Skip to main content

Overlapping-Generations Model of Economic Growth

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Macroeconomics of Corruption

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 1129 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter introduces the one-sector neoclassical growth model with overlapping generations. The primary focus of the chapter is growth via private physical capital accumulation. We think of private physical capital as manmade durable inputs to the production process. For our purposes, private capital can be primarily thought of as plant and equipment that is produced in one period and then used in production in the following period. To model production, we introduce firms, economic institutions that combine physical capital and labor to produce goods and services. Later in the chapter, we re-introduce the public capital that was the focus of Chaps. 2 and 3 and study the interaction between public and private capital accumulation, along with other effects of fiscal policy on growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Definitions of physical capital will vary depending on the purpose at hand. In some cases physical capital is defined to include inventories, software, land, and other inputs that extend beyond plant and equipment.

  2. 2.

    You can think of the value of r t as actually determined in period t−1. In that period households make their saving decision based on the firms’ commitments to rent capital in period t and pay the rental rate r t . In other words, r t is determined in period t−1 based on the savings behavior of households and the planned investment demands of firms.

  3. 3.

    The economy never literally reaches the steady state, although it will get arbitrarily close.

  4. 4.

    The weakening effect of the capital-labor ratio on wages, stems from the diminishing marginal product of capital. As capital accumulates relative to labor, the effect of further capital accumulation on output and wages gets smaller. Formally, note that the effect of an increase in k on the marginal product of labor is (1 − α)αAk α − 1 = (1 − α) × marginal product of captial.

  5. 5.

    There are differences of opinion about what qualifies as an appropriate target. Some believe that calibration should not involve previous econometric estimation. According to this view, all parameters within a model should be set to match particular data points or statistical moments of a data set (sample means, variances, and covariances), but not to match econometric estimates found in the literature. Others broaden the targets to include previous statistical estimates of the model’s parameters and behavioral responses, even if the model used in the estimation is not the same as the one used in the calibration . We are comfortable with either approach. The important point from our perspective is that all quantitative models, however calibrated, should be tested by comparing their predictions against observations or statistics not used in the calibration process. The fact that these “tests” or comparisons are not as formal and refined as traditional hypothesis testing in statistics does not particularly concern us. At this stage in the profession’s understanding of macroeconomics, models that even roughly approximate reality are difficult to find. Hopefully, as our approximations become more refined, we will need to worry about more formal testing procedure.

  6. 6.

    For a further discussion of the issues associated with quantifying overlapping generations models see Appendix B of Chap. 2 from Das et al. (2015).

  7. 7.

    See Das et al. (2015, Chap. 2) for an extensive of the quantitative theory to include human capital accumulation through public schooling.

  8. 8.

    Delays in needed reforms appear likely. Temporary improvements in government budget deficits in recent years have caused fiscal concerns to disappear from political discussions and debate (Auerbach and Gale 2015).

  9. 9.

    Dobrescu et al. (2012) note that saving has fallen across the developed world. Their analysis indicates that the decline in saving is associated with societies placing an increasingly greater weight on current consumption, which is reflected in greater intergenerational transfers toward older households.

  10. 10.

    See Steuerle (2014) for additional discussion of the politics and institutional factors behind the growing debt of the United States . Hallerberg et al. (2009) provide similar discussions for Europe.

  11. 11.

    See Kotlikoff (2003, Table 1) and Kotlikoff and Burns (2005, pp. 59–60).

References

  • Alfaro, L., 2016, “Gains from Foreign Direct Investment: Macro and Micro Approaches,” World Bank Economic Review: Advanced Access, March 23, 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach A, and Gale, D., 2015, “The Fiscal Problem: Gone Today, Here Tomorrow,” University of California Berkeley, Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, A., Gohkale, J., and Kotlikoff, L., 1991, “Generational Accounts: A Meaningful Alternative to Deficit Accounting,” in Bradford, D., editor, Tax Policy and the Economy, NBER 5, 55–110.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., 1997, Macroeconomics, Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congressional Budget Office, 2014, Budget Outlook, Congress of the United States, Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Das, S., Mourmouras, A., and Rangazas, P., 2015, Economic Growth and Development: A Dynamic Dual Economy Approach, Springer: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dobrescu, Loretti I. & Kotlikoff, Laurence J. & Motta, Alberto, 2012. “Why aren’t Developed Countries Saving?,” European Economic Review, 56(6), 1261–1275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, T., and Mandlebaum, M., 2012, That Used to be Us, Picodar: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gokhale, J., Page, B., and Sturroch, J., 1999, “Generational Accounting for the United States: An Update,” in Auerbach, A., Kotlikoff, L., and Leibfritz, W., Generational Accounting around the World, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gollin D., 2002, Getting income shares right. Journal of Political Economy 110(2): 458–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R., 2016, The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the Civil War, Princeton University Press: Princeton.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R., and von Hagen, J., 2009, Fiscal Governance in Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • King, R. and Rebelo, S., 1993, “Transitional Dynamics and Economic Growth in the Neoclassical Growth Model,” American Economic Review, 83, 908–931.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota, N., 1996, “The Equity Premium: It’s Still a Puzzle,” Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 42–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff, L., 2015, “America’s Fiscal Insolvency and its Generational Consequences,” Testimony to the Senate Budget Committee, February 25, 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff, L. 2003, Generational Policy, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff, L., and Burns, S., 2005, The Coming Generational Storm, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose, M., Prasad, E., Rogoff, K., and Wei, S., 2009, “Financial Globalization: A Reappraisal,” IMF Staff Papers, 56 (1), 8–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mourmouras A., Rangazas P. 2009, “Reconciling Kuznets and Habbakuk in a Unified Growth Model,” Journal of Economic Growth 14(2):149–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, M. 1982 The Rise and Decline in Nations, Yale University Press: New Haven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rangazas, P., 2002, The quantity and quality of schooling and U.S. labor productivity growth (1870–2000). Review of Economic Dynamics 5(4): 932–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steurele, E., 2014, Dead Men Ruling, Century Foundation: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey N, Rebelo S., 1995, Growth effects of flat-rate taxes. Journal of Political Economy, 103(3):519–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallis J., 2000, American government finance in the long-run: 1790 to 1990, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(1):61–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viig, J., 2011, The American Technological Challenge, Algora Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

4.1.1 The Government Intertemporal Budget Constraint

To begin construction of the GIBC , write the period t + 1 version of (4.15),

$$ {B}_{t+2}+{\tau}_{t+1}{w}_{t+1}{D}_{t+1}\left(1+\varepsilon \right){N}_{t+1}={R}_t{B}_{t+1}+{z}_{t+1}{N}_t+{w}_{t+1}{D}_{t+1}\varepsilon {N}_{t+1}+{G}_{t+2}. $$

Next solve for B t + 1 in (4.15) and substitute the solution into the equation above and rearrange terms to get

$$ \frac{B_{t+2}}{R_t{R}_{t-1}}={B}_t+\frac{PD_t}{R_{t-1}}+\frac{PD_{t+1}}{R_t{R}_{t-1}}, $$

where PD t  ≡ z t N t − 1 + w t D t εN t  + G t + 1 − τ t w t D t (1 + ε)N t is the primary deficit: the difference between spending, excluding interest and debt repayments, and taxes. We can continue this process of “solving forward” by substituting the expression above into the period t + 2-version of (4.15) and so on. The end result of the forward substitution, N-periods ahead, gives

$$ \frac{B_{t+N}}{\prod \limits_{i=0}^N{R}_{t-1+i}}={B}_t+\sum \limits_{i=0}^{N-1}\frac{PD_{t+i}}{\prod \limits_{j=0}^i{R}_{t-1+j}}. $$

To continue the forward substitution out to the indefinite future, the left-hand-side of the equation above, the present value of outstanding government debt in period t + N, cannot “explode.” In other words, government debt cannot become “too large” in present value terms. This requires that growth rate of debt be smaller than the interest rate, so that

$$ \frac{B_{t+N}}{\prod \limits_{i=0}^N{R}_{t-1+i}}\to 0,\kern1em \mathrm{as}\kern1em N\to \infty . $$

This condition, known as the No Ponzi Game (NPG) condition, means that the government cannot continually issue new debt that is large enough to pay back both previously issued debt and the interest owed on previously issued debt. This scenario would be like the famous Ponzi schemes in finance where funds collected from new investors are used to pay off previous investors. If the government could get away with this much borrowing, it is not constrained at all. Note that satisfying the condition does allow the government to “rollover” a finite amount of debt forever, as long as it finances the interest on that debt with taxes so that the growth rate of the debt is not equal to the interest rate or greater. Using the condition that the present value of government debt goes to zero as time marches on, allows us to write the GIBC as in the text.

There is a related requirement that says for the government to remain solvent, the debt-to-output ratio must remain finite and not explode over time. It is possible for the government to remain solvent even if the NPG condition fails. This could happen if the growth rate of output exceeds the interest rate on government debt . There have been extended historical episodes where the growth rate of output has exceeded the real interest rate on debt. However this is normally not possible so it is also not possible for the government to indefinitely borrow ever larger amounts to pay back both past debt and interest. For example, currently real interest rates are less than the growth in output. As mentioned in this Chapter and as will be discussed in detail in Chap. 7, this situation will not last because there are factors that will both raise interest rates and lower output growth rates. The likelihood of a sharp rise in interest rates increases with the continued increase in debt to GDP ratio.

4.1.2 Tax Rates

In the text, we consider the value of the wage tax rate that maximizes the height of the transition equation for the private capital-labor ratio. Maximizing the growth in private capital intensity is not necessarily a reasonable objective. Instead we might consider the tax rate that maximizes state worker productivity (τ ∗∗∗) or steady state household utility (τ ∗∗). One can compute these tax rates as well (see Problems 29–31). The comparison of the three tax rates is

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{\tau}^{\ast \ast \ast }=\frac{\frac{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)+\alpha }+\varepsilon }{1+\varepsilon }>\\ {}{\tau}^{\ast \ast }=\frac{\frac{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)+\alpha}\left(\frac{1+\beta }{\left(\frac{1}{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)+\alpha}\right)+\beta}\right)+\varepsilon }{1+\varepsilon }=\frac{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)\left(\frac{1+\beta }{1+\beta \left(\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)+\alpha \right)}\right)+\varepsilon }{1+\varepsilon }>\\ {}{\tau}^{\ast }=\frac{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)+\varepsilon }{1+\varepsilon },\end{array}} $$

because μ(1 − α) + α < 1.

The tax rate that maximizes steady utility is perhaps the most compelling. It is higher than the tax rate that maximizes steady state capital intensity because there is a benefit to households of keeping the private capital intensity lower than the maximum. All households are savers, so a higher return to capital, other things constant, raises household welfare. The desire to keep the return to capital high creates an incentive to keep private capital intensity low. This consideration causes the policy maker to set the tax rate higher than the one that maximizes the steady state value of k.

The highest tax rate is the one that maximizes steady state worker productivity . This tax rate is higher than the rate that maximizes steady state utility because it does not account for the fact that a higher tax rate on wages lowers the after-tax wage that determines household consumption and instead only focuses on the before-tax wage associated with worker productivity .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ivanyna, M., Mourmouras, A., Rangazas, P. (2018). Overlapping-Generations Model of Economic Growth. In: The Macroeconomics of Corruption. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-68666-0_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics