special Reference to Economics (L. Schneider, Ed., F. J. Nock, Trans.). New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (2007 [1976/1871]). Principles of Economics (J. D. Dingwall & B. F. Hoselitz, Trans.). Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milford, K. (1995). Roscher’s Epistemological and Methodological Position Its Importance for the Methodenstreit. Journal of Economic Studies, 22(3/4/5), 26–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1966). Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. Chicago: Henry Regnery.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1936 [1922]). Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis (J. Kahane, Trans.). London: Jonathon Cape.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nau, H. H. (2000). Gustav Schmoller’s Historico—Ethical Political Economy: Ethics, Politics and Economics in the Younger German Historical School, 1860–1917. European Journal History of Economic Thought, 7(4), 507–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearson, H. 1999. Was there Really a German Historical School of Economics? History of Political Economy, 31(3), 547–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peuker, H. (2001). The Schmoller Renaissance. History of Political Economy, 33(1), 71–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richter, R. (1996). Bridging Old and New Institutional Economics: Gustav Schmoller, the Leader of the Younger German Historical School, Seen with Neoinstitutionalists’ Eyes. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 152(4), 567–592.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roscher, W. (1972 [1887]). Principles of Political Economy. New York: Arno Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Schmoller, G. (1967 [1884]). The Mercantile System and Its Historical Significance. New York: A.M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Senn, P. R. (1989). What Has Happened to Gustav von Schmoller in English? HES Bulletin, 11(2), 252–295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Senn, P. R. (2005). The German Historical Schools in the History of Economic Thought. Journal of Economic Studies, 32(3), 185–255. www.emeraldinsight.com/0144-3585.htm.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shionoya, Y. (2000). German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shionoya, Y. (2005). The Soul of the German Historical School: Methodological Essays on Schmoller, Weber and Schumpeter. Boston: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1985). Economic History and Economics. American Economic Review, 75(2), 328–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spicer, M. W. (1998). Cameralist Thought and Public Administration. Journal of Management History, 4(3), 149–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1937). The Economics of Carl Menger. Journal of Political Economy, 45(2), 229–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tribe, K. (1998). Governing Economy: Reformation of German Economic Discourse 1750–1840. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tribe, K. (2002). Historical Schools of Economics: German and English. Keele Economics Research Papers. www.keele.ac.uk/depts/ec/web/wpapers/kerp0202.pdf.

  • Tribe, K. (2003). The German Historical School: The Historical and Ethical Approach to Economics. History of Political Economy, 35(1), 173–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tribe, K. (2007). Strategies of Economic Order: German Economic Discourse, 1750–1950. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wakefield, A. (2005). Books, Bureaus, and the Historiography of Cameralism. European Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 311–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakefield, A. (2009). The Disordered Police State: German Cameralism as Science and Practice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Birsen Filip .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Filip, B. (2018). The German Historical School of Economics and the Foundations and Development of the Austrian School of Economics. In: Leeson, R. (eds) Hayek: A Collaborative Biography. Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-91358-2_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-91358-2_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-91357-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-91358-2

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics