Skip to main content

Why is Italy Disproportionally Corrupt?: A Conjecture

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Institutions, Governance and the Control of Corruption

Part of the book series: International Economic Association Series ((IEA))

Abstract

Different indicators show that Italy is an outlier in terms of corruption. As developed a country as Italy should have a much lower level of corruption. All the factors scholars have found to be affecting corruption fail to explain this puzzle. I start instead from the assumption that corrupt exchanges thrive when parties can trust each other both to comply with their obligations and not to snitch. Could Italians enjoy a greater ability to cooperate successfully in illegal markets, and could this ability to make their illegal pacts stick explain their anomalous propensity at striking corrupt deals? One could think of mafia enforcement, which certainly helps. Yet, corruption occurs also outside the regions with heavy mafia presence—it seems rather a white-collar affair in which threats are unnecessary and no blood is spilt. I consider a special bonding mechanism, the sharing of compromising information (SCI), and—relying on evidence from case studies and an experiment—I illustrate how SCI works in bringing about cooperation in other illegal markets. But why should Italians be in a better position to rely on SCI to pursue their corrupt deals? The answer, I contend, lies in the peculiarity of Italy’s judicial system, which is at once inefficient yet independent, and jointly these features make it exploitable by villains as a cheap, reliable and unwitting enforcing mechanism for their deals.

Corruptissima republica, plurimae leges

Tacitus, Annals, III, 27

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Daniel Treisman points out that: “Italy’s corruption rating fell sharply—by more than one and a half points on the Transparency International Index—between the early and mid-1990s, possibly because of the public outrage and judicial campaign against political corruption. But, for its level of economic development, democracy and openness to trade, Italy before these changes had an abnormally high corruption rating” (2000: 441–442, my italics). In that short period of time the judiciary came down the hardest on political corruption in an operation known as “Mani Pulite”, causing a positive blip in the index; but since then matters have gone back to … abnormal.

  2. 2.

    For a comprehensive account see Vannucci 2012, esp. Chap. 3.

  3. 3.

    A new index, based on corruption cases prosecuted in one country but which occurred in a different country, proposed by Saarni Escresa and Lucio Picci, gives some evidence that the CPI may make Italian corruption seem worse than it is (2017).

  4. 4.

    An interesting bias in corruption beliefs is revealed by Olken (2009: 951): “Villagers in more ethnically heterogeneous villages are less likely to report trusting their fellow villagers, and more likely to attend project monitoring meetings, than those in homogeneous villages, which may explain why there is greater perceived corruption in heterogeneous villages but lower missing expenditures.”

  5. 5.

    A different bias is mentioned by Treisman: “It is possible that the ratings we have been analysing measure not corruption itself but guesses about its extent in particular countries that experts or survey respondents have derived by applying conventional theories about corruption’s causes, the same conventional theories that inform the hypotheses of researchers, which turn out—surprise!—to fit the data well. Believing democracy reduces corruption, the experts give high grades to democracies; researchers then discover that democracy predicts a low corruption rating” (2007: 32). Paradoxically, if this were the reason why we cannot rely on these indexes, then the Italian case should be reassuring for these variables that explain corruption levels elsewhere, do not explain the Italian case well.

  6. 6.

    The results also confirm Chile as a positive anomaly, but not Uruguay, which is on the expected line.

  7. 7.

    See, for example, http://espresso.repubblica.it/inchieste/2014/06/09/news/confessate-a-milano-tangenti-per-tre-milioni-1.168631; http://corrieredelveneto.corriere.it/veneto/notizie/cronaca/2016/13-aprile-2016/tangenti-mose-via-processo-gli-imputati-matteoli-orsoni-240299413428.shtml; www.ilfattoquotidiano.it/2015/12/21/mose-a-giudizio-il-sistema-delle-tangenti-processo-per-lex-ministro-fi-matteoli-e-lex-sindaco-orsoni/2324332/.

  8. 8.

    χ2(1) = 29.07, p < 0.001.

  9. 9.

    39% vs 63%: χ2(1) = 18.75, p < 0.001; 39% vs 23%: χ2(1) = 8.52, p = 0.004.

  10. 10.

    χ2(1) = 4.58, p = 0.032.

  11. 11.

    χ2(1) = 4.13, p = 0.042.

  12. 12.

    www.diritto.it/articoli/penale/chiaia.html.

  13. 13.

    http://firenze.repubblica.it/cronaca/2016/09/22/news/lastra_a_signa_il_pm_azzera_l_ufficio_tecnico_del_comune-148260467/.

  14. 14.

    The value of concentrating on preventing small acts of deviancy rests on different and deeper reasons, illustrated by evidence coming from neuroscience: “Behaviorally, we show that the extent to which participants engage in self-serving dishonesty increases with repetition. Using functional MRI, we show that signal reduction in the amygdala is sensitive to the history of dishonest behavior, consistent with adaptation. Critically, the extent of reduced amygdala sensitivity to dishonesty on a present decision relative to the previous one predicts the magnitude of escalation of self-serving dishonesty on the next decision. The findings uncover a biological mechanism that supports a ‘slippery slope’: what begins as small acts of dishonesty can escalate into larger transgressions” (Garrett et al. 2016: 1727).

References

  • Barr, Abigail, and Danila Serra. 2010. Corruption and Culture: An Experimental Analysis. Journal of Public Economics 94: 862–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosworth, Richard J.B. 2006. Mussolini’s Italy: Life Under the Dictatorship. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • CEPEJ. 2014. Study on the Functioning of Judicial Systems in the EU Member States, Facts and Figures from the CEPEJ 2012–2014 Evaluation Exercise. European Commission for the efficiency of justice. http://ec.europa.eu/justice/effective-justice/files/cepj_study_scoreboard_2014_en.pdf

  • Charron, Nicholas. 2016. Do Corruption Measures Have a Perception Problem? Assessing the Relationship Between Experiences and Perceptions of Corruption Among Citizens and Experts. European Political Science Review 8: 147–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Escresa, Laarni, and Lucio Picci. 2017. A New Cross-National Measure of Corruption. The World Bank Economic Review: 31(1): 196–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, Raymond, and Edward Miguel. 2007. Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement: Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets. Journal of Political Economy 115: 1020–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flashman, Jennifer, and Diego Gambetta. 2014. Thick as thieves: Homophily and Trust among Deviants. Rationality and Society 26: 3–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambetta, Diego. 1993. The Sicilian Mafia: An Industry of Private Protection. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009a. Codes of the Underworld. How Criminals Communicate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. “Response” to ‘Roundtable on Codes of the Underworld. Global Crime 12: 150–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambetta, Diego, and Wojtek Przepiorka. 2016. Sharing Compromising Information: How ‘Crime’ Begets Cooperation in the Lab. Unpublished manuscript, European University Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, Neil, Stephanie C. Lazzaro, Dan Ariely, and Tali Sharot. 2016. The Brain Adapts to Dishonesty. Nature Neuroscience 19: 1727–1732.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hiaasen, Carl. 1995. Stormy Weather. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledeneva, Alena. 2006. How Russia Really Works: The Informal Practices That Shaped Post-Soviets Politics And Business. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olken, Benjamin A. 2009. Corruption Perceptions vs. Corruption Reality. Journal of Public Economics 93: 950–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quality of Government Institute. 2010. Measuring the Quality of Government and Subnational Variation. Report for the European Commission Directorate-General Regional Policy Directorate Policy Development, Department of Political Science, University of Gothenburg, Sweden.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramseyer, J. Mark, and Eric Rasmusen. 2010. Comparative Litigation Rates. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Law School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Razafindrakoto, Mirelle, and François Roubaud. 2010. Are International Databases on Corruption Reliable? A Comparison of Expert Opinion Surveys and Household Surveys in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Development 38: 1057–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricciuti, Roberto, and Ilaria Petrarca. 2013. The Historical Economics of Corruption and Development Within Italy. International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance 6: 186–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, Thomas. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tivelli, Luigi. 2006. La fiera delle leggi. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, Daniel. 2000. The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study. Journal of Public Economics 76: 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2007. What Have We Learned About the Causes of Corruption from Ten Years of Cross-National Empirical Research? Annual Review of Political Science 10: 211–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vannucci, Alberto. 2012. Atlante della corruzione. Torino: Edizioni Gruppo Abele.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Valeria Pizzini Gambetta and Alberto Vannucci—as well as Avinash Dixit, Juan Dubra, Frank Fukuyama, Francesca Recanatini and the other participants in the IEA Roundtable—for their comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Diego Gambetta .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gambetta, D. (2018). Why is Italy Disproportionally Corrupt?: A Conjecture. In: Basu, K., Cordella, T. (eds) Institutions, Governance and the Control of Corruption. International Economic Association Series. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-65684-7_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-65684-7_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-73822-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-65684-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics