Skip to main content

The Making of the “Third Way”: Wilhelm Röpke, Luigi Einaudi, and the Identity of Neoliberalism

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences ((EHES,volume 20))

Abstract

Giordano explores the support and impulses which Wilhelm Röpke and Luigi Einaudi, one of the most influential Italian economists of the twentieth century, exchanged during their long and intense intellectual relationship. Their exchange continued from the mid-1930s until Einaudi’s death in 1961. Giordano focuses on their common vision of a liberal “Third Way” between totalitarian collectivism and historical capitalism. In their view, the true nature of the free market economy could only unfold if it was embedded in an “ethical-legal framework.” They also shared a diagnosis of the crisis of Western civilization. Despite some differences, both Röpke and Einaudi accompanied the incipient process of European integration, attempting to guide it toward the principles of the “Third Way.”

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the vast literature on neoliberalism, a helpful collection includes Denord (2007), Mirowski and Plehwe (2009), Audier (2012), Burgin (2012), Kolev (2013), Schulz-Forberg and Olsen (2014). For ordoliberalism, see Peacock and Willgerodt (1989) and Commun (2016). For the Social Market Economy, see Nichols (1994) and Muresan (2014).

  2. 2.

    The acceptance of this approach implies the recognition that “what was called ‘neoliberalism’ back in the 1930s does not correspond to the phenomenon that was labeled ‘neoliberalism’ in the 1970s, even though there may be some connections” (Audier 2012, p. 56). See also Kolev (2013, pp. 2–4).

  3. 3.

    For wide-ranging inquiries in Röpke’s economic and political liberalism, see Peukert (1992), Molina Cano (2001), Zmirak (2001), Hennecke (2005), Resico (2008), Gregg (2010), Solchany (2015). Following Foucault (2010 [1979]), Bonefeld (2012) and (2013) as well as Somma (2014) have assimilated Röpke to “mainstream” ordoliberals, convicting all of them for the naissance of authoritarian power-driven biopolitics. Among others, Goldschmidt and Rauchenschwandtner (2007) have attempted to rebut this narrative, while Mierzejewski (2006) has shed light on the nature of Röpke’s connections to Ludwig Erhard and the Social Market Economy.

  4. 4.

    W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, July 30, 1934, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961), AFLE (Archive of the Fondazione Luigi Einaudi), Section 2, File “Röpke, Wilhelm.” A brief account of Röpke’s Turkish years is given by Solchany (2015, pp. 65–78). See also the chapter by Antonio Masala and Özge Kama in this volume.

  5. 5.

    For Röpke’s approach, see Resico (2009), Gregg (2010, pp. 94–116), and Commun (2014).

  6. 6.

    If not otherwise stated, all translations of Einaudi’s papers and letters into English are mine.

  7. 7.

    “I have the great pleasure to acknowledge the receipt of a copy of your new book ‘Miti e paradossi della giustizia tributaria’, and to thank you wholeheartily for your great kindness. It promises most stimulating reading and most valuable instruction on several of the dark spots of Public Finance. […] I trust that my little book on Elementary Economics will have reached you in safety, and I ask you to look on it as on a pedagogical experiment,” W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, February 23, 1938, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961).

  8. 8.

    L. Einaudi to W. Röpke, April 29, 1942, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961). The Italian translation of the letter, the original (from which I quote) being in English, appeared in Giordano (2006, pp. 317–318).

  9. 9.

    L. Einaudi to W. Röpke, April 29, 1942, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961).

  10. 10.

    Solchany (2014, p. 98) notes that “all the publications of Röpke from the late twenties to his death, and to a lesser extent the writings of many other neoliberal intellectuals, may be interpreted as a thought on the crisis of modern world and the ways to remedy it.”

  11. 11.

    For the long and complex debate between Einaudi and Keynes, see Forte (2016).

  12. 12.

    As correctly stated in Bonefeld (2013), this view of Smith is rather misleading, more than ever in the light of recent studies on Smith, from Winch (1978) to Rothschild (2001). However, I consider unacceptable Bonefeld’s attempt to depict Smith as the forerunner of the (hypothetical) kind of “authoritarian liberalism” that ordoliberals and Röpke would eventually endorse.

  13. 13.

    For Lippmann’s economic liberalism, see Goodwin (2014, pp. 223–260).

  14. 14.

    Somewhat surprisingly, the rejection of collectivism and planning was grounded on ethical rather than economic reasons: “Let us glance back once more at the road of collectivism […] its details are sufficiently known: abolition of freedom and of the sphere of private personality, extreme mechanization, rigid hierarchies and proletarisation, the kneading of society into a dough-like lump, unrelieved dependency of each on the dominant group with its arbitrary and changing plans and programs where man in his uniqueness and dignity means nothing, power and the bureaucratic machine everything. Human dignity, freedom and justice have completely vanished there and, to round off the picture, even material productivity leaves much to be desired” (Röpke 1950 [1942], p. 176).

  15. 15.

    For Simons’ economic liberalism, see De Long (1990) and Köhler and Kolev (2011).

  16. 16.

    For the impact of Swiss politics on his thought, see Zmirak (2001, pp. 25–66), as well as the chapter by Andrea Franc in this volume.

  17. 17.

    W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, August 3, 1942, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961).

  18. 18.

    G. Solari to L. Einaudi, June 27, 1943, in Einaudi-Solari Letters (1899–1952), AFLE, section 2, File “Solari, Gioele”.

  19. 19.

    L. Einaudi to E. Rossi, November 8, 1943, in Einaudi and Rossi (1988, p. 133).

  20. 20.

    L. Einaudi to W. Röpke, October 9, 1943, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961).

  21. 21.

    W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, October 12, 1943, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961).

  22. 22.

    Röpke’s connection to the Austrian School certainly deserves further research, see Ancil (1994), Wohlgemuth (2006), and Audier (2012, pp. 399–508).

  23. 23.

    Einaudi (2006 [1931], pp. 78–79): “Freedom of the spirit, freedom of thought, cannot exist where there is and must be but a single will, a single creed, a single ideology. [...] Freedom of thought is therefore necessarily associated with a certain dose of economic liberalism [...] The spirit, if it is free, creates a varied economy in which there is coexistence of private property and the property of groups, bodies, state administration; coexistence of classes of industrialists, tradesmen, farmers, professionals, artists, different from each other, all of them drawing the material means of life from their own sources, capable of living in poverty, if necessary, but without having to beg for alms from a single power, be it the state, a tyrant, a dominant class, or a priesthood intolerant of any but the orthodox faith. In the free or liberal society, the individual, the family, the class, the group, the business concern, the charitable foundation, the school, the artisans’ or workers’ league must receive the consecration of legality from a supreme organ, called the state; but they must feel and believe they are living, and effectively live, their own lives coordinated with the lives of others but not submerged in the life of the collectivity and not dependent on the tolerance of the organ representing the collectivity.”

  24. 24.

    W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, February 11, 1944, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961): “I am so happy to hear that you will come here to Geneva in March or April, so that we could talk a little longer than we did in my short visit to you in Basel. In the meantime, the publisher will send you a copy of Civitas Humana which could serve as a basis for discussion.”

  25. 25.

    Röpke requested his friend’s assistance quite often: see, for example, W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, March 11, 1946, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters (1934–1961): “Could you please help me dealing with your son Giulio?”

  26. 26.

    See the invitation card in Einaudi-Rinascita Liberale Letters (1946–1947), AFLE, section 2, File “Rinascita Liberale.”

  27. 27.

    For the active partnership of Antoni and Röpke inside and outside the Mont Pèlerin Society, see Audier (2012, pp. 258–262, 336–337).

  28. 28.

    For the economic heritage of left-wing liberals and their Röpkean character, see Bonetti (2014, pp. 114–121). For Leoni’s libertarian philosophy, see Masala (2003).

  29. 29.

    In a letter dated September 18, 1961, Röpke confessed to Einaudi his disgust at the “intrigues inside our Mont Pèlerin Society,” adding that he decided to quit even though “the Assembly has rejected my resignation,” so he had to “reflect on the opportunity of coming back” (W. Röpke to L. Einaudi, September 18, 1961, in Einaudi-Röpke Letters [1934–1961]). More broadly on the history of the MPS, see Hartwell (1995) and Plickert (2008).

  30. 30.

    For a detailed analysis of Röpke’s anti-collectivist stand, see Solchany (2015, pp. 297–369).

  31. 31.

    See, for example, Röpke (1959b, pp. 234–235): “If man is to be restored to the possibility of simple, natural happiness, it can only be done by putting him once more in a humanly tolerable existence, where, placed in the true community that begins with the family and living in harmony with nature, he can support himself with labor made purposeful by the institution of private property. The almost desperate character of this effort does not testify against its necessity if we wish to save our civilization.”

  32. 32.

    For a brilliant exposition of the intellectual roots of the theory of mixed government, see Vile (1998, pp. 58–82).

  33. 33.

    See Burgin (2012, pp. 87–122) and Jackson (2012). Burgin pertinently observes that “like Walter Lippmann’s Inquiry into the Principles of the Good Society before the war, The Road to Serfdom was premised on a belief that one could engage in a vigorous critique of planning without rejecting government intervention altogether” (Burgin 2012, p. 90).

References

  • Ancil R (1994) Röpke and von Mises: the difference. Wilhelm Röpke Review 1(1):5–6

    Google Scholar 

  • Ancil R (1999) The romanticism of Wilhelm Röpke. Modern Age 41(3):199–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Antoni C (1959) La restaurazione del diritto di natura. Neri Pozza, Venice

    Google Scholar 

  • Audier S (2008) Le colloque Lippmann. Aux origines du néo-libéralisme. Éditions Le Bord de l’eau, Lormont

    Google Scholar 

  • Audier S (2012) Néo-libéralisme(s). Une archéologie intellectuelle. Grasset, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonefeld W (2012) Freedom and the strong state: on German ordoliberalism. New Polit Econ 17(5):633–656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonefeld W (2013) Adam Smith and ordoliberalism: on the political form of market liberty. Rev Int Stud 39(2):233–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonetti P (2014) Breve storia del liberalismo di sinistra. Liberilibri, Macerata

    Google Scholar 

  • Burgin A (2012) The great persuasion: reinventing free markets since the depression. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Busino G (1971) Luigi Einaudi e la Svizzera. Materiali per servire alla storia dei rapporti italo-svizzeri e alla biografia einaudiana. Annali della Fondazione Luigi Einaudi 5(1):351–422

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell W (1992) The legacy of Luigi Einaudi and Wilhelm Röpke. Modern Age 35(1):44–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Commun P (2014) German ordoliberalism: order vs. disorder in Röpke’s early works. Rivista I-Lex 9(21):27–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Commun P (2016) Les Ordolibéraux. Histoire d’un libéralisme à l’allemande. Les Belles Lettres, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Cressati C (1992) L’Europa necessaria. Il federalismo liberale di Luigi Einaudi. Giappichelli, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Croce B (1945) Discorsi di varia filosofia. Laterza, Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Croce B, Einaudi L (1988) Liberalismo e liberismo. Ricciardi, Milan-Naples

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Empoli D, Malandrino C, Zanone V (eds) (2014) Luigi Einaudi: selected political essays, vol 3. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • De Long JB (1990) In defense of Henry Simons’ standing as classical liberal. Cato J 9(3):601–618

    Google Scholar 

  • Denord F (2001) Aux origines du néo-libéralisme en France. Louis Rougier et le Colloque Walter Lippmann de 1938. Le Mouvement Social 195(2):9–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denord F (2007) Néo-libéralisme version française: Histoire d’une idéologie politique. Demopolis, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1920) Lettere politiche di Junius. Laterza, Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1931) Dei diversi significati del concetto di liberismo economico e dei suoi rapporti con quello di liberalismo. La Riforma Sociale 38(3–4):186–194. English edition: Einaudi L (2006) Economic liberalism and political liberalism. In: Einaudi L, Faucci R, Marchionatti R (eds) Luigi Einaudi selected economic essays, vol 1. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 73–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1933) Trincee economiche e corporativismo. La Riforma Sociale 40(6):633–656

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1934) La corporazione aperta. La Riforma Sociale 41(2):129–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1937a) Delle origini economiche della Grande Guerra, della crisi e delle diverse specie di piani. Rivista di storia economica 2(3):277–289

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1937b) Tema per gli storici dell’economia: dell’anacoretismo economico. Rivista di storia economica 2(2):186–195. Now in: Einaudi L (2011), pp 101–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1938) Miti e paradossi della giustizia tributaria. Einaudi, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1941a) Intorno al contenuto dei concetti di liberismo, comunismo, interventismo e simili. Argomenti 1(9):18–34. Now in: Einaudi L, Romano R (eds) (1973) Scritti economici, storici e civili. Mondadori, Milan, pp 278–303

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1941b) Ancora su le premesse del ragionamento economico. Rivista di storia economica 6(1):43–50. Reprinted in: Einaudi L, Romano R (eds) (1973) Scritti economici, storici e civili. Mondadori, Milan, pp 261–272

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1942) Dell’uomo, fine o mezzo, e dei beni d’ozio. Rivista di storia economica 7(3–4):117–130

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1943) Per una federazione economica europea. Movimento Liberale Italiano, Rome. Partially reprinted in: Einaudi L, Faucci R, Marchionatti R (eds) Luigi Einaudi: selected economic essays, pp 245–249 and pp 258–260

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1944) I problemi economici della federazione europea. Nuove edizioni di Capolago, Lugano. Partially reprinted in: Einaudi L, Faucci R, Marchionatti R (eds) Luigi Einaudi: selected economic essays, vol 1. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp 250–257

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1949 [1944b]) Lezioni di politica sociale. Einaudi, Turin. Partially reprinted in: Einaudi L, Faucci R, Marchionatti R (eds) Luigi Einaudi: selected economic essays, vol 1. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 39–65 and Da Empoli D, Malandrino C, Zanone V (2014) Luigi Einaudi: selected political essays: vol 3. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp 44–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1954 [1942b]) Economy of competition and historical capitalism. Scienza Nuova. Int J Rev Stud Psycho-Sociol Humanistic Sci 1(1): 1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1956) Lo scrittoio del Presidente 1948–1955. Einaudi, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1973) In: Rossi E (ed) Il Buongoverno. Saggi di economia e politica 1897–1954. Laterza, Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1987 [1961]) Le prediche della domenica. Einaudi, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (1997) In: Soddu P (ed) Diario dall’esilio (1943–44). Einaudi, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L (2011) In: Giordano A (ed) In lode del profitto e altri scritti. IBL Libri, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L, Faucci R, Marchionatti R (eds) (2006) Luigi Einaudi: selected economic writings. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Einaudi L, Rossi E (1986) In: Busino G, Martinotti Dorigo S (eds) Carteggio (1925–1961). Fondazione Luigi Einaudi, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Faucci R (1986) Luigi Einaudi. Utet, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Forte F (2016) Einaudi versus Keynes. Due grandi del Novecento e la crisi dei nostri giorni. IBL Libri, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Foucault M (2010 [1979]) The birth of biopolitics: lectures at the Collège de France, 1978–1979. Picador, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Galston W (1988) Liberal virtues. Am Polit Sci Rev 82(4):1277–1290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentile P (1945) Il liberalismo di Marx. La Città Libera 1(14):7–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Gentile P (1953) La terza via. Corriere della Sera, February 11, 1953

    Google Scholar 

  • Giordano A (2006) Il pensiero politico di Luigi Einaudi. Name edizioni, Genoa

    Google Scholar 

  • Giordano A (2010) Contro il regime. Panfilo Gentile e l’opposizione liberale alla partitocrazia (1945–1970). Rubbettino, Soveria Mannelli

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldschmidt N, Rauchenschwandtner H (2007) The philosophy of Social Market Economy: Michel Foucault’s analysis of ordoliberalism. Discussion Paper 07/04, Walter Eucken Institut, Freiburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin CD (2014) Walter Lippmann: public economist. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gregg S (2010) Wilhelm Röpke’s political economy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hartwell R (1995) A history of the Mont Pèlerin Society. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1992) The fortunes of liberalism. Essays on Austrian economics and the ideal of freedom. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (2006 [1944]) The road to serfdom. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennecke HJ (2005) Wilhelm Röpke. Ein Leben in der Brandung. Schäffer-Poeschel, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirk R (1985 [1953]) The conservative mind: from Burke to Eliot. Henry Regnery, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Köhler EA, Kolev S (2011) The conjoint quest for a liberal positive program: “Old Chicago”, Freiburg and Hayek. HWWI Research Paper 109, Hamburg Institute of International Economics, Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolev S (2013) Neoliberale Staatsverständnisse im Vergleich. Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lippmann W (1944 [1937]) The good society. Billing and Sons, Guildford

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson B (2010) At the origins of neo-liberalism: The free economy and the strong state, 1930–1947. Historical J 53(1):129–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson B (2012) Freedom, the common good, and the rule of law: Lippmann and Hayek on economic planning. J Hist Ideas 73(1):47–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masala A (2003) Il liberalismo di Bruno Leoni. Rubbettino, Soveria Mannelli

    Google Scholar 

  • Masala A (2012) Crisi e rinascita del liberalismo classico. ETS, Pisa

    Google Scholar 

  • Mierzejewski AC (2006) Water in the desert? The influence of Wilhelm Röpke on Ludwig Erhard and the Social Market Economy. Rev Austrian Econ 19(4):275–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski P, Plehwe D (eds) (2009) The road from Mont Pèlerin. The making of the neoliberal thought collective. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Molina Cano J (2001) La tercera vía en Wilhelm Röpke. Instituto Empresa y Humanismo, Navarra

    Google Scholar 

  • Morelli U (1990) Contro il mito dello stato sovrano. Luigi Einaudi e l’unità europea. Franco Angeli, Milan

    Google Scholar 

  • Nichols AJ (1994) Freedom with responsibility: the Social Market Economy in Germany 1918–1963. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Peacock A, Willgerodt H (eds) (1989) German neo-liberals and the Social Market Economy. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Peukert H (1992) Das sozialökonomische Werk Wilhelm Röpkes. Peter Lang, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Plickert P (2008) Wandlungen des Neoliberalismus: Eine Studie zu Entwicklung und Ausstrahlung der “Mont Pèlerin Society”. Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Resico M (2008) La estructura de una economía humana. Reflexiones en cuanto a la actualidad de W. Röpke. Universidad Católica Argentina, Buenos Aires

    Google Scholar 

  • Resico M (2009) La téoria del ciclo económico de W. Röpke. Anales de la Asociation Argentina de Economia Politica, Buenos Aires

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1936) Crises and cycles. William Hodge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1942 [1939]) International economic disintegration. William Hodge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1948 [1944]) Civitas Humana: a humane order of society. William Hodge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1950 [1942a]) The social crisis of our time. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1959a [1945]) International order and economic integration. D. Reidel, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1959b) The necessity of economic freedom. Modern Age 3(3):227–236

    Google Scholar 

  • Röpke W (1963 [1937]) Economics of the free society. Henry Regnery, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild E (2001) Economic sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet and the Enlightenment. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Rougier L (1939) Les mystiques économiques. Éditions de Médicis, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Rüstow A (1932) Freie Wirtschaft – Starker Staat. In: Boese F (ed) Deutschland und die Weltkrise. Verhandlungen des Vereins für Socialpolitik in Dresden 1932. Duncker & Humblot, Munich, pp 62–67. Reprinted in: Wünsche H (ed) (1982) Standard texts on the Social Market Economy. Gustav Fischer, Stuttgart, pp 37–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Rüstow A (1942) Appendix. In: Röpke W (1942b [1939]) International economic disintegration. William Hodge, London, pp 267–283

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulz-Forberg H, Olsen N (eds) (2014) Re-inventing Western civilisation: transnational reconstructions of liberalism in Europe in the twentieth century. Cambridge Scholars Publishing, Newcastle upon Tyne

    Google Scholar 

  • Simons H (1934) A positive program for laissez faire: some proposals for a liberal economic policy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Reprinted in: Simons H (1948) Economic policy for a free society. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 40–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Simons H (1948) Economic policy for a free society. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Solchany J (2014) Wilhelm Röpke as a key actor of transnational neoliberalism after 1945. In: Schulz-Forberg H, Olsen N (eds) Re-inventing Western civilisation: transnational reconstructions of liberalism in Europe in the twentieth century. Cambridge Scholars Publishing, Newcastle upon Tyne, pp 95–116

    Google Scholar 

  • Solchany J (2015) Wilhelm Röpke, l’autre Hayek. Aux origines du néolibéralisme. Publications de la Sorbonne, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Somma A (2014) La Germania e l’economia sociale di mercato. 1. Da Weimar ad Helmut Schmidt. Centro di Ricerca e Documentazione Luigi Einaudi, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorin Muresanu S (2014) Social Market Economy: the case of Germany. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Vile MJC (1998) Constitutionalism and the separation of powers. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis

    Google Scholar 

  • Winch D (1978) Adam Smith’s politics: an essay on historiographic revision. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgemuth M (2006) L’influence de l’économie autrichienne sur le libéralisme allemand. In: Nemo P, Petitot J (eds) Histoire du libéralisme en Europe. PUF, Paris, pp 985–1030

    Google Scholar 

  • Wünsche H (ed) (1982) Standard texts on the Social Market Economy. Gustav Fischer, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Zmirak J (2001) Wilhelm Röpke: Swiss localist, global economist. ISI Books, Wilmington

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alberto Giordano .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Giordano, A. (2018). The Making of the “Third Way”: Wilhelm Röpke, Luigi Einaudi, and the Identity of Neoliberalism. In: Commun, P., Kolev, S. (eds) Wilhelm Röpke (1899–1966). The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences, vol 20. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-68357-7_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics