Paleo- and Neoliberals: Ludwig von Mises and the “Ordo-interventionists”

Chapter
Part of the The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences book series (EHES, volume 20)

Abstract

Kolev provides a reconstruction of the intellectual relationship between Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises and German ordoliberals Walter Eucken and Wilhelm Röpke, aiming at a nuanced understanding of the hostile climate in their relationship. The four decades are separated into five phases: (1) socialization echoing the Methodenstreit, (2) initial debates on business cycles in the 1920s and early 1930s, (3) clashes on political economy and social philosophy at the Colloque Walter Lippmann in 1938 and the early decades of the Mont Pèlerin Society after 1947, (4) coexistence during the German “economic miracle,” and (5) exchanges in the 1960s, including new archival materials about Mises’ only honorary doctorate in economics, at Freiburg in 1964. As an overarching element, Kolev offers a specific interpretation of neoliberalism.

References

  1. Allgoewer E (2009/2010) Wilhelm Röpke und die Konjunkturtheorie im 20. Jahrhundert. In: Rieter H, Zweynert J (eds) Wort und Wirkung: Wilhelm Röpkes Bedeutung für die Gegenwart. Metropolis, Marburg, pp 123–161Google Scholar
  2. Ancil RE (1994) Röpke and von Mises: The difference. In: Wilhelm Röpke Rev 1(94), Available online: http://www.theimaginativeconservative.org/2015/04/roepke-von-mises-the-difference.html
  3. Backhouse RE (2007) Lives in synopsis: the production and use of short biographies by historians of economics. In: Weintraub ER, Forget EL (eds) Economists’ lives: biography and autobiography in the history of economics. Hist Polit Econ Ann Suppl 39:51–75Google Scholar
  4. Barry NP (1989) Political and economic thought of German neo-liberals. In: Peacock AT, Willgerodt H (eds) German neo-liberals and the Social Market Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp 105–124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Blümle G, Goldschmidt N (2006) From economic stability to social order: the debate about business cycle theory in the 1920s and its relevance for the development of theories of social order by Lowe, Hayek and Eucken. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 13(4):543–570CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Blumenthal K (2007) Die Steuertheorien der Austrian Economics. Von Menger zu Mises, Metropolis, MarburgGoogle Scholar
  7. Boas TC, Gans-Morse J (2009) Neoliberalism: from new liberal philosophy to anti-liberal slogan. Stud Compar Int Develop 44(2):137–161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Buchanan JM (1979) Notes on Hayek. Unpublished Manuscript, Center for Study of Public Choice, FairfaxGoogle Scholar
  9. Burgin A (2012) The great persuasion: reinventing free markets since the depression. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MACrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Dathe U (2009) Walter Euckens Weg zum Liberalismus (1918–1934). ORDO Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 60:53–86Google Scholar
  11. Dekker E (2016) The Viennese students of civilization: the meaning and context of Austrian economics reconsidered. Cambridge University Press, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Dekker E (2017) The importance of the framework: the unexpected commonalities in the work of Karl Polanyi and the early neo-liberals. Paper presented at the History of Economics Society annual conference, University of Toronto, 22–26 June, 2017Google Scholar
  13. Düppe T, Weintraub RE (2014) Finding equilibrium: Arrow, Debreu, McKenzie and the problem of scientific credit. Princeton University Press, PrincetonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Ebeling RM (2003) The limits of economic policy: The Austrian economists and the German ORDO liberals. In: Austrian economics and the political economy of freedom. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 231–246CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Eucken W (1926) Besprechung: Ludwig Mises—Theorie des Geldes und der Umlaufsmittel. Schmollers Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reiche 50(2):649–653Google Scholar
  16. Eucken W (1928a/1929a) Kredit und Konjunktur. In: Boese F (ed) Verhandlungen des Vereins für Socialpolitik in Zürich 1928. Duncker & Humblot, Munich, pp 287–305Google Scholar
  17. Eucken W (1928b/1929b) Schlußwort: Prof. Dr. Eucken (Freiburg). In: Boese F (ed) Verhandlungen des Vereins für Socialpolitik in Zürich 1928. Duncker & Humblot, Munich, pp 386–391Google Scholar
  18. Eucken W (1933) Beitrag zur Festschrift. In: Clausing G (ed) Der Stand und die nächste Zukunft der Konjunkturforschung: Festschrift für Arthur Spiethoff. Duncker & Humblot, Munich, pp 74–78Google Scholar
  19. Eucken W (1940/1989) The foundations of economics. History and theory in the analysis of economic reality. Springer, BerlinGoogle Scholar
  20. Feld LP, Köhler EA (eds) (2015) Wettbewerbsordnung und Monopolbekämpfung: Zum Gedenken an Leonhard Miksch (1901–1950). Mohr Siebeck, TübingenGoogle Scholar
  21. Foucault M (1979/2008) The birth of biopolitics: lectures at the Collège de France 1978–79. Palgrave Macmillan, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  22. Friedman M, Friedman RD (1998) Two lucky people: memoirs. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  23. Gide C (1898) Has co-operation introduced a new principle into economics? Econ J 8(32):490–511CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Glossner CL (2010) The making of the German post-war economy. I.B. Tauris, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  25. Goodwin CD (2014) Walter Lippmann: public economist. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MACrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Gregg S (2010) Wilhelm Röpke’s political economy. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Hayek FA (1933) Beitrag zur Festschrift. In: Clausing G (ed) Der Stand und die nächste Zukunft der Konjunkturforschung: Festschrift für Arthur Spiethoff. Duncker & Humblot, Munich, pp 110–117Google Scholar
  28. Hayek FA (1947/2004) Der Mensch in der Planwirtschaft (Presentation at the 3rd European Forum Alpbach). In: Gesammelte Schriften, vol A7. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen, pp 153–170Google Scholar
  29. Hayek FA (1951/1967) The transmission of the ideals of economic freedom. In: Studies in philosophy, politics and economics. Routledge, London, pp 195–200Google Scholar
  30. Hayek FA (1959) Glückwunschadresse. In: Röpke W (ed) Gegen die Brandung: Zeugnisse eines Gelehrtenlebens unserer Zeit. Eugen Rentsch, Erlenbach-Zurich, pp 25–28Google Scholar
  31. Hayek FA (1962/1969) Wirtschaft, Wissenschaft und Politik (Inaugural lecture on June 18 1962 at the University of Freiburg). In: Freiburger Studien. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen, pp 1–17Google Scholar
  32. Hayek FA (1992) Ludwig von Mises (1881–1973). In: The fortunes of liberalism. Vol 4 of the collected works of F.A. Hayek. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 126–159Google Scholar
  33. Hennecke HJ (2000) Friedrich August von Hayek: Die Tradition der Freiheit. Wirtschaft und Finanzen, DüsseldorfGoogle Scholar
  34. Hennecke HJ (2005) Wilhelm Röpke: Ein Leben in der Brandung. Schäffer Poeschel, StuttgartGoogle Scholar
  35. Hülsmann JG (2007) Mises: the last knight of liberalism. Ludwig von Mises Institute, AuburnGoogle Scholar
  36. Huerta de Soto J (2006) Money, bank credit, and economic cycles. Ludwig von Mises Institute, AuburnGoogle Scholar
  37. Ikeda S (2015) Dynamics of interventionism. In: Boettke PJ, Coyne CJ (eds) The Oxford handbook of Austrian economics. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 393–416Google Scholar
  38. Janssen H (1998/2000) Nationalökonomie und Nationalsozialismus. Die deutsche Volkswirtschaftslehre in den dreißiger Jahren des 20. Jahrhunderts. Metropolis, MarburgGoogle Scholar
  39. Janssen H (2009) Zwischen Historismus und Neoklassik: Alexander Rüstow und die Krise in der deutschen Volkswirtschaftslehre. ORDO Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 60:101–118. Also: HWWI Research Paper 5-7, Hamburg Institute of International Economics, HamburgGoogle Scholar
  40. Klausinger H (1999) German anticipations of the Keynesian revolution? The case of Lautenbach, Neisser and Röpke. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 6(3):378–403CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Klausinger H (2006) “In the Wilderness”: emigration and the decline of the Austrian School. Hist Polit Econ 38(4):617–664CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Klinckowstroem W (2000) Walter Eucken: Eine biographische Skizze. In: Gerken L (ed) Walter Eucken und sein Werk. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen, pp 53–115Google Scholar
  43. Köster R (2011) Die Wissenschaft der Außenseiter: Die Krise der Nationalökonomie in der Weimarer Republik. Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, GöttingenCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Kolev S (2010) F. A. Hayek as an ordo-liberal. HWWI Research Paper 5–11, Hamburg Institute of International Economics, HamburgGoogle Scholar
  45. Kolev S (2013) Neoliberale Staatsverständnisse im Vergleich. Lucius & Lucius, StuttgartCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Kolev S (2015) Ordoliberalism and the Austrian School. In: Boettke PJ, Coyne CJ (eds) The Oxford handbook of Austrian economics. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 419–444Google Scholar
  47. Kolev S (2016) Ludwig von Mises and the “ordo-interventionists”—more than just aggression and contempt? Working Paper 2016–35, Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University, DurhamGoogle Scholar
  48. Kolev S, Goldschmidt N, Hesse J-O (2014) Walter Eucken’s role in the early history of the Mont Pèlerin Society. Discussion Paper 14/02, Walter Eucken Institut, FreiburgGoogle Scholar
  49. Krebs H, Tarrach M (2016) Liberalismus im Zeitalter der Globalisierung: Denkübungen zur Weitung des Horizonts. BoD, NorderstedtGoogle Scholar
  50. Magliulo A (2016) Hayek and the Great Depression of 1929: did he really change his mind? Eur J Hist Econ Thought 23(1):31–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Mises L (1928/1929) Aussprache: Prof. Dr. von Mises (Wien). In: Boese F (ed) Verhandlungen des Vereins für Socialpolitik in Zürich 1928. Duncker & Humblot, Munich, pp 317–326Google Scholar
  52. Mises L (1929/2011) A critique of interventionism. Ludwig von Mises Institute, AuburnGoogle Scholar
  53. Mises L (1931) Die Ursachen der Wirtschaftskrise. Ein Vortrag. J. C. B Mohr (Paul Siebeck), TübingenGoogle Scholar
  54. Mises L (1943) “Elastic expectations” and the Austrian Theory of the trade cycle. Economica 10(39):251–252CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Mises L (1946/2009) Observations on Professor Hayek’s Plan. Libertarian Pap 1(2):1–3. Available online: http://www.libertarianpapers.org/articles/2009/lp-1-2.pdf
  56. Mises L (1949/1966) Human action. A treatise on economics. Henry Regenery, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  57. Mises L (1957a) Die Wahrheit über den Interventionismus. Monatsblätter für freiheitliche Wirtschaftspolitik 3(10):599–607Google Scholar
  58. Mises L (1957b) Die Rolle der Vorstellung vom Volkseinkommen in der Weltpolitik. Monatsblätter für freiheitliche Wirtschaftspolitik 3(2):88–92Google Scholar
  59. Mises L (1958/2007) Economic freedom in the present-day world. In: Economic freedom and interventionism. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, pp 268–278Google Scholar
  60. Mises L (1964) Das Eigentum in der Marktwirtschaft. Monatsblätter für freiheitliche Wirtschaftspolitik 10(12):725–729Google Scholar
  61. Mises L (1965) Monopole – Dichtung und Wahrheit. Monatsblätter für freiheitliche Wirtschaftspolitik 11(1):40–47Google Scholar
  62. Mises L (1966) Wilhelm Roepke, RIP. National Review, March 8:200Google Scholar
  63. Mises L (1969/2013) The historical setting of the Austrian School of Economics. In: Notes and recollections. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, pp 125–153Google Scholar
  64. Mises L (1978/2013) Notes and recollections. Liberty Fund, IndianapolisGoogle Scholar
  65. Moss LS (ed) (1976) The economics of Ludwig von Mises: toward a critical reappraisal. Sheed and Ward, Kansas CityGoogle Scholar
  66. Nicholls AJ (1994) Freedom with responsibility. The Social Market Economy in Germany (1918–1963). Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  67. Nientiedt D, Köhler EA (2017) The Muthesius controversy: a tale of two liberalisms. Hist Polit Econ 49(4):607–630Google Scholar
  68. Pantaleoni M (1898) An attempt to analyse the concepts of “strong and weak” in their economic connection. Econ J 8(30):183–205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Peukert H (2000) Walter Eucken (1891–1950) and the historical school. In: Koslowski P (ed) The theory of capitalism in the German economic tradition Historism, ordo-liberalism, critical theory, solidarism. Springer, Berlin, pp 93–146Google Scholar
  70. Plickert P (2008) Wandlungen des Neoliberalismus. Eine Studie zu Entwicklung und Ausstrahlung der “Mont Pèlerin Society”. Lucius & Lucius, StuttgartCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Pongracic I (1997) How different were Röpke and Mises? Rev Austrian Econ 10(1):125–132CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Record of the Sessions (1938) The record of the sessions of the Walter Lippmann Colloquium, August 26–30 1938 in Paris. Typoscript English translation by Liberty FundGoogle Scholar
  73. Rieter H (1994/2002) Historische Schulen. In: Issing O (ed) Geschichte der Nationalökonomie. Vahlen, Munich, pp 131–168Google Scholar
  74. Röpke W (1926) Kredit und Konjunktur. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 124:243–285Google Scholar
  75. Röpke W (1929) Staatsinterventionismus. In: Conrad J et al (eds) Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften. Ergänzungsband. Gustav Fischer, Jena, pp 861–882Google Scholar
  76. Röpke W (1931) Praktische Konjunkturpolitik. Die Arbeit der Brauns-Kommission. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 34(2):423–464Google Scholar
  77. Röpke W (1933a) Review: Ludwig Mises – Die Ursachen der Wirtschaftskrise. Ein Vortrag. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4(2):273–275Google Scholar
  78. Röpke W (1933b) Trends in German business cycle policy. Econ J 43(171):427–441CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Röpke W (1936) Crises and cycles. William Hodge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  80. Röpke W (1937/1963) Economics of the free society. Henry Regnery, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  81. Röpke W (1960) Blätter der Erinnerung an Walter Eucken. ORDO Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 12:3–19Google Scholar
  82. Röpke W (1961) Homage to a master and a friend. Mont Pèlerin Quarterly 10:5–7Google Scholar
  83. Schabas M (2002) Coming together: history of economics and history of science. Hist Polit Econ Ann Suppl 34:208–225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Schüller A (2003) Wilhelm Röpke – Werk und Wirken in Marburg: Lehren für Gegenwart und Zukunft. ORDO Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 54:21–48Google Scholar
  85. Schumpeter JA (1954/2006) History of economic analysis. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  86. Skousen M (2005) Vienna & Chicago: friends or foes? Capital Press, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  87. Solchany J (2015) Wilhelm Röpke, l’autre Hayek. Aux origines du néolibéralisme. Publications de la Sorbonne, ParisGoogle Scholar
  88. Stigler GJ (1988) Memoirs of an unregulated economist. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  89. Streit ME, Wohlgemuth M (2000) The market economy and the state: Hayekian and ordoliberal conceptions. In: Koslowski P (ed) The theory of capitalism in the German economic tradition Historism, ordo-liberalism, critical theory, solidarism. Springer, Berlin, pp 224–271Google Scholar
  90. Walter Eucken Institut (1964) Tätigkeitsbericht des Walter Eucken Instituts 1964, FreiburgGoogle Scholar
  91. Wegmann M (2002) Früher Neoliberalismus und europäische Integration. Interdependenz der nationalen, supranationalen und internationalen Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft (1932–1965). Nomos, Baden-BadenGoogle Scholar
  92. Zweynert J, Kolev S, Goldschmidt N (eds) (2016) Neue Ordnungsökonomik. Mohr Siebeck, TübingenGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer International Publishing AG 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Wilhelm Röpke InstituteErfurtGermany
  2. 2.Department of Business and EconomicsUniversity of Applied Sciences ZwickauZwickauGermany

Personalised recommendations