Skip to main content

Compliance and Individual Sanctions in the Enforcement of Competition Law

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Competition Law Compliance Programmes

Abstract

This chapter describes the status quo of criminal enforcement in selected Member States of the European Union and discusses the desirability of criminal enforcement of competition law from a policy perspective. It concludes that at least in Germany the introduction of a criminal offence for horizontal hardcore cartels beyond the existing bid-rigging offence would be desirable, provided an automatic criminal immunity provision for immunity recipients under a leniency programme within the European Competition Network is introduced and the Bundeskartellamt is involved in the criminal prosecution. The introduction of effective criminal enforcement would make compliance training both more important and more effective. Criminalisation makes compliance more important because compliance training helps to spread knowledge about the criminal offence—and only a known threat can deter. Criminalisation makes compliance training more effective because the participants of compliance sessions are motivated to pay attention to avoid criminal liability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Think of recent recalls, e.g., for Takata airbags (Tabuchi and Ivory 2016); for the defect in the ignition switch for GM vehicles, which resulted in a criminal penalty of $900 million and private settlements of at least a further $600 million (Wright 2015) in addition to a large-scale recall (Vlasic and Stout 2014); or for the defect leading to uncontrolled acceleration in Toyota vehicles, resulting, inter alia, in a financial penalty of $1.2 billion (see Department of Justice 2014a).

  2. 2.

    See, e.g., the Siemens scandal (on the consequences for compliance, see, e.g., Sindhu 2009). Good relations to the government may help, cf Adams and Boxell (2006) on the attorney-general’s intervention in the investigation by the Serious Fraud Office (SFO) into alleged corruption of BAE in Saudi Arabia.

  3. 3.

    See, e.g., the HSBC case (Department of Justice 2012).

  4. 4.

    See European Commission, Cartel Statistics, https://perma.cc/KP5P-4GGJ, Table 1.4 (court adjusted) (at the time of writing last changed on 6 April 2016; for periodically updated statistics see http://ec.europa.eu/competition/cartels/statistics/statistics.pdf).

  5. 5.

    Ibid. The amounts do not seem to be adjusted for inflation, however.

  6. 6.

    Ibid.

  7. 7.

    Ibid, Table 1.8 (at the time of writing last changed 6 April 2016).

  8. 8.

    Ibid, Table 1.10 (at the time of writing last changed 6 April 2016). The number of immunity recipients was 20, 25, and 21, for the three 5 year periods from 2001 to 2005, 2006 to 2010, and 2011 to 2015, respectively (see Wils 2016), thus accounting fairly precisely for the jump to around 30 cartel cases in each of these periods from the baseline of about 10 cartel cases per 5-year period before 2000.

  9. 9.

    See Lianos et al. (2014, p. 129) (the average fine for the full period from 2010 to 2014 is only about €41 million, as opposed to the €50 million reported in that report, because the report was published in May 2014 and could not take into account later events, which included both the downward court adjustment of cartel fines and a number of lower fines imposed in 2014).

  10. 10.

    European Commission, n. 4, Table 1.6 (at the time of writing last updated 6 April 2016).

  11. 11.

    Ibid, Table 1.11 (at the time of writing last updated 31 December 2015).

  12. 12.

    Employing risk averse, civic-minded bureaucrat-type personalities would arguably reduce the danger of cartels, but may be suboptimal in terms of vigorous competition.

  13. 13.

    Levenstein and Suslow (2011, pp. 462–463) look at 81 cartels with participants from at least two jurisdictions (“international cartels”) that were prosecuted in the US or the EU with start dates from 1990; they find a mean duration of 8.1 years (standard deviation s = 5.8 years) and a median of 7 years (see also ibid, pp. 463–464, citing older studies that report similar means of between 5.3 and 8.3 years). Combe and Monnier (2011, p. 243) consider a sample of 64 European cartels between 1975 and 2009 and find a mean duration of 7 years. Bryant and Eckard (1991) look at a sample of 184 detected cartel cases (US Department of Justice cases from the period between 1961 and 1988) and find a mean duration of between 5.2 and 7.3 years (with a median of between 3.6 and 5.8 years) (the ranges indicate the lowest and highest duration estimates, respectively). See also Harrington and Wei (2015), who argue that the estimated duration derived from the average duration of detected cartels is only mildly biased because of two countervailing effects: on the one hand, when cartels are detected, their lifetime is cut short, and so for that reason they may have a shorter duration than those cartels that are not detected, and additionally, the probability of dying cartels to be detected may be higher (in particular because this transforms the stag-hunt-game of leniency programmes into prisoners’ dilemmas); on the other hand, longer cartels may be overrepresented in the sample of detected cartels because they are more likely to be detected at some point in their lifetime.

  14. 14.

    In the United Kingdom, it was held that the ex turpi causa doctrine prevented the undertaking from seeking indemnification from employees and directors, because the Chapter I prohibition and Article 101 TFEU are addressed to the undertaking itself. Safeway Stores Ltd and others v Twigger and others, [2010] EWCA Civ 1472, [2011] Bus. L.R. 1629 (for a discussion, see, e.g., Kapp and Hummel 2011). The UK Supreme Court has recently indicated that it may not unreservedly stand behind Safeway v Twigger, see Les Laboratoires Servier and another v Apotex Inc and others, [2014] UKSC 55, [2015] A.C. 430, 451 [45]: “[T]his is not a case in which any question arises as to the correctness or otherwise of a decision such as that of the Court of Appeal in Safeway Stores Ltd v Twigger […], which held that a company could not recover from directors or employees who had by involving the company in acts contravening the Competition Act 1998 caused it to incur a ‘personal’ liability for penalties imposed under that Act.” In Germany, the Landesarbeitsgericht Düsseldorf reached the same result by a similar route: indemnification was held to run counter the purposes of the fine imposed on the undertaking; this was considered to be in particular the case where the fine incorporates elements of disgorgement of illegal gains; and the possibility of imposing fines on the undertaking and the individual was considered to preclude the possibility for the undertaking to seek indemnification from the responsible individuals, both individuals in management (LAG Düsseldorf, 20 January 2015, 16 Sa 459/14, Neue Juristische Online-Zeitschrift 2015, 782, 789 ff.; the court below had considered capping the damages claim at the maximum amount for the individual fine) and employees (LAG Düsseldorf, 27 November 2015, 14 Sa 800/14, BeckRS 2016, 65558, para 164 (obiter, because the court considered the employee’s participation in the cartel not to be proven, ibid, paras 180 ff.)).

  15. 15.

    While Director & Officers’ Insurance could lead to deeper pockets, D&O Insurance will not cover willful law infringements.

  16. 16.

    See on the one hand Combe and Monnier (2011), pp. 267–268 (finding that in about half of the cases the fines did not even skim off the gains, so that they would not even be deterrent if the detection probability were 100 %) and on the other hand Allain et al. (2013) (finding that between 30 and 80 % of the fines imposed from 2005 to 2010 were deterrent, depending largely on the assumptions about the competitive mark-up in the counterfactual, about the cartel overcharge, and about the demand elasticities).

  17. 17.

    I say only “nearly costlessly” because any extension of scope or duration of the cartel or intensification of cartel activity would increase the probability of detection of the cartel, so that the expected fine would rise. Nevertheless, if the cartel is considered to be profitable in the first place, it is likely that the marginal increase in the detection probability would be lower than the marginal increase in cartel profits where, for example, the cartel duration is extended.

  18. 18.

    See point 35 of the Fining Guidelines. See also Almunia and Lewandowski (2010); Monopolkommission (2014), § 148.

  19. 19.

    At least the following EU jurisdictions provide for criminal sanctions for cartels (or, where noted, only bid rigging): Austria (bid rigging only, Ablasser-Neuhuber and Neumayr 2015, p. 19); Belgium (Lebrun and Bersou 2015, p. 25: ‘Bid rigging is the sole cartel activity which is likely to lead to criminal sanctions’); the Czech Republic (Fiala 2015, p. 65); Denmark (since 2013, Rung-Hansen 2015, p. 71); France (Viros 2016); Germany (bid rigging; Wagner-von Papp 2011; Wagner-von Papp 2016; Zimmer 2016); Greece (Papadopoulos and Lovdahl Gormsen 2015, p. 107); Hungary (bid rigging; Szabó 2015, p. 120); Ireland (Andrews and Collins 2015, pp. 137–138; for more detail see Massey and Cooke 2011, p. 105); Italy (Caiazzo and Costantini 2015, p. 154); Poland (bid rigging only, Hansberry-Bieguńska and Krasnodębska-Tomkiel 2015, p. 214); Romania (separate provisions for cartels and bid rigging, Rădulescu and Iacob 2015, p. 229); Slovenia (Pipan Nahtigal and Lahovnik 2015, pp. 247–248); UK (for the amended cartel offence, see Stephan 2014; Gilbert 2015; for the 2002 version, see Stephan 2008; Joshua 2011, p. 129). This does not even include criminal sanctions for procedural offences, such as in Cyprus or Finland. Finland, and Sweden (and in the EFTA Switzerland) considered, but eventually rejected criminalisation. In the EEA, Norway has also criminal sanctions (Sando and Hageler 2015, p. 208). For a global overview of criminalisation see Campbell 2015; Shaffer, Nesbitt and Weber Waller (2015). To be sure, in many of these jurisdictions this is pure law in the books without any significant enforcement. Yet even this law in the books may become relevant when it comes to extradition, see below Sect. 8.5.

  20. 20.

    For example, the following Member States provide for administrative sanctions for individuals (such as fines and/or director disqualifications), either in addition or as an alternative to criminal sanctions. Germany provides for individual fines of up to €1 million for all intentional or negligent competition law infringements, in addition to the criminal bid-rigging offence (see below Sect. 8.3.2). The UK provides, in addition to the criminal cartel offence, for director disqualification orders (see below Sect. 8.3.1). Greek law provides, in addition to the criminal cartel offence, for individual administrative fines of between €200,000 and €2 million (Papadopoulos and Lovdahl Gormsen 2015, p. 107). Slovenia, also in addition to its criminal cartel offence, provides for individual administrative fines of between €5000 and 30,000 (Pipan Nahtigal and Lahovnik 2015, p. 248). Lithuania, while not providing for criminal liability, provides for individual fines and director disqualifications (Kolesnikovas 2015, p. 176). The Netherlands considered re-criminalising cartels, but eventually decided against it (Frese 2014, pp. 222–224), but Dutch law does provides for individual administrative fines of up to €450,000 (de Pree and Molin 2015, p. 197; Frese 2014, pp. 202–208). Portugal provides for administrative fines on individuals, albeit of a very low magnitude (between approximately €1000 and 5000, Marques Mendes and Vilarinho Pires 2015, pp. 222–223). Article 63.2 of the Spanish Competition Act provides for administrative fines of up to €60,000 for individuals (see Jiménez-Laiglesia et al 2015, p. 262). Swedish law provides for “injunctions against trading” similar to director disqualifications (Pettersson et al. 2015, p. 269). With effect from January 2015, Poland introduced administrative fines on individuals of up to 2 million Polish zlotys (at the time of writing: approximately €455,000) (Motyka-Mojkowski 2015, pp. 1109–1111; Hansberry-Bieguńska and Krasnodębska-Tomkiel 2015, p. 214). There are special criminal prohibitions against bid rigging, for example, in Germany, Austria, Hungary, and Poland.

  21. 21.

    CMA (2014: § 1.3). Until s 47 of the ERRA 2013 came into force on 1 April 2014, the conduct had to be shown to be “dishonest”.

  22. 22.

    s 190(4) EA 2002.

  23. 23.

    R v Whittle and others, [2008] EWCA Crim 2560, [25]–[28].

  24. 24.

    R v Whittle and others, [2008] EWCA Crim 2560.

  25. 25.

    Ibid [31].

  26. 26.

    Norris v Government of the United States of America [2008] UKHL 16, [2008] 2 WLR 673 (HL(E)).

  27. 27.

    For a summary, see Blake 2015.

  28. 28.

    s 188A EA 2002, as amended by s 47(5) ERRA 2013.

  29. 29.

    s 188B(1), (2) EA 2002, as amended by s 47(6) ERRA 2013.

  30. 30.

    s 188B(3) EA 2002, as amended by s 47(6) ERRA 2013.

  31. 31.

    Wils (2013). The National Audit Office (2016) noted: “The low caseflow we identified in 2010 has continued, with the Office of Fair Trading and the CMA making 24 decisions and the regulators just eight since 2010. The UK competition authorities issued only £65 million of competition enforcement fines between 2012 and 2014 (in 2015 prices), compared to almost £1.4 billion of fines imposed by their German counterparts. The CMA faces significant barriers in increasing its flow of competition cases, although recent activity means it now has 12 ongoing cases.”

  32. 32.

    s 204 EA 2002, amending the Company Directors Disqualification Act 1986 (c. 46) and inserting ss 9A–9E into that Act.

  33. 33.

    Bundestags-Drucksache 1/3462, Annex 1, 21–22 and Bundestags-Drucksache 2/1158, Annex 1, 27–28, quoted in Wagner-von Papp (2010a, p. 281; 2011, p. 164).

  34. 34.

    § 47 Gesetz über Ordnungswidrigkeiten (OWiG). The Bundeskartellamt is empowered to publish guidelines in particular on the setting of the fine, and has done so as far as fines for undertakings and associations of undertakings are concerned. The latest version are the 2013 Guidelines. Bundeskartellamt, Guidelines for the Setting of Fines in Cartel Administrative Offence Proceedings, 25 June 2013, https://perma.cc/T3L5-WDHD.

  35. 35.

    Bundeskartellamt, Notice no 9/2006, Notice no. 9/2006 of the Bundeskartellamt on the immunity from and reduction of fines in cartel cases—Leniency Programme—of 7 March 2006, https://perma.cc/LNS9-NZ8Q.

  36. 36.

    § 81(4) GWB. Theoretically, this maximum could be exceeded where this is necessary to skim off illegal gains, § 17(4) of the Gesetz über Ordnungswidrigkeiten (OWiG), which applies with the modification in § 81(5) GWB.

  37. 37.

    The following paragraph partially replicates what I wrote in Wagner-von Papp (2016), § 15.

  38. 38.

    BVerfG, 19 December 2012, 1 BvL 18/11, WuW/E DE-R 3766, paragraphs 52, 60—Verzinsungspflicht, available at http://www.bverfg.de/entscheidungen/ls20121219_1bvl001811.html (in German).

  39. 39.

    Ibid., paragraph 60.

  40. 40.

    Bundeskartellamt, 2 April 2014, Fallbericht Bußgelder gegen Brauereien (Summary Case Report on the decisions of 27 December 2013 and 31 March 2014, Case B10-105/11), http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Entscheidung/DE/Fallberichte/Kartellverbot/2014/B10-105-11.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=1.

  41. 41.

    BGH, 19 June 2007—KRB 12/07, NJW 2007, 3792, WuW/E DE-R 2225, § 10—Papiergroßhandel (Wholesale Paper).

  42. 42.

    In the Cement case, the individual fine of €200,000 imposed on the individual “Ed. Sch.” was reduced by 5 % (€10,000) on appeal because of the long duration of the appeal procedure, BGH, 26 February 2013—KRB 20/12, WuW/E DE-R 3861, §§ 1, 87–91—Grauzement (Cement).

  43. 43.

    Second sentence of § 17(3) of the Administrative Offences Act (OWiG).

  44. 44.

    E.g., in the Cement case, the lowest of the fines for nine individual appellants was only €6000, BGH, n. 42. In another cartel case, the Higher Regional Court Düsseldorf set a fine of some €40,000 for one of the individuals, OLG Düsseldorf, 29 May 2015, V-2 Kart 1 + 2/13 (OWi), NRWEntscheidungen. For a discussion of the factors influencing the setting of the individual fines in an information exchange case, see OLG Düsseldorf, 29 October 2012, V-1 Kart 1–6/12 (OWi) §§ 140–96, NRWEntscheidungen—Silostellgebühren.

  45. 45.

    See, for example, OLG Hamm, 5 June 1996, 4 Ss 60/96. Further references in Mayer Lux (2013, p. 224 ff.).

  46. 46.

    LG Munich II (2006); Wagner-von Papp (2011), pp. 169–170.

  47. 47.

    BGH, 29 April 2015, 1 StR 235/14, BeckRS 2015, 12466; Wagner-von Papp (2016), § 14.

  48. 48.

    Where the suspected offence carries a minimum prison sentence, § 49b StGB applies, and the court may either reduce the sentence under § 49 StGB or may abstain from imposing any sentence. This could become relevant for our context where a leniency applicant committed aggravated fraud.

  49. 49.

    Bundeskartellamt, Press Releases of 10 February 2012, 15 April 2013, and 3 June 2014.

  50. 50.

    In 2012 Ireland considered the decriminalisation of non-hardcore offences, but this was given up when its Attorney General advised that substantial civil fines could raise constitutional concerns under Article 38 of the Irish Constitution.

  51. 51.

    The recommendation awards criminal immunity to perpetrators where the competition authority awards immunity from fines to the undertaking, but excludes immunity for the sole instigator and coercers. A debate is to be had whether this should not be reduced to excluding at most coercers, so as not to deter leniency applications from instigators; otherwise, especially cartels with only two members would be stabilised. More importantly, the recommendation would have to be amended to take account of individual leniency applications.

  52. 52.

    Links to the transcripts are contained in Hammond (2005); the videos themselves are available on Youtube.

  53. 53.

    “[The poor have] to work under the majestic equality of the law, which prohibits the rich and the poor to sleep under bridges, beg in the streets and steal bread”.

  54. 54.

    For the United Kingdom, see already the earlier case of Ian Norris, who was eventually extradited to the United States from the United Kingdom. His extradition was not, however, based on the cartel offence, because s 188 EA 2002 had not been in force when he entered into a cartel; nor did the House of Lords consider cartel conduct to fall under the common law offence of conspiracy to defraud (Norris v Government of the United States of America [2008] UKHL 16, [2008] 2 WLR 673 (HL(E))). Instead, his extradition was based on obstruction of justice charges. Those participating in horizontal hardcore cartels after June 2003, however, would satisfy the dual criminality requirement.

  55. 55.

    European Commission (2014a), § 41: “The majority of Member States provide for sanctions to be imposed on individuals for breaches of competition law, over and above fines on undertakings. If such systems do not provide for leniency for the employees of undertakings which are considering applying for corporate leniency, this may lead to disincentives to cooperate with authorities EU-wide. The threat of investigations and sanctions targeted at employees may deter potential corporate applicants from applying.” Even more clearly European Commission (2014b), §§ 99–102, highlighting the interjurisdictional externalities of the threat of criminal sanctions.

References

  • Ablasser-Neuhuber, A., & Neumayr, F. (2015). Austria. In Campbell (2015), (p. 17).

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, C., & Boxell, J. (2006). UK drops BAE-Saudi bribery probe. Financial Times, 15 December 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allain, M.-L., Boyer, M., Kotchoni, R., & Ponssard, J.-P. (2013). Are cartel fines optimal? — Theory and evidence from the European Union. CIRANO Scientific Series 2013s-24 (July 2013), http://www.cirano.qc.ca/pdf/publication/2013s-24.pdf.

  • Almunia, J., & Lewandowski, J. (2010). Information note by Mr. Joaquín Almunia, Vice- President of the Commission, and by Mr. Janusz Lewandowski, Member of the Commission, Inability to Pay under paragraph 35 of the 2006 fining guidelines and payment conditions pre- and post-decision finding an infringement and imposing fines, SEC(2010) 737/2 (12 June 2010).

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, P., & Collins, D. (2015). Ireland. In Campbell (2015), (p. 135).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashton, D., & Henry, D. (2013). Competition damages actions in the EU: Law and practice. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Autorité de la Concurrences. (2015). Communiqué de procédure du 3 avril 2015 relatif au programme de clémence français. Available from http://www.autoritedelaconcurrence.fr/doc/cpro_autorite_clemence_revise.pdf.

  • Baumann, J., & Arzt, G. (1970). Kartellrecht und allgemeines Strafrecht. Zeitschrift für das gesamte Handelsrecht und Wirtschaftsrecht, 134, 24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaton-Wells, C., & Ezrachi, A. (Eds.). (2011). Criminalising cartels: Critical studies of an international regulatory movement. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, J. (2007). Neubestimmung des deutschen und europäischen Kartellsanktionenrechts: Reformüberlegungen, Determinanten und Perspektiven einer Kriminalisierung von Verstößen gegen das Kartellrecht. Zeitschrift für Wettbewerbsrecht, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaise, J.-B. (2013). La Sanction Pénale. Concurrence No 1-2013, Colloque “Les Sanctions du Droit de la Concurrence”, 23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blake, S. (2015). The UK steel tanks criminal cartel trial: Implications for criminalisation and leniency, 13 November 2015. Available from https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/stephen-blake-on-the-uk-steel-tanks-criminal-cartel-case.

  • Bryant, P. G., & Eckard, E. W. (1991). Price fixing: The probability of getting caught. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 73(3), 531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bundeskartellamt. (2006). Notice no. 9/2006 of the Bundeskartellamt on the immunity from and reduction of fines in cartel cases – Leniency Programme (7 March 2006). Available from http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/EN/Banoncartels/Leniency_programme/leniencyprogramme_node

  • Bundeskartellamt. (2011). Erfolgreiche Kartellverfolgung — Nutzen für Wirtschaft und Verbraucher (August 2011). Available from http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/DE/Broschueren/Informationsbrosch%C3%BCre%20-%20Erfolgreiche%20Kartellverfolgung.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=9.

  • Bundeskartellamt. (2012). Fallbericht — Erste Bußgelder im Schienenkartell verhängt, Case B12 – 11/11 (14 December 2012). Available from http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Entscheidung/DE/Fallberichte/Kartellverbot/2012/B12-11-11.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=4.

  • Bundeskartellamt. (2015a). Tätigkeitsbericht des Bundeskartellamts 2013/14, Bundestags-Drucksache 18/5210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundeskartellamt. (2015b). Zwischenbericht des Bundeskartellamts zum Expertenkreis Kartellsanktionenrecht — Reformimpulse für das Kartellbußgeldverfahren (12 January 2015). Available from http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/DE/Berichte/AG_Kartellsanktionenrecht_Zwischenbericht.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=2.

  • Caiazzo, R., & Costantini, F. (2015). Italy. In Campbell (2015), (p. 150).

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A. N. (2015). Getting the deal through: cartel regulation 2015 (15th ed.). London: Law Business Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • CMA. (2014). Cartel offence prosecution guidance. March 2014, CMA9. Available from https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/288648/CMA9__Cartel_Offence_Prosecution_Guidance.pdf.

  • CMA, & COPFS. (2014). Memorandum of understanding between the Competition and Markets Authority and the Crown Office and Procurator Fiscal Service. July 2014. Available from https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/328403/CMA_and_COPFS_MOU.pdf.

  • CMA. (2015a). CMA statement following completion of criminal cartel prosecution. Press Release, 24 June 2015. Available from https://www.gov.uk/government/news/cma-statement-following-completion-of-criminal-cartel-prosecution.

  • CMA. (2015b). Director sentenced to six months for criminal cartel. Press Release, 14 September 2015. Available from https://www.gov.uk/government/news/director-sentenced-to-6-months-for-criminal-cartel.

  • Coffee, J. (1980). Corporate crime and punishment. American Criminal Law Review, 17, 419.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combe, E., & Monnier, C. (2011). Fines against hard-core cartels in Europe: The myth of overenforcement. The Antitrust Bulletin, 56(2), 235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coulon, J.-M. (2008). La Dépénalisation de la Vie des Affaires, Rapport au garde des Sceaux, Ministre de la Justice (Paris, January 2008). Available from http://www.ladocumentationfrancaise.fr/var/storage/rapports-publics/084000090.pdf.

  • Crofts, L. (2015). MLex interview with Romano Pisciotti (9 December 2015). Available from http://mlexmarketinsight.com/reports/mlex-interview-with-romano-pisciotti/, https://perma.cc/DT5U-JS26.

  • Cseres, K., Schinkel, M.-P., & Vogelaar, F. (2006). Law and economics of criminal antitrust enforcement: An introduction. In K. Cseres, M.-P. Schinkel, & F. Vogelaar (Eds.), Criminalization of competition law enforcement (p. 1). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Department of Justice. (2012). HSBC Holdings plc and HSBC Bank USA N.A. Admit to Anti-Money Laundering and Sanctions Violations, Forfeit $1.256 Billion in Deferred Prosecution Agreement: Bank Agrees to Enhanced Compliance Obligations, Oversight by Monitor in Connection with Five-Year Agreement. Press Release, 11 December 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Justice. (2014a). Justice Department announces criminal charge against Toyota Motor Corporation and Deferred Prosecution Agreement with $1.2 Billion Financial Penalty. Press Release, 19 March 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Justice. (2014b). Antitrust Division, Workload Statistics FY 2005-2014. Available from https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/788426/download.

  • Department of Justice. (2016). United States files complaint against Volkswagen, Audi and Porsche for Alleged Clean Air Act Violations. Press Release, 4 January 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Pree, J. K., & Molin, S. (2015). Netherlands. In Campbell (2015), (p. 193).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, M. (2009). Die persönliche Verantwortlichkeit von Geschäftsleitern nach außen auf Schadensersatz bei Kartellrechtsverstößen. Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 59, 133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, M. (2011). Wider die Kriminalisierung des Kartellrechts. Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 61, 232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eden, E. (2013). Persönliche Schadensersatzhaftung von Managern gegenüber Kartellgeschädigten. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eden, E. (2014). Haften Geschäftsführer persönlich gegenüber Kartellgeschädigten auf Schadensersatz? Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 64, 792, WUW0665591.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emrich-Katzin, S. (2013). Schwerpunktstaatsanwaltschaften im Wirtschaftsstrafrecht und die Stellung der Wirtschaftsreferenten. Frankfurt: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2014a). Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council: Ten Years of Antitrust Enforcement under Regulation 1/2003: Achievements and Future Perspectives (9 July 2014), COM(2014) 453 final.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2014b). Commission Staff Working Document: enhancing competition enforcement by the Member States' competition authorities: institutional and procedural issues (9 July 2014), SWD(2014) 231 final

    Google Scholar 

  • Federmann, B. (2006). Kriminalstrafen im Kartellrecht: Eine rechtsvergleichende Untersuchung zur Frage der Kriminalisierung von Hardcore-Kartellen. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiala, T. (2015). Czech Republic. In Campbell (2015), (p. 63).

    Google Scholar 

  • France, A. (1894). Le Lys Rouge (14th ed.). Paris: Calmann-Lévy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frese, M. J. (2014). Sanctions in EU competition law: Principles and practice. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, P. (2015). Changes to the UK cartel offence—Be careful what you wish for. Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 6, 192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girardet, P. (2010). ‘What if Uncle Sam wants you? Principles and recent practice concerning US extradition requests in cartel cases. Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 1(4), 286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, S. D. (2005). Caught in the act: Inside an international cartel, OECD Competition Committee Working Party No. 3, OECD, Paris, 18 October 2005. Available from https://www.justice.gov/atr/speech/caught-act-inside-international-cartel (permanent link: https://perma.cc/V2H2-FCRV).

  • Hansberry-Bieguńska, D., & Krasnodębska-Tomkiel, M. (2015). Poland. In Campbell (2015), (p. 212).

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington Jr, J. E., & Wei, Y. (2015). What can the duration of detected cartels tell us about the duration of all cartels? (4 December 2015). Available from http://assets.wharton.upenn.edu/~harrij/pdf/Cartel%20Duration_12.15.pdf.

  • Jenny, F. (2013). L’Articulation des Sanctions en Matière de Droit de la Concurrence du Point de Vue Économique. Concurrence No 1-2013, Colloque “Les Sanctions du Droit de la Concurrence”, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiménez-Laiglesia, J., Ois, A., Masía, J., Hervada, J., & Maldonado, R. (2015). Spain. In Campbell (2015), (p. 260).

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, K. R., & Harrison, F. (2014). Criminal sanctions: An overview of EU and national case law (25 March 2014). e-competitions No 64713.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joshua, J. (2011). DOA: Can the UK cartel offence be resuscitated. In Beaton-Wells & Ezrachi (2011), (p. 129).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapp, T., & Hummel, K. (2011). Haftung von Managern und Mitarbeitern für Unternehmensbußgelder? Zeitschrift für Wettbewerbsrecht, 349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kartte, W., & von Portatius, A. (1975). Kriminalisierung des Kartellrechts? Betriebs-Berater, 1169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolesnikovas, G. (2015). Lithuania. In Campbell (2015), (p. 172).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic, W. E. (2006). Competition policy and cartels: the design of remedies. In K. Cseres, M.-P. Schinkel, & F. Vogelaar (Eds.), Criminalization of competition law enforcement (p. 41). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic, W. E. (2016). Criminal enforcement of competition law: implications of US experience. Concurrences No. 2–2016, 33. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2782090

  • Lampert, T., & Götting, S. (2002). Startschuss für eine Kriminalisierung des Kartellrechts? Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 52, 1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lebrun, B., & Bersou, L. (2015). Belgium. In Campbell (2015), (p. 23).

    Google Scholar 

  • Levenstein, M. C., & Suslow, V. Y. (2011). Breaking up is hard to do: Determinants of cartel duration. Journal of Law & Economics, 54(2), 455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LG Munich II. (2006). 3 May 2006, W5 KLs 567 Js 30966/04, partially reprinted in BeckRS 2008, 00736 “King of the Pipes”.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lianos, I., Jenny, F., Wagner-von Papp, F., Motchenkova, E., & David, E. (2014). An optimal and just financial penalties system for infringements of competition law: A comparative analysis. CLES Research paper series 3/2014, UCL Faculty of Laws: London (May 2014). Available from http://www.fne.gob.cl/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/Estudio.pdf.

  • Marques Mendes, M., & Vilarinho Pires, P. (2015). Portugal. In Campbell (2015), (p. 218).

    Google Scholar 

  • Marvão, C., & Spagnolo, G. (2015). What do we know about the effectiveness of leniency policies? A survey of the empirical and experimental evidence. In C. Beaton-Wells & C. Tran (Eds.), Anti-cartel enforcement in a contemporary age: Leniency religion (p. 57). Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Massey, P., & Cooke, J. D. (2011). Competition offences in Ireland: The regime and its results. In Beaton-Wells & Ezrachi (2011), (p. 105).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer Lux, L. (2013). Die konkludente Täuschung beim Betrug. V&R Unipress, Bonner rechtswissenschaftliche Abhandlungen N.F. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monopolkommission. (2014). Eine Wettbewerbsordnung für die Finanzmärkte, XX. Hauptgutachten 2012/13. Available from http://monopolkommission.de/images/PDF/HG/HG20/HG_XX_gesamt.pdf.

  • Monopolkommission. (2015). Strafrechtliche Sanktionen bei Kartellverstößen, Sondergutachten 72. Available from http://monopolkommission.de/images/PDF/SG/s72_volltext.pdf.

  • Möschel, W. (1980). Zur Problematik einer Kriminalisierung von Submissionsabsprachen. Cologne: Carl Heymanns Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Motyka-Mojkowski, M. (2015). Reform des polnischen Kartellrechts — Schwerpunkte der kartellrechtlichen Novelle 2014. Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 65, 1104.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Audit Office. (2016). The UK competition regime, HC 737, Session 2015-16, 5 February 2016. Available from https://www.nao.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2016/02/The-UK-Competition-regime.pdf.

  • Nikpay, A., & Taylor, D. (2014). The new UK competition regime: Radically different or more of the same? Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 5, 278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, A. (2015). Leadership of leniency. In C. Beaton-Wells & C. Tran (Eds.), Anti-cartel enforcement in a contemporary age (p. 17). Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • OFT. (2007). The deterrent effect of competition enforcement by the OFT — A REPORT prepared for the OFT by Deloitte. Office of Fair Trading, OFT962.

    Google Scholar 

  • OFT. (2010). Office of Fair Trading, Project Condor Board Review. (December 2010). Available from https://assets.digital.cabinet-office.gov.uk/media/556876fce5274a1895000008/Project_Condor_Board_Review.pdf.

  • OFT. (2013). Applications for leniency and no-action in cartel cases. July 2013, Office of Fair Trading, OFT1495. Available from https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/284417/OFT1495.pdf.

  • Ost, K. (2014). From regulation 1 to regulation 2: national enforcement of EU cartel prohibition and the need for further convergence. Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 5, 125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papadopoulos, A., & Lovdahl Gormsen, L. (2015). Greece. In Campbell (2015), (p. 104).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pettersson, T., Carle, J., & Lindeborg, S. P. (2015). Sweden. In Campbell (2015), (p. 266).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pipan Nahtigal, N., & Lahovnik, T. (2015). Slovenia. In Campbell (2015), (p. 245).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pound, R. (1910). Law in books and law in action. American Law Review, 44, 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ransiek, A., & Hüls, S. (2009). Strafrecht zur Regulierung der Wirtschaft. Zeitschrift für Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht, 38, 157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rădulescu, M., & Iacob, V. (2015). Romania. In Campbell (2015), (p. 227).

    Google Scholar 

  • Raum, R. (2014). § 81a. In E. Langen & H.-J. Bunte (Eds.), Langen/Bunte Kartellrecht Kommentar (Vol. 1, 12th ed.). Wolters Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rung-Hansen, A. (2015). Denmark. In Campbell (2015), (p. 69).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sando, T., & Hageler, A. J. (2015). Norway. In Campbell (2015), (p. 206).

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G., Nesbitt, N. H., & Weber Waller, S. (2015). Criminalizing cartels: a global trend? In J. Duns, A. Duke, & B. Sweeney (Eds.), Comparative competition law (p. 301). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sindhu, K. (2009). Anti-corruption compliance standards in the aftermath of the Siemens scandal. German Law Journal, 10, 1343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, B. (2016). Individual accountability for antitrust crimes. Remarks at the Yale global antitrust enforcement conference, New Haven, 19 February 2016. Available from https://www.justice.gov/opa/speech/deputy-assistant-attorney-general-brent-snyder-delivers-remarks-yale-global-antitrust; permanent link: https://perma.cc/XW7J-XUMN.

  • Spagnolo, G. (2006). Criminalization of cartels and their internal organization. In K. J. Cseres, M. P. Schinkel, & F. O. W. Vogelaar (Eds.), Criminalization of competition law enforcement: Economic and legal implications for the EU Member States. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisches Bundesamt. (1999–2015). Rechtspflege — Strafverfolgung, Fachserie 10 Reihe 3, Wiesbaden (latest available: 2013, published 2015).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, A. (2008). The UK cartel offence: Lame duck or black mamba. Centre for Competition Policy (CCP) Working Paper No. 08-19. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1310683.

  • Stephan, A. (2011). Disqualification orders for directors involved in cartels. Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2, 529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, A. (2014). The UK cartel offence: A purposive interpretation. Criminal Law Review, 12, 879.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, A. (2014a). Is the Korean innovation of individual informant rewards a viable cartel detection tool? (January 15, 2014). CCP Working Paper 14–3. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2405933.

  • Stephan, A. (2015). Survey of public attitudes to price fixing in the UK, Germany, Italy and the USA. Centre for Competition Policy (CCP) Working Paper 15-8. Available from http://competitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/8158338/8368036/Working+Paper+15-8+CCP.pdf/0ae07f44-485e-4ff3-a0e5-2cdd8f0052e0.

  • Stephan, A. (2016). Is there public support for cartel criminalisation?. Concurrences No. 2–2016, 40. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2782090.

  • Stucke, M. E. (2006). Morality and antitrust. Columbia Business Law Review, 2006(3), 443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szabó, L. (2015). Hungary. In Campbell (2015), (p. 117).

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabuchi, H., & Ivory, D. (2016). 10th death is linked to airbag by Takata. New York Times (New York edn), 23 January 2016, B1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiedemann, K. (1976). Kartellrechtsverstöße und Strafrecht. Cologne: Carl Heymanns Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiedemann, K. (2001). Wettbewerb als Rechtsgut des Strafrechts. In G. Britz, H. Jung, H. Koriath, & E. Müller (Eds.), Grundfragen staatlichen Strafens: Festschrift für Heinz Müller-Dietz zum 70 Geburtstag (p. 905). Munich: C.H. Beck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Twele, M. (2013). Die Haftung des Vorstands für Kartellrechtsverstöße. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • van Bergeijk, P. A. C. (2008). On the allegedly invisible construction cartel. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 4, 115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Duyne, P. C. (2007). All in the Dutch construction family: Cartel building and organised crime. In L. Holmes (Ed.), Terrorism, organised crime and corruption: Networks and linkages. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viros, D. (2016). Individual Criminal Sanctions in France. Concurrences No. 2–2016, 24. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2782090.

  • Vlasic, B., & Stout, H. (2014). Auto industry galvanized after record recall year. New York Times (New York edn), 31 December 2014, A1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner-von Papp, F. (2010a). Privatrechtliche oder strafrechtliche Durchsetzung des Kartellrechts? In W. Möschel & F. Bien (Eds.), Kartellrechtsdurchsetzung durch private Schadenersatzklagen? (p. 267). Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner-von Papp, F. (2010b). Kriminalisierung von Kartellen. Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 60, 268, WUW0347235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner-von Papp, F. (2011). What if all bid riggers went to prison and nobody noticed? Criminal antitrust law enforcement in Germany. In C. Beaton-Wells & A. Ezrachi (Eds.) (p. 157).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner-von Papp, F. (2014). Kriminalisierung von Kartellabsprachen — tut sich da was? Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 64, 1155, WUW0666947.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner-von Papp, F. (2016). Individual sanctions for competition law infringements: pros, cons, and challenges. Concurrences No. 2–2016, 14. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2782090.

  • Wardaugh, B. (2014). Cartels, markets and crime — A normative justification for the criminalisation of economic collusion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Werden, G. J., Hammond, S. D., & Barnett, B. A. (2012). Deterrence and detection of cartels: Using all the tools and sanctions, 26th Annual Institute on White Collar Crime (1 March 2012). Available from https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/518936/download.

  • Werden, G. J., & Simon, M. J. (1987). Why price-fixers should go to prison. The Antitrust Bulletin, XXXII, 917.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, P. (2014). The criminalization of European cartel enforcement: Theoretical, legal, and practical challenges. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wils, W. P. J. (2003). Does the effective enforcement of Articles 81 and 82 EC require not only fines on undertakings, but also individual penalties, and in particular imprisonment? In C. D. Ehlermann & I. Atanasiu (Eds.), European competition law annual 2001: Effective private enforcement of EC antitrust law (p. 411). Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wils, W. P. J. (2008). Efficiency and justice in European antitrust enforcement. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wils, W. P. J. (2013). Ten years of regulation 1/2003 — a retrospective. Journal of Competition Law & Practice, 4, 293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wils, W. P. J. (2016) The use of leniency in EU cartel enforcement: an assessment after twenty years. King's College London Law School Research Paper No. 2016–29; forthcoming in World Competition: Law and Economics Review, 39(3). Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2793717.

  • Wright, R. (2015). GM faces more than $1.5 bn over fatal ignition switch fault. Financial Times, 17 September 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zembla. (2001–2006). The Dutch construction cartel. Available from http://zembla.vara.nl/seizoenen/2006/afleveringen/12-11-2006/extras/the-duch-construction-cartel/.

  • Zimmer, D. (2016). Individual sanctions in German competition law: the case for a criminalisation of antitrust offences? Concurrences No. 2–2016, 28. Available from http://ssrn.com/abstract=2782090.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Florian Wagner-von Papp .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Wagner-von Papp, F. (2016). Compliance and Individual Sanctions in the Enforcement of Competition Law. In: Paha, J. (eds) Competition Law Compliance Programmes. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-44633-2_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-44633-2_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-44632-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-44633-2

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics