Skip to main content

Compliance and Incentive Contracts

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Competition Law Compliance Programmes

Abstract

In the discussion of competition law compliance programmes it is important to address the internal delegation problems within the firm. Hard core cartels are typically triggered by economic developments having a strong impact on industry profits, and are formed on a higher level of the firm’s hierarchy. One way to control managerial behaviour is by designing incentive contracts. This chapter argues that compliance measures such as training programmes or internal monitoring should be complemented by an appropriate design of incentive pay. Insights from the economic literature on agency problems and cartels show that particularly profit thresholds that must be met to receive a bonus and bonus caps have a crucial impact on managerial incentives to engage in collusive activity. Properly designed incentive contracts complement other compliance measures and improve deterrence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See http://goo.gl/IZshkg.

  2. 2.

    This definition is taken from the European Commission (DG Comp), see http://goo.gl/8l1lqT (last visit: October 13, 2015).

  3. 3.

    For an extensive review of fines and other components of the European Commission’s decisions, see Carree et al. (2010).

  4. 4.

    In a recent bribery case, Siemens sued a former member of its board for not having stopped and reported internally detected misconduct (see http://goo.gl/zemslQ).

  5. 5.

    See e.g. d’Aspremont et al. (1983) and Prokop (1999).

  6. 6.

    Theoretical findings in the theory of collusion with respect to demand fluctuations are manifold. Some relevant papers are Green and Porter (1984), Rotemberg and Saloner (1986), Haltiwanger and Harrington (1991), Staiger and Wolak (1992), Fabra (2006) and Paha (2013).

  7. 7.

    See: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/37152/37152_72_1.pdf.

  8. 8.

    There is also earlier work analysing the internal operation of a firm and contracts, e.g. Berhold (1971) and the book of Barnard, originally published in 1938 as well as the work of Herbert Simon in the 1950s.

  9. 9.

    For instance, Bagwell and Staiger (1997) analyse cartel stability over the business cycle from a firm’s perspective. Future research could examine how their analysis translates into a principal-agent relationship.

  10. 10.

    Some important papers are Arrow (1970), Pauly (1974), Harris and Raviv (1979), Shavell (1979), Holmström (1979), Grossman and Hart (1983) and Innes (1990).

  11. 11.

    The selected articles do not provide a complete overview of the problem. I refer to these papers due to their relevance for our topic.

  12. 12.

    One example of a firm that employs a comparable remuneration scheme is ThyssenKrupp, see https://www.thyssenkrupp.com/en/investor/verguetungsbericht.html.

  13. 13.

    In a Nash Equilibrium, no player (here: firm) has an incentive to unilaterally choose a different strategy given the other firms play their equilibrium strategies.

  14. 14.

    The term ‘efficient’ in this case covers allocative efficiency. In a cartel, both firms realise profits K. Higher profits are only possible if one firm deviates: however, the other firm is worse off in this case. The profits of one firm cannot be increased without decreasing the profits of another firm.

  15. 15.

    To be more precise, the authors (ibid.) show that collusion is a subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium. Subgame perfection is a refinement of the original Nash Equilibrium concept. If the latter is subgame perfect, it does not contain any non-credible threats. In most games it is important to determine an optimal reaction for every player to any choice of the other players (best response). Subgame perfection requires every possible action to be a best response, even those who are not played (threats).

  16. 16.

    It also has to hold that B < K − C because otherwise the principal would not have an incentive to offer the contract.

  17. 17.

    This is a slight modification of the original model which also incorporates a stochastic influence of effort on profits. I abstract from the stochastics arising from the state of nature θ outlined above in order to focus on the intuition. Note that the results in the original paper are less straightforward.

  18. 18.

    In the paper, the agent can exert effort. When an attempt to collude failed, it is shown that profits are generally lower than if there was no collusion at all.

  19. 19.

    For instance, in the LIBOR case bonuses of former bankers were cut or not paid at all. In one case, this process is the subject of lawsuits (see Bloomberg, http://goo.gl/qN43z1). One bank actually plans to use the bonus pool to pay the fines imposed by the authorities (see Financial Times, http://goo.gl/5A6I0z).

References

  • Arrow, K. (1970). Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashton, J., & Pressey, A. (2012). Who manages cartels? The role of sales and marketing managers within international cartels: Evidence from the European union 1990–2009. CCP Working Paper November 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert, C. (2009). Managerial effort incentives and market collusion. TSE Working Paper 09-127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R. W. (1997). Collusion over the business cycle. The RAND Journal of Economics, 28(1), 82–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2003). Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3), 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berhold, M. (1971). A theory of linear profit-sharing incentives. The Quarterly Journal of Economic, 85(3), 460–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., & Dewatripont, M. (2005). Contract theory. Cambridge/London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carree, M., Günster, A., & Schinkel, M. P. (2010). European antitrust policy 1957–2004: an analysis of commission decisions. Review of Industrial Organization, 36(2), 97–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor, J. M. (2004). Global antitrust prosecutions of international cartels. Staff Paper No. 04-15, Purdue University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connor, J. M., & Bolotova, Y. (2006). Cartel overcharges: Survey and meta-analysis. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24(6), 1109–1137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Aspremont, C., Jacquemin, A., Gabszewicz, J., & Weymark, J. (1983). On the stability of collusive price leadership. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 16(1), 17–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2002). Commission Decision of 27.11.02 relating to a proceeding under Article 81 of the EC Treaty, Case COMP/E-1/37.152 – Plasterboard. http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/37152/37152_72_1.pdf

  • Fabra, N. (2006). Collusion with capacity constraints over the business cycle. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24(1), 69–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman, C., Judd, K., & Kalai, E. (1991). Observable contracts: Strategic delegation and cooperation. International Economic Review, 32(3), 551–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, E. J., & Porter, R. H. (1984). Noncooperative collusion under imperfect price information. Econometrica, 52(1), 87–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1983). An analysis of the principal-agent problem. Econometrica, 51(1), 7–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grout, P., & Sonderegger, S. (2005). Predicting cartels. Office of Fair Trading OFT 773.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger, J., & Harrington, J. F. (1991). The impact of cyclical demand movements on collusive behavior. The RAND Journal of Economics, 22(1), 89–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J. E. (2006). How do cartels operate? In Foundations and trends in microeconomics. Hannover: Now Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J. E., & Chang, M. (2009). Modeling the birth and death of cartels with an application to evaluating competition policy. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(6), 1400–1435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1979). Optimal incentive contracts with imperfect information. Journal of Economic Theory, 20, 231–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herold, D. (2016). The impact of incentive pay and internal monitoring on corporate crime. Unpublished Working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herold, D., & Paha, J. (2015). Predicting cartel formation. Unpublished Working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 74–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Innes, R. (1990). Limited liability and incentive contracting with ex-ante action choices. Journal of Economic Theory, 52(1), 45–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J., & Martimort, D. (2002). The theory of incentives. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. J. (1999). Executive compensation. In O. C. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3, pp. 2485–2563). New York: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. J., & Kolasky, W. (2012). The role of anti-cartel compliance programs in preventing cartel behaviour. Antitrust, 26(2), 61–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Near, J. P., & Dworkin, T. M. (1998). Responses to legislative changes: Corporate whistleblowing policies. Journal of Business Ethics, 17(14), 1551–1561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Office of Fair Trading. (2010). Global antitrust prosecutions of international cartels.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paha, J. (2013). Cartel formation with endogenous capacity and demand uncertainty. MAGKS Working Paper No. 43-2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. (1974). Overinsurance and public provision of insurance: The roles of moral hazard and adverse selection. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(1), 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (1993). Should employees be subject to fines and imprisonment given the existence of corporate liability? International Review of Law and Economics, 13(3), 239–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prokop, J. (1999). Process of dominant cartel formation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17(2), 241–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. A. (1973). The economic theory of agency: The principal’s problem. American Economic Review, 63(2), 134–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg, J. T., & Saloner, G. (1986). A supergame-theoretic model of price wars during booms. The American Economic Review, 76(3), 390–407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1979). Risk sharing and incentives in the principal agent relationship. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spagnolo, G. (2000). Stock-related compensation and product-market competition. The RAND Journal of Economics, 31(1), 22–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spagnolo, G. (2005). Managerial incentives and collusive behaviour. European Economic Review, 49(6), 1501–1523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staiger, R. W., & Wolak, F. A. (1992). Collusive pricing with capacity constraints in the presence of demand uncertainty. The RAND Journal of Economics, 23(2), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, A. (2009). Hear no evil, see no evil: Why antitrust compliance programmes may be ineffective at preventing cartels. CCP Working Paper 09-09.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1964). A theory of oligopoly. The Journal of Political Economy, 72(1), 44–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veljanovski, C. (2007). Cartel fines in Europe – Law, practice and deterrence. World Competition, 30(1), 65–86.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel Herold .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Herold, D. (2016). Compliance and Incentive Contracts. In: Paha, J. (eds) Competition Law Compliance Programmes. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-44633-2_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-44633-2_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-44632-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-44633-2

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics