Skip to main content

Banking

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Macroeconomics in Ecological Context

Part of the book series: Studies in Ecological Economics ((SEEC,volume 5))

  • 766 Accesses

Abstract

The mill parable of Chap. 9 was a device to get at the essence of money as a credible promise. But to understand how money works more realistically, we have to look at how banks work. We start with how a checking account functions, which leads us to the bank balance sheet. The balance sheet in turn sets up how money is actually created by banks (as opposed to how it’s created by entrepreneurs building water mills in fictional villages growing homogenous food). The balance sheet raises the issue of banks’ need for credibility and how they establish that. The role of the central bank grows out of this need for credibility, and ranges from regulation of banks to acting as a lender of last resort for them. The chapter ends with a brief discussion of fractional-reserve banking.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For simplicity, we’re setting aside the value of the vault itself, and the building the vault is in, etc.

  2. 2.

    An interesting recent explanation of this process is from the Bank of England, at [1].

  3. 3.

    This is the U.S. structure in particular and will be covered in more detail in Chap. 12 Other countries have similar systems with minor differences.

  4. 4.

    During the financial crisis following the market meltdown of 2008, the Federal Reserve has sometimes paid positive interest on reserves, ostensibly as a way of keeping the banks healthy. There have been proposals that it should actually do the opposite, charge interest (or pay negative interest) as a way of encouraging banks to make more loans rather than sitting on their reserves.

  5. 5.

    In the U.S., a bank that is part of the Federal Reserve system has a reserve requirement: there’s a minimum amount of reserves it has to have, defined in relation to the total deposits on their balance sheets. In Canada, on the other hand, there is no minimum requirement; it is left to the banks to determine the quantity of reserves they need in order to function reliably.

  6. 6.

    This is only good up to a certain limit. As of August, 2014, the FDIC “insured limit” is $250,000 per depositor per bank. If you have an account balance of less than $250,000, you’ll get all your money back. If you have an account of more than $250,000, you’ll get $250,000 back. If you want to protect more than $250,000, you can have accounts at more than one bank.

  7. 7.

    There is a caveat to this point, which is that if a bank knows that it’s insured, it also knows it can take greater risks in its efforts to earn higher interest earnings. In theory, without insurance a bank has to worry about risky loans, because if depositors see it making too many risky loans, they won’t want to be depositors anymore, and the bank will fail. In practice, many households may not be good judges of how much risk a bank is running—the people who work at the bank are supposedly experts at judging such risks, whereas almost all of the depositors are experts at something else, but not at assessing risks. And on top of that, when a bank is part of FDIC, they don’t just pay insurance premiums, they also submit to regulation of what kinds of loans they can make, so as to limit the riskiness of their portfolios.

  8. 8.

    The following discussion will focus on the U.S. system with the Federal Reserve. The details are different in other countries, but the core functions and operations are similar.

  9. 9.

    This relationship between taxes and money is at the core of “Chartalism”; see, e.g., [2].

References

  1. McLeay, M., Radia, A. & Thomas, R. (2014). Money creation in the modern economy. Quarterly Bulletin, Q1, 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Tcherneva, P. R. (2006). Chartalism and the tax-driven approach to money. In P. Arestis & M. Sawyer (Eds.), Handbook of alternative monetary economics (pp. 69–86). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Seeley, K. (2017). Banking. In: Macroeconomics in Ecological Context. Studies in Ecological Economics, vol 5. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-51757-5_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics