Skip to main content

The Mills Model

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Organization of Cities
  • 1034 Accesses

Abstract

Mills (1967) —a widely cited paper in its area—was among the first to present a model of an urban economy operating under perfect competition . Even by today’s standards, the model is bold in scope; it contains 4 industry sectors, 3 factors of production, and two geographic zones (CBD and suburb). In terms of the global economy , this is an open model ; factors flow freely into or out of the city in response to market prices. My intention here is to simplify and clarify the model so that we can better understand its significant implications. Mills implicitly assumes that the state has already enabled competitive markets locally in commodities, housing, transportation , land, labor, and capital . The state has decentralized its authority by empowering property and labor rights and creating incentives for individuals to participate in markets fully enough for everyone in a given market to be a price taker (small player). In market equilibrium , the city reaches a size where the unit cost of production (including land rent , wages, and paid and imputed interest)—the same for each firm in the sector—is just equal to price. No firm is able to earn any profit. Workers who in-migrate to the city are implicitly no better off as a result than those who did not in-migrate. Each unit of capital that flows into the city earns the same rate of return: presumably the same as it could earn outside the city. Despite its elegance, the absence of an algebraic solution make the Mills model difficult to understand. Further, the lengthy set of assumptions made make it difficult to separate out the significance of any one assumption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Mills (1967) is referenced, for example, in Henderson (1974) , Hamilton (1975) , Fujita and Thisse (1996) , Anas et al. (1998) and Quigly (1998).

  2. 2.

    Modeling of rates of change and/or flows from date to date.

  3. 3.

    Production technology by which the firm is able to increase its output only by a similarly proportional increase in all its inputs.

  4. 4.

    For an elastic supply curve, quantity supplied increases quickly as price is increased.

  5. 5.

    Mills used a fixed price elasticity model here. To me, a linear model is simpler.

  6. 6.

    Mills allowed for increasing or decreasing returns to scale. I use constant returns to scale for ease of exposition.

  7. 7.

    Mills appears to treat the transporter pricing parameter a as a constant (i.e., exogenous). However, if the market for transportation is in perfect competition, new keep adding to the supply of land for transportation until there is no excess profit to be earned. In this Chapter, I treat a as just another price whose equilibrium level is to be determined; hence, a is endogenous.

  8. 8.

    As my students look at me (first quizzically then disappointedly), I describe calculations such as the above as demonstrating the beauty of a model. What I mean by “beautiful” here is, of course, how a set of just 16 seemingly innocuous parameters translates into a full and consistent picture of an urban economy in operation.

  9. 9.

    The hypothetical area below the consumer’s demand curve out to the quantity demanded and above market price.

  10. 10.

    The hypothetical area below the consumer’s demand curve out to the quantity demanded.

  11. 11.

    This excludes nonlabor costs incurred by the other sector.

  12. 12.

    Measure of the carrying capacity of a vehicle or vessel: e.g., tonnage or passengers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John R. Miron .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Miron, J.R. (2017). The Mills Model. In: The Organization of Cities . Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-50100-0_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics