Skip to main content

Positive Inequality Indices

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1016 Accesses

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 685))

Abstract

This chapter discusses positive inequality measures, as functions that try to provide descriptive estimates of the variability of income distributions that satisfy most of the properties presented in Chap. 2 and are compatible with our intuitions about what inequality means. There are no explicit references to social welfare even though different measures incorporate implicitly different value judgements. Indeed, one can think of those measures as particular ways of aggregating the differences between individual incomes and a reference value, most of the times the mean income. We review here four different ways of comparing income distributions from a descriptive point of view: the Lorenz curve, the Gini index, the Theil’s family of indices and the Palma ratio. We shall check the properties that those measures satisfy in order to illustrate the different ways of valuing inequality. There are many other ways of measuring inequality, but these are the most common ones.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   89.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This is what happens with the Lorenz curves of the example in the Introduction, as can be easily deduced from Table 2.1. We shall see that the Gini index and other inequality measures rank those two distributions differently as how the variance or the coefficient of variation does.

  2. 2.

    Note that is corresponds to the area of a rectangle minus the upper left triangle, which has two equal sides.

  3. 3.

    This expression can also be rewritten as: \( G=\frac{1}{n}{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n\left(\frac{2i-\left(n+1\right)}{n}\right)\left(\frac{y_i}{\mu}\right)} \)

  4. 4.

    See Mehran (1976), Donaldson and Weymark (1980, 1983), Weymark (1981), Yaari (1988), Chakravarty (1988), Ben-Porath and Gilboa (1994), Aaberge (2000) or Imedio Olmedo and Bárcena Martín (2007).

  5. 5.

    The idea appears first in Kakwani’s (1980) extension of Sen’s (1976) poverty indices.

  6. 6.

    It is immediate to check that solving the programme \( \max\;{\displaystyle {\sum}_{i=1}^n{w}_i \log \left(1/{w}_i\right)} \) subject to \( {\displaystyle {\sum}_{i=1}^n{w}_i=1} \) yields \( \log \left(1/{w}_i\right)= \log \left(1/{w}_j\right) \), for all i, j, so that all w i must be equal and thus correspond to 1/n.

  7. 7.

    See Kanbur (1984) for a different interpretation.

  8. 8.

    Indeed, this index is not defined when s i  = 0 for some i.

  9. 9.

    Bourguignon (1979), Shorrocks (1980, 1984), Cowell (1980) and Cowell and Kuga (1981a) study this family as the result of additive decomposability. An alternative approach is that of strengthening the principle of transfers Cowell and Kuga (1981b). The study of the family extending the information function that we follow here appears in Cowell (1977, 1995) and Cowell and Kuga (1981b).

  10. 10.

    See Cowell (2003) for an additional extension of these indices.

  11. 11.

    This family of functions corresponds to the (negative) class of non-linear transformations introduced by Box and Cox (1964), widely used in statistics and econometrics.

  12. 12.

    The same argument here applies to the second index of Theil, T *.

  13. 13.

    Clearly, any transfer that does not affect the shares of the relationship between the selected quantiles does not affect the index. Transfers that affect the selected quantiles move according to the principle of transfers. This is what we mean by “weak version”.

  14. 14.

    These authors also provide empirical results that point out a link between countries’ Palma ratios and their rates of progress on the major Millennium Development Goal (MDG) poverty targets.

  15. 15.

    As there are three groups clearly defined, any change in the middle one will affect the relative position of the other two.

References

  • Aaberge, R. (2000). Characterizations of Lorenz curves and income distributions. Social Choice and Welfare, 17(4), 639–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B. (1970). On the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory, 2(3), 244–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Porath, E., & Gilboa, I. (1994). Linear measures, the Gini index, and the income-equality trade-off. Journal of Economic Theory, 64, 443–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F. (1979). Decomposable income inequality measures. Econometrica, 47(4), 901–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Box, G. E. P., & Cox, D. R. (1964). An analysis of transformations. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 26(2), 211–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty, S. R. (1988). Extended Gini indices of inequality. International Economic Review, 29(2), 147–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cobham, A., & Sumner, A. (2013). Puntting the Gini back in the bottle? “The Palma” as a policy relevant inequality measure. Working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. A. (1977). Measuring inequality. Oxford: Phillip Allan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. A. (1980). On the structure of additive inequality measures. Review of Economic Studies, 47, 521–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. A. (1995). Measuring inequality, LSE handbooks in economics series (2nd ed.). Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. A. (2003, Mayo). Theil, inequality and the structure of income distribution (Working Paper DARP No. 67). STICERD, LSE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. A., & Kuga, K. (1981a). Additivity and the entropy concept: An axiomatic approach to inequality measurement”. Journal of Economic Theory, 25(1), 131–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. A., & Kuga, K. (1981b). Inequality measurement. An axiomatic approach. European Economic Review, 15(3), 287–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P. S., Sen, A. K., & Starrett, D. A. (1973). Notes on the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory, 6(2), 180–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, D., & Weymark, J. A. (1980). A single parameter generalization of the Gini indices of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory, 22, 67–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, D., & Weymark, J. A. (1983). Ethically flexible Gini indices for income distribution in the continuum. Journal of Economic Theory, 29(4), 353–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doylan, M. W., & Stigliz, J. E. (2014). Eliminating extreme inequality: A sustainable development goal 2015-2030. http://www.ethicsandinternationalaffairs.org/2014/eliminating-extreme-inequality-a-sustainable-development-goal-2015-2030/

  • Foster, J. E. (1983). An axiomatic characterization of the Theil measure of income inequality. Journal of Economic Theory, 31(1), 105–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gini, C. (1921). Measurement of inequality of incomes. The Economic Journal, 31, 124–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goerlich, F., & Villar, A. (2009). Desigualdad y bienestar. Fundación BBVA: De la teoría a la práctica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imedio Olmedo, L. J., & Bárcena Martín, E. (2007). Dos familias numerables de medidas de desigualdad. Investigaciones Económicas, 31(1), 191–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani, N. (1980). On a class of poverty measures. Econometrica, 48(2), 437–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur, R. (1984). The measurement and decomposition of inequality and poverty. In F. van der Ploeg (Ed.), Mathematical methods in economics. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khinchin, A. (1957). Mathematical formulations of information theory. New York: Dover Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolm, S.-C. (1976a). Unequal inequalities I. Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 416–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolm, S.-C. (1976b). Unequal inequalities II. Journal of Economic Theory, 13, 82–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kullback, S. (1959). Information theory and statistics. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz, M. O. (1905). Methods of measuring the concentration of wealth. Publications of the American Statistical Association, 9, 209–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Love, R., & Wolfson, M. C. (1976). Income inequality: Statistical methodology and Canadian illustrations. Ottawa: Statistics Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehran, F. (1976). Linear measures of income inequality. Econometrica, 44(4), 805–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B. (2015). Why I’m still not excited by the Palma index. Blog Globalinequality. http://glineq.blogspot.com/2015/06/why-i-am-still-not-excited-by-palma.html

  • Palma, J. G. (2011). Homogeneous middles vs. heterogeneous tails, and the end of the ‘Inverted-U’: The share of the rich is what it’s all about. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics (CWPE) 1111. Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, M., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1973). Some further results on the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory, 6(2), 188–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1973). On economic inequality. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1976). Poverty: An ordinal approach to measurement. Econometrica, 44(2), 219–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks, A. F. (1980). The class of additively decomposable inequality measures. Econometrica, 48(3), 613–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks, A. F. (1984). Inequality decomposition by population subgroups. Econometrica, 52(6), 1369–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Theil, H. (1967). Economics and information theory. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weymark, J. A. (1981). Generalized Gini inequality indices. Mathemathical Social Sciences, 1, 409–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yaari, M. E. (1988). A controversial proposal concerning inequality measurement. Journal of Economic Theory, 44(4), 381–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki, S. (1983). On an extension of the Gini inequality index. International Economic Review, 24(3), 617–628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Decomposability of the Generalised Indices of Theil

Appendix: Decomposability of the Generalised Indices of Theil

Let us describe how the generalised index of Theil can be decomposed. The formula of this uni-parametric family of indices is give by:

$$ {I}_{\theta}\left(n,y\right)=\frac{1}{n}\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n\left[{\left(\frac{y_i}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]} $$

with θ ≠ 0,1 (the 0 and 1 cases have already been discussed). We can proceed as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{I}_{\theta}\left(n,y\right)=\frac{1}{n}\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n_g}\left[{\left(\frac{y_i^g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]}}\hfill \\ {}=\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{1}{n}}\left[{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n_g}{\left(\frac{y_i^g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }-{n}_g}\right]\hfill \\ {}=\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}}{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta}\left[\frac{1}{n_g}{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n_g}\left[{\left(\frac{y_i^g}{\mu_g}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]}+1-{\left(\frac{\mu }{\mu_g}\right)}^{\theta}\right]\hfill \\ {}={\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}}{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta}\underset{I_{\theta}^g}{\underbrace{\frac{1}{n_g}\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n_g}\left[{\left(\frac{y_i^g}{\mu_g}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]}}}+\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}}\left[{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]\hfill \end{array} $$

The first term of this expression is a weighted sum of the indices I θ within groups. The weights are given by:

$$ {\omega}_g^G\left(\boldsymbol{\mu}, \mathtt{n}\right)=\frac{n_g}{n}{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta } $$

which depend on the parameter θ of inequality aversion.

Note that those weights can be expressed in terms of population and income shares, that is,

$$ {\omega}_g^G\left(\boldsymbol{\mu}, \mathtt{n}\right)=\frac{n_g}{n}{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }={\left(\frac{n_g}{n}\right)}^{1-\theta }{\left(\frac{n_g{\mu}_g}{n\mu}\right)}^{\theta } $$

This expression is interesting because it shows that only when θ = 0 and θ = 1 (the first and second indices of Theil), those weights add up to 1.

The second term of that expression corresponds to I θ applied to the mean values of each group, that is, it describes the between groups component.

We can thus write:

$$ {I}_{\theta}\left(n,\mathbf{y}\right)={\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }{I}_{\theta}^g}+\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}\left[{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]} $$
(3.22a)

or,

$$ {I}_{\theta }={I}_{\theta, W}+{I}_{\theta, B} $$
(3.22b)

where,

  1. (i)
    $$ {I}_{\theta, W}={\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }{I}_{\theta}^g} $$
  2. (ii)
    $$ {I}_{\theta, B}=\frac{1}{\theta \left(\theta -1\right)}{\displaystyle \sum_{g=1}^G\frac{n_g}{n}\left[{\left(\frac{\mu_g}{\mu}\right)}^{\theta }-1\right]} $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Villar, A. (2017). Positive Inequality Indices. In: Lectures on Inequality, Poverty and Welfare. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 685. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-45562-4_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics