Skip to main content

The Reinvention of Development

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Reinventing Development
  • 203 Accesses

Abstract

The chapter starts with a recapitulation of the main arguments: first, that the facts of development are usually highly aggregative, have a strong tendency to encourage thinking that development is one dimensional, and coexist with a parallel set of facts of development, equally easy to access, that argues that thinking in this way obscures reality and risks denying voice to poor people or others. Second, that the social epistemologies that give meaning to these facts are: sectarian, in the sense that we find a range of differing belief sets, each of which asserts that it is true, in a world of multiple truths; they are located within historical habits of believing in metaphorical accounts of social change that are essentialist; such metaphorical accounts contrast with those in a natural science method; official aid practice, as shown by bilateral donors and the DAC umbrella, requires interventions to assume, in the name of formal accountability, that cause–effect relations are predictively known, and this is expressed in the techniques of the log-frame. The knowledge deployed in this official aid practice is, however, metaphorical rather than predictive.

The chapter then looks at the conflict between classic and radical social epistemologies. Under such conditions, considerable tensions arguably exist between what important social epistemologies say is the case and what is experienced. The conflict is political, in the sense that mainstream social epistemology, believing in predictively known cause–effect relationships embodied in log-frames, is endorsed by various agencies—donors—whose principals are the elected governments to which they themselves are accountable. Then, it recapitulates the reinvention of development—the conservative and radical responses. The conservative approach, expressed through theories of change, allows asserted predictive knowledge of cause–effect relationships to continue to play a central role in the organisation of development. It allows for horizontal inconsistency, in that different aid projects and other interventions can now more easily have mutually inconsistent cause–effect relationships built into them. But it requires that each intervention has just one such notion. The radical approach addresses directly the possibility that cause–effect relations in social change are not (perhaps for the moment) predictively known. It allows for people to choose to believe this. The chapter discusses how the focus of the book has been upon a case study—contemporary mainstream ways of organising international development interventions—and also on how the industry of official aid works and the social epistemologies embedded in it. These epistemologies, however, are not only concerned with aid work, for they are close to powerful epistemologies relevant to how developed country states engage with social change in their own countries. Since these countries are democracies, this is related to how democratic government happens and how it is understood. In its final conclusions, the chapter makes two points: (1) if predictive power is absent, as is likely, standard methods of accountability are deeply flawed and lack the proper formal foundations they pretend to, (2) if accountability is based upon trust, the old mainstream ways of policy making will flounder, for no narrative will dictate what led to what in terms of inputs and outputs. These two implications are all signs of deep flaws in dominant social epistemologies that must be corrected if we want to move forward. The point is to be effective rather than right. If there is diversity and stubbornly messy complexity, and being right means having predictive capacity, then trying to be right too easily leads to the void. And if you want to win, you may need to be efficient.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

  • Aho, Errki, Kari Pitkanen, and Pasi Sahlberg. 2006. Policy Development and Reform Principles of Basic and Secondary Education in Finland Since 1968. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Catton, Bruce. 1969. The War Lords of Washington. 2nd ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crombie, A.C. 1953. Robert Grosseteste and the Origins of Experimental Science 1100–1700. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, John. 1990. Brute Force: Allied Strategy and Tactics in the Second World War. New York: Viking.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fforde, Adam. 2016. Confirmation Bias: Methodological Causes and a Palliative Response. Quantity and Quality. doi:10.1007/s11135-016-0389-z

  • Fforde, John S. 1995. Comments on Johan de Vries’ Presentation. In How to Write the History of a Bank, ed. Martin M.G. Fase. Aldershot, England: Scolar Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hindess, Barry. 1996. Discourses of Power; From Hobbes to Foucault. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakatos, Imre. 1970. Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes. In Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, ed. Imre Lakatos and Alan Musgrave. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mosse, David. 2005. Cultivating Development: An Ethnography of Aid Policy and Practice. London and Ann Arbor, MI: Pluto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nisbet, R.A. 1969. Social Change and History: Aspects of the Western Theory of Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson, David. 1994. Sly and Able: A Political Biography of James F Byrnes. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Eijndhoven, Josée C.M. 1997. Technology Assessment: Product or Process? Technological Forecasting and Social Change 54: 269–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willis, Katie. 2005. Theories and Practices of Development. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Womack, Brantly. 2004. Asymmetry Theory and China’s Concept of Multipolarity. Journal of Contemporary China 13(39): 351–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. China and Vietnam—The Politics and Asymmetry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Fforde, A. (2017). The Reinvention of Development. In: Reinventing Development . Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-50227-4_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics