Skip to main content

Introduction

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1270 Accesses

Abstract

The theory behind Bayesian Belief Networks (BBN) and Bayes’ theorem is becoming increasingly applicable in economic decision-making in today’s human capital and economic markets across all business, government, and commercial segments in the new global economy. The economic end state of these markets is clearly to maximize stakeholder wealth effectively and efficiently. The question remains, are we? To respond to this question, this chapter provides a discussion of quintessential Bayes’, scope, motivation, intent, utility of the theorem and BBN. Then an introduction to Bayes’ Theorem and BBN and a discussion of inductive versus deductive logic, Popper’s logic of scientific discovery, frequentist versus Bayesian (subjective) views and philosophy, the identification of the truth, finally a classic illustration of the Monty Hall Game Show Paradox.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   64.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The basis for the data consist of a 10,000 rows of randomly generated data from a Monte Carlo experiment to build up to and including a four node BBN.

  2. 2.

    E. T. Jaynes, in his book, Probability Theory: The Logic of Science (Jaynes, 1995) suggests the concept of plausible reasoning is a limited form of deductive logic and “The theory of plausible reasoning” …“is not a weakened form of logic; it is an extension of logic with new content not present at all in conventional deductive logic” (p. 8).

  3. 3.

    In the BBN literature, researchers refer to this knowledge as subjective and originates from a priori (prior) probabilities.

  4. 4.

    We computed the (marginal) probability of event A using the law of total probability as: P(A) = P(A, B)+P(A, B ) = P(A | B) P(B)+P(A | B ) P(B ) = 95. 0 % 1. 0 %+5. 0 % 99. 0 % = 0. 95 %+4. 95 % = 5. 9 %.

  5. 5.

    We computed this as: 490. 1 % = (95 % − 16. 1 %)∕16. 1 %.

  6. 6.

    This term is not statistical but practical in nature.

  7. 7.

    Parameters are statistical reference points such as means and standard deviations, etc.

  8. 8.

    We conducted this search on January 1, 2016. When I first published Strategic Economic Decision-Making: Using Bayesian Belief Networks to Solve Complex Problems (Grover, 2013), there were only 4,000,000 hits.

  9. 9.

    In Bayesian epistemology, P(B | A) is a hypothesis of our initial beliefs. This states that the probability of event B given A is conditioned on a form of evidence, A. (See http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/epistemology-bayesian/ (14 September 2016) for a thorough conversation of this topic.)

  10. 10.

    This means it is occurring at the same time and on the same trial of the experiment.

  11. 11.

    Often we gather these starting points, from observable data. It turns out that this is acceptable, due to the learning that occurs by the algorithm, when we add multiple observable events to the BBN.

  12. 12.

    For Door 1, we compute this as: P(Car Door1 | Contestant Door1, Host Door2) = P(Car Door1, Contestant Door1, Host Door2)∕P(Contestant Door1, Host Door2) = 0. 333333 = 0. 055556∕(0. 055556 + 0. 000000 + 0. 111111).

  13. 13.

    For Door 1, we compute this as: P(Car Door1 | Contestant Door1, Host Door3) = P(Car Door1, Contestant Door1, Host Door3)∕P(Contestant Door1, Host Door3) = 0. 333333 = 0. 055556∕(0. 055556 + 0. 111111 + 0. 000000).

  14. 14.

    For Door 2, we compute this as: P(Car Door2 | Contestant Door2, Host Door1) = P(Car Door2, Contestant Door2, Host Door1)∕P(Contestant Door2, Host Door1) = 0. 333333 = 0. 055556∕(0. 000000 + 0. 055556 + 0. 111111).

  15. 15.

    For Door 1, we compute this as: P(Car Door1 | Contestant Door2, Host Door3) = P(Car Door1, Contestant Door2, Host Door3)∕P(Contestant Door2, Host Door3) = 0. 666667 = 0. 111111∕(0. 111111 + 0. 055556 + 0. 000000).

  16. 16.

    For Door 2, we compute this as: P(Car Door2 | Contestant Door3, Host Door1) = P(Car Door2, Contestant Door3, Host Door1)∕P(Contestant Door3, Host Door1) = 0. 666667 = 0. 111111∕(0. 000000 + 0. 111111 + 0. 055556).

  17. 17.

    For Door 1, we compute this as: P(Car Door1 | Contestant Door3, Host Door2) = P(Car Door1, Contestant Door3, Host Door2)∕P(Contestant Door3, Host Door2) = 0. 666667 = 0. 111111∕(0. 111111 + 0. 000000 + 0. 055556).

  18. 18.

    Ruling out rows 1, 5, and 9 are key to solving this problem.

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Grover, J. (2016). Introduction. In: The Manual of Strategic Economic Decision Making. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-48414-3_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics