Skip to main content

Was Wilhelm Röpke Really a Proto-Keynesian?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences ((EHES,volume 20))

Abstract

Fèvre examines the difficulties of the commonly encountered qualification that Wilhelm Röpke’s early work is “proto-Keynesian.” By focusing on his 1936 Crises and Cycles and previous publications, Fèvre shows that Röpke attempted a synthesis by drawing upon various inspirations in business cycle theory. The major impulses stemmed from J.M. Keynes, with concepts from the period before his General Theory, and F.A. Hayek, both of whom in Fèvre’s assessment were equally important for Röpke regarding different phases of the business cycle. Röpke’s innovative approach to the secondary depression and “liberal interventionism” as a possible solution for this depression type receive further attention. Moreover, Röpke’s political insights from the same publications help to understand why Röpke’s latest works were characterized by such a virulent anti-Keynesianism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Within a broader perspective, the study directed by Peter E. Hall (1989) on The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations showed how Western countries’ countercyclical fiscal policies combatting unemployment were developed primarily without any reference to Keynes. Franklin D. Roosevelt’s New Deal is an obvious example, but other examples can be found in Sweden, France, and Italy (see also Bateman, 2006, pp. 283–286).

  2. 2.

    Between 1932 and 1936, a series of publications—Röpke (1933, 1934, 1935a, 1936c, 1936d)—can be traced where he specified certain aspects of his business cycle theory.

  3. 3.

    For a recent account, see Hagemann (2013, pp. 45–47).

  4. 4.

    If Röpke “cannot help feeling deep sympathy with the general trend of ideas of the psychological school” of which Arthur C. Pigou is the main exponent (Röpke 1936a, p. 97), he rejected it as a proper explanation of the business cycle on the basis of two interrelated arguments. First, psychological factors do not concern the ultimate causes of the ups and downs of the cycle but constitute mere adjunction to oscillations. Second, the ultimate causes are to be found in fluctuations in “real facts of economic life” (such as the value of money, costs or prices, income structure, etc.) and the “real task consists in showing how these psychological events connect up as a whole” (Röpke 1936a, p. 96).

  5. 5.

    Röpke (1936c, p. 325) gave credit especially to John M. Clark (1917) for having developed this concept.

  6. 6.

    For the controversy between Hayek, Sraffa, and Keynes following the publication of Prices and Production, see Kurz (2000).

  7. 7.

    Röpke gave a good explanation of that plan in his “Trends in German Business Cycle Policy”: “What in effect the plan amounted to was that the most burdensome taxes (business taxes, turnover tax, etc.), while not actually abolished, were transformed into liquid assets. The whole system was rather complicated, but its meaning can be summed up by saying that in the place of certain taxes, a forced loan was instituted, the titles to which, thanks to the collaboration of the banking system, could be sold or employed as collateral. In other words, a certain amount of taxes were virtually abolished, but the financial burden of this abolition was temporarily shifted from the state to the banking system, which would expand credit to the corresponding extent. This assumed that business men would employ their Steuergutscheine, not for paying off or consolidating old debts—improving their own liquidity, as it were—but for making new investments in working or in fixed capital” (Röpke 1933, p. 432, emphasis in the original).

  8. 8.

    For the search for consensus in the business cycle theory in the 1930s, see Boianovsky and Trautwein (2006).

  9. 9.

    See also Ellis (1938).

References

  • Backhaus JG (1985) Keynesianism in Germany. In: Lawson T, Pesaran H (eds) Keynes’ economics: methodological issues. Routledge, London, pp 209–253

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus JG (1997) Keynes’ German contenders 1932–1944: on the sociology of multiple discovery in economics. Hist Econ Ideas 5(2):69–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Bateman BW (2006) Keynes and Keynesianism. In: Backhouse RE, Bateman BW (eds) The Cambridge companion to Keynes. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 271–290

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Blümle G, Goldschmidt N (2006) From economic stability to social order: The debate about business cycle theory in the 1920s and its relevance for the development of theories of social order by Lowe, Hayek and Eucken. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 13(4):543–570

    Google Scholar 

  • Boianovsky M, Trautwein H-M (2006) Haberler, the League of Nations, and the quest for consensus in business cycle theory in the 1930s. Hist Polit Econ 38(1):45–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark JM (1917) Business acceleration and the law of demand: a technical factor in economic cycles. J Polit Econ 25(3):217–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commun P (2014) German ordoliberalism: order vs. disorder in Röpke’s early works. Rivista i-lex 9(21):27–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Dostaler G, Maris B (2009) Capitalisme et pulsion de mort. Albin Michel, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis HS (1936) Review of crises and cycles, Wilhelm Röpke. Am Econ Rev 26(4):762–764

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis HS (1938) Notes on recent business-cycle literature. Rev Econ Stat 20(3):111–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fèvre R (2015) Du libéralisme historique à la crise sociale du XXe siècle : la lecture de Wilhelm Röpke. Revue économique 66(5):901–932

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garvy G (1975) Keynes and the economic activists of pre-Hitler Germany. J Polit Econ 83(2):391–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haberler G (1943) Prospérité et dépression: étude théorique des cycles économiques. Société des Nations Service d’études économiques, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann H (2013) Germany after World War II: Ordoliberalism, the Social Market Economy and Keynesianism. Hist Econ Thought Pol 1(1):37–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall PA (ed) (1989) The political power of economic ideas: Keynesianism across nations. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1931) Prices and production. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1944) The road to serfdom, reprinted in: Caldwell BJ (ed) (2007) The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol 2. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Howson S (2011) Lionel Robbins. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hudson M (1985) German economists and the depression of 1929–1933. Hist Polit Econ 17(1):35–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1930) A treatise on money: the applied theory of money. Reprinted in: Johnson E, Moggridge D (eds) (1973) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 6. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Reprinted in: Johnson E, Moggridge D (eds) (1973) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 7. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Klausinger H (1999) German anticipations of the Keynesian revolution?: The case of Lautenbach, Neisser and Röpke. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 6(3):378–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolev S (2010) F. A. Hayek as an ordo-liberal. HWWI Research Paper 5–11, Hamburg Institute of International Economics, Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD (2000) The Hayek-Keynes-Sraffa controversy reconsidered. In: Kurz HD (ed) Critical essays on Piero Sraffa’s legacy in economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 257–302

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Magliulo A (2016) Hayek and the Great Depression of 1929: did he really change his mind? Eur J Hist Econ Thought 23(1):31–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meade JE (1936) Review of “Crises and Cycles” by Wilhelm Röpke. Econ J 46(184):694–695

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsen AH (2015) Wilhelm Röpke and Richard C. Koo on secondary deflations and balance sheet recessions. Econ Aff 35(2):215–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peukert H (1992) Das sozialökonomische Werk Wilhelm Röpkes. Peter Lang, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson DH (1936) Review of “Crises and Cycles” by Wilhelm Röpke. Economica 3(12):476–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1932) Krise und Konjunktur. Quelle & Meyer, Leipzig

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1933) Trends in German business cycle policy. Econ J 43(171):427–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1934) Kapitalismus und Imperialismus. Zeitschrift für Schweizerische Statistik und Volkswirtschaft 70(4):370–386

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1935a) Fascist economics. Economica 2(5):85–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1935b) Letter to L. Robbins, December 22 LSE Archive: ROBBINS/3/1/2

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1936a) Crises and cycles. William Hodge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1936b) Letter to L. Robbins, May 6. LSE Archive: ROBBINS/3/1/2

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1936c) Socialism, planning, and the business cycle. J Polit Econ 44(3):318–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1936d) Tendances actuelles de l’économie politique. Revue d’Économie Politique 50(4):1284–1307

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1937) Explanatory note on the review of Röpke’s “Crises and Cycles”. Am Econ Rev 27(1):108–109

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1942) Die Gesellschaftskrisis der Gegenwart. Eugen Rentsch, Erlenbach-Zurich. English edition: Röpke W (1950) The social crisis of our time. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Solchany J (2015) Wilhelm Röpke, l’autre Hayek. Aux origines du néolibéralisme. Publications de la Sorbonne, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Tooze JA (2001) Statistics and the German state, 1900–1945: the making of modern economic knowledge. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Tribe K (1995) Strategies of economic order: German economic discourse, 1750–1950. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raphaël Fèvre .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Fèvre, R. (2018). Was Wilhelm Röpke Really a Proto-Keynesian?. In: Commun, P., Kolev, S. (eds) Wilhelm Röpke (1899–1966). The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences, vol 20. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-68357-7_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics