Skip to main content

Investment, Unemployment and the Cyber Revolution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: International Papers in Political Economy ((IPPE))

Abstract

Internet and mobile technologies have brought many benefits, including productivity rises, more effective co-ordination of economic and financial activities, and new market opportunities. However, negative impacts are often ignored. Labour productivity, wages and life satisfaction may decline if workers struggle with, or are replaced by, new technologies. Online social networks, easily accessible via mobile technologies, create opportunities for distractions and shirking at work. Automation of an increasing range of jobs dampens labour demand and accelerates substitution of capital for labour. This chapter explores one facet of potential implications, specifically the impacts on long-term unemployment, as a proxy for secular stagnation. Relationships between gross fixed capital formation, computing investment and long-term unemployment for 17 OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) countries over the period 2000–2010 are analysed using panel estimation techniques. The findings suggest that increases in computing investment are associated with rises in long-term unemployment. The chapter concludes with an analysis of policy implications and potential solutions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Details were publicised in the news, e.g. see https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2005/may/16/media.business

  2. 2.

    Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis, Contributions to Real GDP for Final Sales of Computers, Software, and Communications Equipment, Prices and Output for Information and Communication Technologies, US Department of Commerce. Available at: www.bea.gov/iTable/iTable.cfm?reqid=12&step=3&isuri=1&1203=2079#reqid=12&step=3&isuri=1&1203=2079. Available at: www.bea.gov/iTable/iTable.cfm?reqid=12&step=3&isuri=1&1203=2079#reqid=12&step=3&isuri=1&1203=2079.

  3. 3.

    Chamley (2003) provides an overview of Bayes’s rational herding models.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (1993). Learning about others’ actions and the investment accelerator. Economic Journal, 103, 318–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baddeley, M. C. (2002). Investment in an uncertain world. Zagreb International Review of Economics and Business, 5(2), 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baddeley, M. (2003). Investment: Theories and analysis. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baddeley, M. (2004). Using e-cash in the new economy: An economic analysis of micropayments systems. Journal of Electronic Commerce Research, 5(4), 239–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baddeley, M. (2008). Structural shifts in UK unemployment: The twin impacts of financial deregulation and computerisation. Bulletin of Economic Research, 60(2), 123–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baddeley, M., & Fontana, G. (2006). Monetary policy in the information economy: Old problems and new challenges. In P. Arestis, M. Baddeley, & J. McCombie (Eds.), New’ monetary policy: Implications and relevance. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. (1992). A simple model of herd behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(3), 797–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu, S., Fernald, J. G., Oulton, N., & Srinivasan, S. (2003). The case of the missing productivity growth: Or, does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the US but not the UK (NBER Working Paper Series, No. 10010). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A theory of fads, fashions, custom and cultural change as informational cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 100(5), 992–1026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebczuk, R. N. (2003). Asymmetric information in financial markets: Introduction and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackett Review. (2015). FinTech futures – The UK as a world leader in financial technologies: A report by the UK government chief scientific adviser. London: UK Government Office for Science (GO-Science).

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrado, C., & Slifman, L. (1999). The reliability of aggregate statistics: Decomposition of productivity and unit costs. American Economic Review, 89(2), 328–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassells, R. (2017). Happy workers: How satisfied are Australians at work? Bentley: Curtin Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cecchetti, S. G. (2002). The new economy and challenges for macroeconomic policy (NBER Working Papers Series, No. 8935). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamley, C. P. (2003). Rational herds – Economic models of social learning. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Darby, M. R., & Zucker, L. G. (2002). Going public when you can in biotechnology (NBER Working Paper Series, No. 8954). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, P. (1995). Uncertainty in economics. In S. Dow & S. Hillard (Eds.), Keynes, knowledge and uncertainty (pp. 107–116). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. B. (1997). J.M. Keynes on history and convention. In G. C. Harcourt & P. A. Riach (Eds.), A ‘second edition’ of the general theory. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. B. (1998). Davidson, non-ergodicity and individuals. In P. Arestis (Ed.), Methodology, theory and policy in Keynes: Essays in honour of Paul Davidson (Vol. 3, pp. 1–16). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • DeLong, J. B., & Summers, L. H. (2001). The ‘new economy’: Background, historical perspective, questions and speculations. In Economic Policy of the Information Economy, Proceedings of the Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (pp. 11–46).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. K., & Pindyck, R. S. (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dockery, M. (2003). Happiness, life satisfaction, and the role of work: Evidence from two Australian surveys. Curtin Business: School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, T. (1991). Technology usage in US manufacturing industries. Washington, DC: US Census Economic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., Kanniainen, V., & Mustonen, M. (2002). Innovation of network goods: A non-innovating firm will gain (CESifo Working Paper Series, No. 692). Munich: Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute for Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. J. (2000). Does the “new economy” measure up to the great inventions- of the past? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 49–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gowrisankaran, G., & Stevens, J. (2002). Network externalities and technology adoption: Lessons from electronic payments (BER NBER Working Paper Series, No. 8943). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of R&D to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobjin, B., & Jovanovic, B. (2001). The information technology revolution and the stock market: Evidence. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1203–1220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W. (1963). Capital theory and investment behavior. American Economic Review, 53, 247–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W., & Stiroh, K. J. (2000). Raising the speed limit: U.S. economic growth in the information age. New York: Mimeo/Harvard University and Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., & Shapiro, C. (1986). Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 822–841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes J. M. (1930). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren. Essays in persuasion (pp. 358–373). New York: W.W.Norton & Co., 1963. Available at http://www.econ.yale.edu/smith/econ116a/keynes1.pdf

  • Keynes, J. M. (1937). The general theory of employment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51, 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landefeld, J. S., & Fraumeni, B. M. (2000). Measuring the new economy. Bureau of Economic Analysis, Advisory Committee Meeting.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (2011). Happiness: Lessons from a new science (2nd ed.). London: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, M. M., & Quiros, G. B. (2000). Output fluctuations in the United States: What has changed since the early 1980s? American Economic Review, 90, 1464–1476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mensch, G. O. (1979). Stalemate in technology: Innovations overcome the depressions. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell, G., Deaton, A., Durand, M., Halpern, D., & Layard, R. (2014). Wellbeing and policy. London: Legatum Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2015). Digital economy outlook. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oswald, A., Proto, E., & Sgroi, D. (2015). Happiness and productivity. Journal of Labor Economics, 33(4), 789–822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roach, S. S. (1998). The boom for whom: Revisiting America’s technology paradox. New York: Morgan Stanley Dean Witter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowlatt, A., Clayton, T., & Vaze, P. (2002). Where, and how, to look for the new economy. Economic Trends, 580, 29–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1911). Theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles: A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1987, July 12). We’d better watch out. New York Times, Book Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spencer, P. (2002). The impact of information and communications technology investment on UK productive potential 1986–2000: New statistical methods and tests. The Manchester School Supplement, 70, 107–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Temple, J. (2002). New economy – An assessment. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 18(3), 241–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Topol, R. (1991). Bubbles and volatility of stock prices: Effect of mimetic contagion. Economic Journal, 101(406), 786–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watts, D. J. (2004). Small worlds – The dynamics of networks between order and randomness (Princeton studies in complexity). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts, D. J., & Strogatz, S. H. (1998). Collective dynamics of “small-world” networks. Nature, CCCLXXXXIII, 440–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, K. (2002). Computers, obsolescence and productivity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(3), 445–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2016). Digital dividends –– Overview. World Bank Development Report 2016. Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, S., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2001). Intangible assets and growth accounting: Evidence from computer investments. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Available at http://ebusiness.mit.edu/erik/itg01-05-30.pdf

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Data sources (2000–2010), 17 countries: Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France , Germany , Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Spain , Sweden , Switzerland, the UK and the USA .

All data downloaded from the OECD database:

Long-term unemployment

Unemployment of 6 months or more, as a proportion of total unemployment .

Calculated from OECD labour market data on unemployment duration.

Source: OECD database.

https://data.oecd.org/unemp/long-term-unemployment -rate.htm

ICT investment

Measured as a proportion of total investment .

Source: OECD database

https://data.oecd.org/ict/ict-investment .htm

Gross fixed capital formation

Gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) measured as growth rate.

Source: OECD database, Investment (GFCF)

https://data.oecd.org/gdp/investment-gfcf.htm (indicator). doi: 10.1787/b6793677-en

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Baddeley, M. (2017). Investment, Unemployment and the Cyber Revolution. In: Arestis, P., Sawyer, M. (eds) Economic Policies since the Global Financial Crisis. International Papers in Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-60459-6_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-60459-6_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-60458-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-60459-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics