Skip to main content

A Framework for Modelling Wealth Creation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 348 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter introduces a theoretical construct, referred to as a “socio-economic space”, in which one can analyse the functioning of the social division of labour. This socio-economic space provides a framework in which to consider how economic agents interact, assume roles in the social division of labour, build networks and bring about institutional innovation through entrepreneurial activities. Particularly, this theoretical construct allows an analysis of how institutions govern wealth creation processes and how institutions change: economic agents are embedded in the governing socio-economic institutions through their socio-economic role in the networks that make up the trade infrastructure in the social division of labour. On the other hand, their entrepreneurial activities affect the functionality of these institutions and create new institutions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   64.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    I emphasise here that institutional change is not necessarily “good”. There have been voices that have argued that certain innovations are clear failures if viewed from the perspective of the functionality of the socio-economic space. Currently, the socio-economic consequences of inequality caused by the adoption of neo-liberal institutions comes to mind (Stiglitz 2011, 2013; Piketty 2014).

  2. 2.

    The handshake is a very ancient social convention that has been depicted throughout history in art and texts. Many ancient artworks show representations of a handshake used for greeting and confirmation of accepted contracts.

  3. 3.

    On the other hand, governance in the broad sense refers to the regulation and conduct of socio-economic interaction through a system of commonly accepted institutions and rules. Government can be an important part of that, but governance can be strong even in the presence of a weak government. The main example is economies that are founded on a strong sense of morality and conduct following accepted social conventions.

  4. 4.

    It would be prudent to distinguish here the categories of media and platforms, even though they are closely related. The internet is clearly a medium, as is the mark-up language HTML and the programming language JAVA for building websites that allow platforms to develop. The platforms mentioned are built on top of these media. Indeed, Facebook uses the internet, HTML and JAVA to perform functions in its website design. Facebook itself, with its commonly accepted conventions, is however a platform that facilitates social interaction among its customers.

  5. 5.

    The social or collective nature of preferences is an expression of the social embeddedness of individual citizens. Indeed, it is common for individuals to prefer one homestead over another based on social opinion rather than true individualistic reflection and investigation.

  6. 6.

    I emphasise here that Pareto efficiency or optimality is a rather weak allocative property. Indeed, it does not impose any condition related to fairness or freedom. If all wealth is allocated to a single individual, say a dictator, then the situation is Pareto optimal: to make anybody else better off, one has to take wealth from the dictator.

  7. 7.

    The interested reader is invited to check that the given allocation is indeed Pareto optimal.

  8. 8.

    I emphasise here that the concept of willingness-to-pay has a purely individualistic meaning in neo-classical economics. There it is a purely individual expression of preference, and it is treated as such in the theory. There is a lack of reference to a strong relationship with purchasing power and social institutions such as societal hierarchy.

  9. 9.

    In the analysis introduced by Easley and Kleinberg the set of excess demand properties is directly related to their notion of a constricted set. Their use of network analysis allows a much easier identification of equilibrium allocations in the absence of any constructed sets. This cannot be applied in the analysis with the representations through tables used here.

  10. 10.

    The incorporated division of labour has been referred to as the manufacturing division of labour by Babbage (1835) and Marx (1867).

  11. 11.

    This theory clearly can be used as a theoretical justification for the bonus culture in our contemporary global economy. In particular, the prevailing remuneration culture in transnational corporations is affected by this. The theory is, however, more subtle than the bonus culture lets us believe: the balance between bonus and monitoring is very precise, requiring advanced structures for proper implementation. For a full and enlightening treatment of this subject, using elementary mathematical techniques, I refer to Ricketts (2003).

  12. 12.

    I emphasise here that this implies that a link ij is exactly the same as a link ji. This reflects that both parties that constitute this link are equal and that the link represents an interaction that is founded on parity between the two parties involved.

  13. 13.

    This implies that each node in D is connected to at least one other node, either as a predecessor or as a successor or both. It excludes the existence of unattached nodes in the directed network as is the case for (undirected) networks.

  14. 14.

    Note that I avoid the many philosophical complications that the proper definition of a market has to incorporate such as the voluntary nature of economic trade. Here I base the given definition on a practical consideration only. For an account of the complexities of the concept of a market and its proper definition I refer to Rosenbaum (2000).

  15. 15.

    In actuality, the lord was represented by a professional market master, who levied fees on the market participants on behalf of the lord. In many European cities, public markets are still run in this way, the market master nowadays usually being a municipal employee.

  16. 16.

    This activation could happen with a certain delay. Indeed, if there are fewer final consumers interested in obtaining units of a certain commodity provided through a supply chain there is naturally a lag before these supply chains are de-activated.

  17. 17.

    These historical episodes of collective entrepreneurship are usually just viewed as part of a process of economic development. In our managerial economy, they can also be referred to as research and development processes.

  18. 18.

    The fundamental difference between risk and uncertainty is that risk can be assessed through statistical methods (in particular it is subject to a probability distribution), while uncertainty is also known as unmeasurable risk and cannot be assessed through these methodologies. Uncertainty is usually assessed purely subjectively. Knight argues that entrepreneurship required the ability to handle uncertainty quite well, while risk could be assessed through designing and implementing appropriate managerial contingencies.

  19. 19.

    The Roman Empire actually continued in the east as the Byzantine Empire for another millennium after that.

  20. 20.

    The period of the Principate ended with the assumption of the title “Dominus” by the emperor Diocletian in 284 CE, introducing the Dominate era of the Roman Empire. During the Principate the Roman Republican constitution was formally upheld, but with Diocletian this was formally abolished, together with republican institutions such as the Consulate and the Senate. The Dominate was a system that focused on the supremacy of the Dominus as the sole ruler of the Empire, making it a purely autocratic system of government.

  21. 21.

    Definition: those chosen to fill a vacancy in any office or collegium.

  22. 22.

    There was no evidence that Augustus would have the right to deny any man’s candidature for office. Nor did he take over any running of elections from the magistrate whose function it was at any time.

  23. 23.

    A voting century refers to a class of eligible Roman citizens that are allowed to participate in the republican voting system. A century was based on ancient tribal heritage, but was expanded over time to include more and more new classes of (new) citizens.

  24. 24.

    Surprisingly, not much upheaval has been recorded. These laws were intrusive and restricted freedom. It is not clear why there was no more resistance. It could be that the large emphasis on sport and games in the circus and amphitheatres was leveraged in order to show Augustus to be a benevolent ruler of the Roman population.

  25. 25.

    The miracle itself was rather trivial from a modern perspective. The host given to a dying man in the sacrament of Holy Communion remained unburnt after it was thrown in a hearth fire. For a full account I refer to Shorto (2013, pp. 30–31).

  26. 26.

    The Vereenigde Oost-Indische Companie was established as a joint venture of merchants in Amsterdam to finance expeditions to the East Indies. They were able to establish profitable trade routes to these regions for the trade of spices and other goods. The success of the VOC resulted in the creation of a global trade network that was governed from Amsterdam.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., V. M. Carvalho, A. Ozdaglar, and A. Tahbaz-Salehi. 2012. The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 80: 1977–2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., and J. Tirole. 1997. Formal and Real Authority in Organizations. Journal of Political Economy 105: 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Albanese, J. 2011. Neanderthal Speech. Totem: The University of Western Ontario Journal of Anthropology Totem: The University of Western Ontario Journal of Anthropology Totem: The University of Western Ontario Journal of Anthropology Totem: The University of Western Ontario Journal of Anthropology 1(1): 99–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A.A. 1950. Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy 58: 211–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle (340 BCE). Ethica Nicomachea. 2009 ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle (350 BCE). The Politics: A Treatise on Government. 1995 ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. 1835. On the Economy of Machinery and Manufacturers. 4th enlarged ed. London: Augustus M. Kelley Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barabási, A.-L. 2016. Network Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., and J.-K. Choi. 2013. Coevolution of Farming and Private Property During the Early Holocene. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 110: 8830–8835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., and J.-K. Choi. 2016. The Neolithic Agricultural Revolution. SFI Working Paper 2016-09-016, Santa Fe Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brin, S., and L. Page. 1998. The Anatomy of a Large-Scale Hypertext Web Search Engine. Computer Networks 30: 107–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burt, R.S. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, B.M.S. 2016. The Great Transition: Climate, Disease and Society in the Late-Medieval World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho, V.M. 2014. From Micro to Macro via Production Networks. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28: 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4: 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dediu, D., and S.C. Levinson. 2013. On the Antiquity of Language: The Reinterpretation of Neandertal Linguistic Capacities and Its Consequences. Frontiers in Psychology 4(397). https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2013.00397.

  • Dessein, W. 2013. Incomplete contracts and firm boundaries: New directions. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 30 (suppl 1): i13–i36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D., and J. Kleinberg. 2010. Networks, Crowds and Markets: Reasoning about a Highly Connected World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eck, W. 2007. The Age of Augustus. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, S.A. 1991. Wage Labor and Guilds in Medieval Europe. 2006 reissue ed. Raleigh, NC: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D.S. 2003. Some Empirical Aspects of Multi-sided Platform Industries. Review of Network Economics 2(3): 191–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D.S., and R. Schmalensee. 2013. The Antitrust Analysis of Multi-Sided Platform Businesses. NBER Working Paper 18783.

    Google Scholar 

  • Everitt, A. 2006. Augustus: The Life of Rome’s First Emperor. London: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foley, D.K. 2010. What’s Wrong with the Fundamental Existence and Welfare Theorems? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 75: 115–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P. 2018. Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour Volume II: Network Economies. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P., and D. Diamantaras. 2003. To Trade or Not to Trade: Economies With a Variable Number of Tradeables. International Economic Review 44: 1173–1204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P., E.A. Lazarova, and P.H.M. Ruys. 2015. Stability in a Network Economy: The Role of Institutions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 119: 375–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsworthy, A. 2014. Augustus: From Revolutionary to Emperor. London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graeber, D. 2011. Debt: The First 5,000 Years. Brooklyn, NY: Melville House Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H., and O.D. Hart. 1983. An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem. Econometrica 51: 7–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagiu, A., and J. Wright. 2011. Multi-Sided Platforms. Harvard Business School Working Paper 12–024.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O.D., and J. Moore. 1990. Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm. Journal of Political Economy 98: 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O.D., and J. Moore. 1999. Foundations of Incomplete Contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 66: 115–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hudson, M. 1994. Land Monopolization, Fiscal Crises and Clean Slate ‘Jubilee’ Proclamations in Antiquity. In A Philosophy for a Fair Society, ed. M. Hudson, G.J. Miller, and C. Feder, 33–79. London: Shepheard-Walwyn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hudson, M. 2002. Reconstructing the Origins of Interest-Bearing Debt and the Logic of Clean Slates. In Debt and Economic Renewal in the Ancient Near East, ed. M. Hudson, and M. van de Mieroop. Bethesda: CDL Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huremovic, K., and F. Vega-Redondo. 2016. Production Networks. HAL Working Paper 01370725.

    Google Scholar 

  • Isaacson, W. 2011. Steve Jobs: The Exclusive Biography. London: Little, Brown Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M.O. 2008. Social and Economic Networks. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N., G. Zhao, E. Hunsader, H. Qi, N. Johnson, J. Meng, and B. Tivnan. 2013. Abrupt Rise of New Machine Ecology Beyond Human Response Time. Scientific Reports 3: 2627.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F.H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K.J. 1966. A New Approach to Consumer Theory. Journal of Political Economy 74: 132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levick, B. 2010. Augustus: Image and Substance. London: Pearson Education Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mak, G. 1994. Amsterdam: A Brief Life of the City. Amsterdam: Olympus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. 1867. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy — Volume I: The Process of Production of Capital. 1967 ed. New York, NY: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, A., M. Whinston, and J. Green. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzucato, M. 2014. The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector Myths. London: Anthem Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman, M.E.J. 2010. Networks: An Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogilvie, S. 2014. The Economics of Guilds. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28: 169–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. 1906. Manual of Political Economy. 1972 Reprint ed. London: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piccione, M., and A. Rubinstein. 2007. Equilibrium in the Jungle. Economic Journal 117: 883–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. 2014. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Boston, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plato (380 BCE). Republic. 2007 ed. London: Penguin Classics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricketts, M. 2003. The Economics of Business Enterprise: An Introduction to Economic Organisation and the Theory of the Firm. 3rd ed. London: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., and J. Tirole. 2003. Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets. Journal of European Economic Association 1(4): 990–1029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum, E.F. 2000. What Is a Market? On the Methodology of a Contested Concept. Review of Social Economy 58(4): 455–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. 2012. Economic Fables. New York, NY: Open Book Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J., and F.R. Velde. 2002. The Big Problem of Small Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. 1934. The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackle, G.L.S. 1979. Imagination and the Nature of Choice. Edinburgh: University of Edinburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L.S., and H. Scarf. 1974. On Cores and Indivisibility. Journal of Mathematical Economics 1: 23–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorto, R. 2013. Amsterdam: A History of the World’s Most Liberal City. New York, NY: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spanjers, W. 1997. Hierarchically Structured Exchange Economies: Models with Bilateral Exchange Institutions. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. 2011. Of the 1%, by the 1%, for the 1%. Vanity Fair.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. 2013. The Price of Inequality. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Temin, P. 2006. The Economy of the Early Roman Empire. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(1): 133–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Temin, P. 2012. The Roman Market Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink, R., and R.P. Gilles. 1994. A Social Power Index for Hierarchically Structured Populations of Economic Agents. In Imperfections and Behavior in Economic Organizations, ed. R.P. Gilles and P.H.M. Ruys. Theory and Decision Library, chap. 12, 279–318. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink, R., and R.P. Gilles. 2000. Measuring Domination in Directed Networks. Social Networks 22: 141–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink, R., and R.P. Gilles. 2016. Explicit and Latent Authority in Hierarchical Organizations. Working Paper, Queen’s Management School, Queen’s University Belfast.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vignes, A. 1993. Dispersion de prix et marchés décentralisés: le cas du marché au poisson de Marseille. Ph.D. thesis, European University Institute, Florence.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vignes, A., and J.-M. Etienne. 2011. Price Formation on the Marseille Fish Market: Evidence from a Network Analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 80: 50–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, I. 2011a. The Modern World-System I: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century, vol. 1, Reprint edn. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, I. 2011b. The Modern World-System II: Capitalism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600–1750, vol. 2, Reprint edn. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zakaria, F. 2008. The Post-American World. New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Co.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gilles, R.P. (2018). A Framework for Modelling Wealth Creation. In: Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-76397-2_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-76397-2_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-76396-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-76397-2

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics