Skip to main content

Innovation Policies: Strategy of Growth in a Complex Perspective

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Social Dynamics in a Systems Perspective

Part of the book series: New Economic Windows ((NEW))

  • 1157 Accesses

Abstract

The aim of this chapter is to highlight new understandings of innovation as an interactive process in relation to economic growth. The resulting ideas could be of considerable interest to innovation policy makers. Two impacts are of considerable potential importance. The first relates to the absorption of complex and evolutionary systems dynamics ideas into the study of innovation, and growth. The second relates to the synthesis of complex systems ideas with evolutionary models of innovation, and growth. Considering innovation as a complex multi-level process means that it is not possible to devise the context into independent ways and that it is not enough to provide policymakers with simple solutions, but it should help them formulate and address questions that are appropriate to the evolutionary and complex context within which they operate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Adam Smith did recognize the great importance of science and technology, even if List (1841) had strongly criticized him and other classical economists for what he perceived as their neglect of technology and skills, that’s they did not consistently give it the prominence which List thought that it merited (Freeman 2002).

  2. 2.

    This issue was explored in detail in Lane and Maxfield (1997, 2005).

  3. 3.

    See also Barile (2000, 2008, 2009), Golinelli (2000, 2005, 2010), Barile et al. (2012).

  4. 4.

    Principle of system hierarchy.

  5. 5.

    For a firm the trajectory is determined by large-scale, often global, trends in demand and technological opportunity which are usually uncertain and at best involve risk for the firms.

  6. 6.

    See Innovation and Research Strategy for Growth BIS economic paper n.15 dic 2011.

  7. 7.

    New Growth Theory (NGT) is the view that technological change is essentially an economic phenomenon, or at least explicable in economic terms. Furthermore, the mechanics of economic growth emphasized by NOT captures the traditional idea of uneven growth: some sectors generate more economic growth than others, for example through the creation of new knowledge.

  8. 8.

    In the 1991 the World Bank in our report has established that “it is intangible investment in knowledge accumulation, which is decisive in the economic growth rather than physical capital investment” (Freeman 2002).

  9. 9.

    Nelson and others have pointed to the complementarity of all these variables. “The contribution of capital accumulation to growth depends not only on its quantity but on its quality, on the direction of investment, on the skills of entrepreneurs and the labour Force in the exploitation of new investment, on the presence (or absence) of social overhead capital and so forth (Freeman 2002).

  10. 10.

    In short when economics are out of equilibrium they stay out of equilibrium. But they always exhibit order and that order reflects, and might be measured in terms of processes of interaction and the patterns of co-ordination that ensue.

  11. 11.

    “The origins of the systems concept, applied to innovation, lie in the concept of national systems of innovation (Freeman 1987; Nelson 1988; Ludvall 1992). The concept emerged as an alternative way to explain the innovation process, improving on an earlier view that considered this process as a simple linear progression of scientific research” (Iizuka 2013, p. 2).

  12. 12.

    “Innovation is thus the result of a complex interaction between various actors and institutions. Technical change does not occur in a perfectly linear sequence, but through feedback loops within this system. In the centre of this system are the firms, the way they organise production and innovation and the channels by which they gain access to external sources of knowledge. These sources might be other firms, public and private research institutes, universities or transfer institutions—regional, national or international. Here, the innovative firm is seen as operating within a complex network of co-operating and competing firms and other institutions, building on a range of joint ventures and close linkages with suppliers and customers” (OECD 1997, p. 12).

  13. 13.

    For a deep overview see Shulin (1999).

References

  • Aghion, P. (2005). Handbook of economic growth theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (2009). The economics of growth theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Archibugi, D. (2000). The globalisation of technology and the European innovation system, Prepared as part of the project “Innovation Policy in a Knowledge-Based Economy” Commissioned by the European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barile, S. (Ed.). (2000). Contributi sul pensiero sistemico. Salerno: Arnia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barile, S. (2008). L’impresa come Sistema – Contributi sull’Approccio Sistemico Vitale (II ed.). Torino: Giappichelli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barile, S. (2009). Management Sistemico Vitale. Torino: Giappichelli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barile, S., Polese, F., & Saviano, M. (2012). Immaginare L’Innovazione. Giappichelli Ed, Torino.

    Google Scholar 

  • BIS-Department for Business Innovation and Skills. (2011). Innovation and research strategy for growth. BIS Economics Paper, no. 15. http://bis.gov.uk/innovatingforgrowth

  • Etzkowitz, H., & Leydersdoff, L. (2000). The dynamics of innovation: From national systems and “Mode 2” to a triple helix of University-Industry-Government relations. Research Policy, 29, 109–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, M. M. (2002). A systemic approach to innovation in regional development reconsidered Part A (pp. 15–31). Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C. (1987). Technology and economic performance: Lessons from Japan. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C. (2002). Continental, national and sub-national innovation systems-complementarities and economic growth. Research Policy, 31, 191–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenken, K. (2016). A complexity-theoretic perspective on innovation policy (ISU Working Paper #16.01).

    Google Scholar 

  • Golinelli, G. M. (2000). L’approccio Sistemico al Governo dell’Impresa – L’Impresa Sistema Vitale (I ed.). Padova: CEDAM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golinelli, G. M. (2005). L’approccio Sistemico al Governo dell’Impresa. – L’Impresa Sistema Vitale (II ed.). Padova: CEDAM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golinelli, G. M. (2010). Viable systems approach (VSA). Governing business dynamics. Padova: Kluwer CEDAM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iizuka, M.. (2013). Innovation systems framework: Still useful in the new global context? (UNU-MERIT Working Papers 2013-005).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kline, S., & Rosenberg, N. (1986). An overview of innovation. In Landau et al. (Eds.), The positive sum strategy. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, D. A., & Maxfield, R. (1997). Foresight complexity and strategy. In W. B. Arthur, S. Durlauf, & D. A. Lane (Eds.), The economy as an evolving complex system II. Redwood City, CA: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, D. A., & Maxfield, R. (2005). Ontological uncertainty and innovation. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 6, 43–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, F. (1841). The national system of political economy (S. Sampson & M.P. Lloyd, Trans., 1885 ed., Fourth Book, “The politics”, Chapter 33).

    Google Scholar 

  • Llerena, P., & Matt, M. (1999). Technological cooperation and dynamic performance of industries: Towards an evolutionary foundation of technology policies. Communication to European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics 7–9 June, Grenoble, France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ludvall, B.-Å. (Ed.). (1992). National systems of innovation and interactive learning. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mani, S. (2001). Role of government in promoting innovation, an international comparative study. In Paper presented to the Conference “The Future of Innovation Studies Eidhoven University of Technology, The Netherlands 20–23 September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. S. (1994). Evolution, technology, policy and technology management. Prometheus, 12, 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, S. (1995). The Economic foundations of technology policy: Equilibrium and evolutionary perspectives. In P. Stoneman (Ed.), Handbook of the economics of innovation and technological change. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. S., Fonseca, M. D., & Ramlogan, R. (2000). Innovation, growth and competition: ESRC Centre for research on innovation & competition. In Paper prepared for the Complexity and Complex Systems in Industry Conference 19th 20th September, University of Warwick.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1988). Institutions supporting technical change in the United States. In G. Dosi, C. Freemann, R. R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, & L. Soete (Eds.), Technical change and economic theory (pp. 312–329). London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Nelson, K. (2002). Technology, institutions, and innovation systems. Research Policy, 31, 265–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1997). National Innovation Policy. Paris: OECD. https://www.oecd.org/science/inno/2101733.pdf

  • Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shulin, G. (1999). Implication of National Innovation Systems for developing countries managing change and complexity in economic development (UNU/INTECH Discussion Papers ISSN 1564-8370).

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith K., (1991). Innovation policy in an evolutionary context. In J. S. Metcalfe (Ed.), Evolutionary theories of economic and technological change. London: Harwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Robert M. Solow. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen, B. (2001). Economic growth and technological change: An evolutionary interpretation (OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, No. 2001/01). Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marisa Faggini .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bruno, B., Faggini, M., Parziale, A. (2018). Innovation Policies: Strategy of Growth in a Complex Perspective. In: Barile, S., Pellicano, M., Polese, F. (eds) Social Dynamics in a Systems Perspective. New Economic Windows. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-61967-5_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics