Skip to main content

Abstract

The rural financial problems of Republican China are bound up to a considerable extent with the 4000 years or more of history of the Chinese people. To understand and appreciate the evolution of modern rural financial institutions, it is both necessary and interesting to consider historical developments in rural credit or forms of credit that peppered China during the decades and centuries prior to the Republican era. An historical retrospective not only provides some colorful and innovative approaches to providing credit access to farmers but also provides context as to why the innovations in cooperative credit that started to emerge in 1921 China are historically significant. In this chapter we want to step back and explore the institutions and methods by which farmers and emperors established the means to address the liquidity and credit needs of farmers in good times and bad. The ‘institutions’ that evolved include granaries, the Qian Hui (money-loan society, known in modern times as ROSCA, rotating savings and credits association), pawn shops, the Qian Zhuang (money shop) and Piao Hao (old-style native private banks), and private money lenders.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    North, Douglass C. (1986). The New Institutional Economics. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 142(1).

  2. 2.

    Kaldor , N. (1939). Speculation and economic stability. The Review of Economic Studies, 7(1), 1–27.

    Working, H. (1949). The theory of price of storage . The American Economic Review, 1254–1262.

  3. 3.

    Red Herring (2001). Death by Finance, April 11, 2001 …Toxic finance involves what is referred to as a “toxic convert,” which is a financing measure of last resort commonly used in the wake of the Nasdaq crash in 2000. In one example an entrepreneur, desperate for cash, agreed to an exchange of $17 million in cash for $19 million’s in common stock. The catch to a toxic convert is that the investors were entitled to the $19 million in stock, regardless of the price per share. It was not uncommon that the investors would then short sell the stock driving its price down, diluting the position of the original owners. The private investors running the scheme were in the industry as the ‘grimmest of reapers’, as were perhaps the usurers in ancient China. Accessed 8/23/2016 at share. http://www.placementtracker.com/News/PR%2004.11.01%20-%20Death%20By%20Finance2.html

  4. 4.

    Zhongqi Wu (1992). A short history of Chinese Grainaries, Chinese Storage & Transport, V.2. 

  5. 5.

    Zhou, Shuangxi (1996). History of Grain in Ancient Times, Chinese Commerce Publishing House.

    Fu, Hong (2009). “Development of Modern Rural Financial Institutions in Republican China”. Chinese Material Publishing House, Beijing. Even before this there are records showing some basic elements of ‘normalizing grain-sale’ were practiced as early as the Spring and Autumn periods of China’s development.

  6. 6.

    DuHalde , (1741), page 387.

  7. 7.

    Which is how one of the world’s largest granaries in the present era, the Commodity Credit Corporation (CCC) in the United States operates. With the CCC a target price is set below which farmers can voluntarily default on the ‘target loan’ which is equivalent to selling the stored grain to the CCC at the higher-than-market target price. See Gardner, B. L. (1977). Commodity options for agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 59(5), 986–992 or Turvey , C. G. , Brorsen, B. W ., & Baker, T. G. (1988, December). A Contingent Claim Pricing Model for Valuing Nonrecourse Loan Programs and Target Prices. In American Journal of Agricultural Economics (abstract Vol. 70, No. 5, pages 1197–1197).

  8. 8.

    Benevolent societies, commonly named t’ung-shan hui or ‘societies for sharing goodness’, developed around the Late Ming and early Qing dynasties and expanded beyond the charity granaries to assist impoverished widows, bury the unclaimed dead, set up soup kitchens, and provide capital to merchants and doctors. See Smith (1987). Page 309.

    Smith, J. F. H. (1987). Benevolent societies: the reshaping of charity during the late Ming and early Ch’ing. The Journal of Asian Studies, 46(02), 309–337.

  9. 9.

    Zhou (1996). Op Cit. One dan is a measure of weight ranging from 180 to 360 kilos depending on local measures. One dou is 1/10 of a dan.

  10. 10.

    Xu Liu (1975). Old book of the Tang, Beijing: ZhongHua publishing house.

  11. 11.

    Zhiping Chen. (2016).The design and change of Zhu Xi’s Community Granary. Researches in Chinese Economic History, 6.

  12. 12.

    Liping Bai. (2013). Emperor Kangxi and the construction of Community Granary , Beijing Social Science, 5.

  13. 13.

    Ramon H. Myers (1970). The Chinese Peasant Economy: Agricultural Development in Hebei and Shandong 1890–1949, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.

  14. 14.

    Bouman, F. J. (1977). Indigenous Savings and Credit Societies in The Third World. A Message. Savings and Development, 1(4), 181–219.

  15. 15.

    Fei, Hsiao-Tung , Peasant life in China: A Field Study of Country Life in the Yangtze Valley, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul Ltd.

  16. 16.

    Arthur H. Smith (1899). Village Life in China: A Study in Sociology, Einburgh and London.

  17. 17.

    Hsu, Chi-lien (1928). Rural Credit in China. 12 Chinese Soc. & Pol. Sci. Rev. 1.

  18. 18.

    Gamble, Sidney D. (1954). Ting Hsien: A North China Rural Community, California: Stanford University Press.

  19. 19.

    Arthur H. Smith. (1899). Op Cit.

  20. 20.

    Chi-lien Hsu. (1928).

  21. 21.

    Zongpei Wang. (1935). ROSCAs in China, Nanjing: Chinese Institute of Cooperatives.

  22. 22.

    We are unclear as to the reference to the ‘interest free’ loans referred to in this statement. This may be referring to the private granaries that we discussed above or simply interest-free loans by the benevolence societies that were springing up here and there throughout that period.

  23. 23.

    This debate was actually a continuation of a centuries-old debate. In 597 B.C. during the Tcheou dynasty there were two philosophers Yang and Me. Yang believed that all men should be loved alike, with strangers treated and loved as much as the nearest kin. Me, on the other hand, would have no man care about anyone except himself, nor be concerned about the welfare of the rest of mankind, including the emperor (DuHalde 1742, Page 329). Me’s approach is reminiscent of Adam Smith’s invisible hand in The Wealth of Nations: “By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it”. Me’s self-interest seems to refer to absolute self-interest even in non-economic terms. Adam Smith’s self-interest was in economic terms. At any rate the wedge between benevolence and self-interested behavior persisted through Wang’s time, and as between Yang and Me, conflicts arose between Wang and the proponents of the charity granaries . Like Smith and the economic part of Me, Wang believed that free charity distorted market signals and encouraged borrowing for fancy rather than necessity. By charging interest rates , farmers incentives to borrow changed, and it was no longer in their self-interest to borrow unnecessarily, nor was it in their self-interest to become imprudent and complacent in reliance on free loans from the charity granaries .

    Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the wealth of nations. Strahan and Cadell, London.

  24. 24.

    J. B. Tayler , Potentialities of cooperative movement in China, 21 Chinese Soc. &Pol. Sci. Rev. 1, 1937–1938.

  25. 25.

    Arthur H. Smith. (1899). Village Life in China: A Study in Sociology, Edinburgh and London, Oliphant, Anderson & Ferrier.

  26. 26.

    Shan, Qiang. (2002). A study on Hehui in regions south of the Yangtze River in mordern era, Research in Chinese economic history, Vol. 2.

  27. 27.

    Fei, Hsiao-Tung. (1939). Peasant Life in China:A field Study of Country Life in the Yangtze Valley, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul Ltd.

  28. 28.

    Qiang Shan. (2002). Op Cit.

  29. 29.

    Gamble, Sidney D. (1954). Ting Hsien: A North China Rural Community, Stanford University Press, Stanford.

  30. 30.

    Gamble. (1954). Op Cit.

  31. 31.

    Gamble. (1954). Op Cit.

  32. 32.

    Xiao, Zheng. (1977). Materials on Chinese Lands in 1931, Chengwen Press, Vol. 42.

  33. 33.

    Gamble. (1954). Op Cit.

  34. 34.

    Mi, Gonggan. (1936). A Study on Pawn Shop, Shanghai :the Commercial Press.

  35. 35.

    Liu, Qiugen. (1995). History of Pawn Shops in China, Shanghai Classics Publishing House, Shanghai.

  36. 36.

    We use the word dian in its present-day usage. In the Republican era this is known as tien, Likewise we use zhi in the present day but in the Republican era this was known as chih.

  37. 37.

    Chow C. P. (1938). Pawn shops in Shanghai , The Central Bank of China Bulletin, Vol. 4, No. 3.

  38. 38.

    Gamble (1954). Op Cit.

  39. 39.

    Ramon H. Myers. (1970), page 243.

  40. 40.

    Liu, Qiugen. (1955). History of Pawns hops in China, Shanghai Classics Publishing House, page 257.

  41. 41.

    Lu, Guoxiang. (1936). Estimation of Amounts of Capitals of Pawnshops in China, Monthly of Farmers Bank of China , Vol. 3, No. 4.

  42. 42.

    Yearbook of China. (1948). China Yearbook Press, page 1235.

  43. 43.

    Gonggan Mi. (1936). Pawn shops, The Commercial Press (CP), pages 196, 242.

  44. 44.

    Myers , Ramon H. (1970). The Chinese Peasant Economy: Agricultural Development in Hebei and Shandong 1890–1949, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

  45. 45.

    Fu, Hong. (2009). Op Cit.

  46. 46.

    Jianhui Huang. (2002). History of Shanxi Piaohao, Taiyuan: Shanxi Economy Press.

  47. 47.

    George H Chang. (1938). A Brief Survey of Chinese Native Banks, The Central Bank of China Bulliten, Vol. 4, No. 1.

  48. 48.

    Cited from L. Y. Shen. (1938). Chinese currencies: old and new. The Central Bank of China Bulletin, Vol. 4, No.1, page 10.

  49. 49.

    L. Y. Shen. (1938). Op Cit.

  50. 50.

    Chang, George H. (1938). A Brief Survey of Chinses Native Banks, The Central Bank of China Bulletin, Vol. 4, No. 1.

  51. 51.

    Duara, Prasenjit , Culture Power and The state Rural North China, 1900–1942, Stanford University Press 1988, page 271.

  52. 52.

    The term tien as used by Myers (1970) and refers to a mortgage but not of the usual sort. In actuality the term mortgage in his context can be interpreted in the modern sense as a usufruct loan. If interest is charged and the loan not repaid then the holder of the mortgage receives a usufruct right to use the land for his own purpose until the loan is repaid. If interest is not charged then the usufruct right is assigned at the time the loan is made and the holder of the mortgage has immediate use of the land until the loan is repaid. Buck (1930, page 67) notes that the number of usufruct mortgages was quite low, accounting for only 1.2% of total capital recorded in his surveys.

  53. 53.

    Buck , J.L. (1930). Chinese Farm Economy: A Study of 2866 Farms in Seventeen Localities and Seven Provinces in China. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Illinois, pages 67–68.

  54. 54.

    Myers (1970). Op Cit, page 95.

  55. 55.

    Myers (1970). Op Cit, page 167.

  56. 56.

    Myers (1970).

  57. 57.

    Hsu, Chi-lien (1928). “Rural Credit in China” Chinese Social and Political Science Review, Vol. 1 :1–15.

  58. 58.

    Buck , J.L. (1930). Op Cit, pages 147–148.

  59. 59.

    Buck (1930). Op Cit, Table 2, page 148.

  60. 60.

    Buck , J.L. (1937). Land Utilization in China: A Study of 16,786 Farms in 168 Localities, and 38,256 Farm Families in Twenty-Two Provinces in Chia, 1929–1933. University of Nanjing, Nanjing China, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Illinois, Table 6.2, pages 33, 34.

  61. 61.

    China Weekly Review, June 6 1931, pages 16–18 “The Plight of the Manchurian Peasant” by A.A.R. (anonymous). The information reported here is translated from uncited documents prepared by the Chinese Eastern Railway and South Manchurian Railway and translated from Russian and Japanese .

  62. 62.

    The unit of land here is a shang which equals 15 mou. Land ownership ranges from 1 mou to several hundred shang.

  63. 63.

    The reality was that earning a profit for the tenant was still very difficult and with many hurdles and too many intermediary agents: the farmer will carry his stock in native, horse driven, double-wheeled carts to the nearest populated center; the inn owner then acts as middleman and negotiates a price on behalf of the seller; or the grain dealers send out agents to the inns to negotiate directly. The peasant delivers the goods on payment of cash or simply leaves it in the hands of the innkeeper.

    But another problem arises in that payment is made in strange Kirin provincial dollar notes , Heilongjiang provincial dollar notes, Mukden provincial dollar notes and the Harbin dollar notes . These almost operate as different currencies and with different exchange rates. The peasant borrows money when it is at its lowest level in the summer and pays it back when it is at its highest level, losing purchasing power along the way. There are also reports of forward sales. The marketer will negotiate for soybean seed in July when the price is lowest for delivery in November when the price is highest. Because there is no forward pricing the farmer cannot hedge the price and is locked in to the lower price. Future deals were officially banned but still widely practiced.

    For farmers that live some distance from the central market the additional cost of cartage must be borne by the farmer (who also usually pays a lower rent but must also pay taxes when passing from one district to another). Other taxes can be steep ranging from 2.3% to 3.4% depending on region and on top of this a tax of perhaps $6 per carload. The taxes can amount to as much as 10% of the value of the grain paid by the merchants but no doubt passed on to farmers.

    Because of taxes and fees the farmer even in the best years might receive only 40% of the Free on Rail price of the commodities sold with the remainder being absorbed by taxes , fees, cartage, commissions, bribes, and so on.

    Banditry is a widespread problem. It is infrequent but when it occurs it is damaging. But because conditions are so bad for so many peasants they actually become part-time bandits themselves. There is also widespread corruption when farmers add dirt to bulk-weight grain; marketers fudging the scales and adding further weight to exporters, and so on, and these activities lead to price discounting.

  64. 64.

    Yang, Solon S.C “Eye Witness Account and Analysis of Wanpaoshan Incident ”.China Weekly Review, August 1 1931, pages 339–342. This section is based on a description of a lease agreement that was central to the July 2, 1931, Wanpaoshan incident. The incident arose from the leasing of lands to Koreans under Japanese protection for growing rice . Our interest in this particular article is the detailed lease arrangement which can be used as an example of lease arrangements from a landlord in Manchuria .

  65. 65.

    Under item 6 in the following list it should be noted that the irrigation ditch described cut across the lands of some 41 farmers who had no interest in the lease arrangement at all. Apparently CLCC/Koreans simply started digging ditches across these private lands without consent and under Japanese direction. This canal stretched for 7 miles by 15 feet wide by 8 feet deep destroying 2000 mou of land (333 acres) and putting an additional 40,000 mou at risk of flood . The Wanpaoshan incident resulted from the landowner protests. Changchun was the transfer point between the Japanese controlled South Manchuria Railway and the Soviet controlled China Eastern Railway and also home to a significant Japanese garrison. Under the orders of the Japanese , the Korean farmers, growing rice , were digging an irrigation canal drawing water from the Yitung River under Chinese protest. Failing to halt construction, 500 farmers armed with hoes, rakes, and scythes stormed the Korean settlement and destroyed the ditches. Japan responded by sending the military, evicting the farmers and maintaining control over the area. Ten Chinese farmers and two mounted policemen were killed. Meanwhile, as the news of the attack hit Soule, Koreans and Chinese clashed resulting in 44 Chinese deaths and one Korean dead.

    Editorial, “Japan Uses Koreans in New Plan to ‘Conquer’ Manchuria ” China Weekly Review, July 11 1931, pages 208–209.

  66. 66.

    1 picul = 1 dan = 50 kg.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Fu, H., Turvey, C.G. (2018). Traditional Forms of Credit in Rural China. In: The Evolution of Agricultural Credit during China’s Republican Era, 1912–1949. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-76801-4_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-76801-4_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-76800-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-76801-4

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics